Hostname: page-component-6bf8c574d5-8gtf8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-19T17:49:26.611Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Social Structure and Electoral Behavior in Comparative Perspective: The Decline of Social Cleavages in Western Europe Revisited

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 May 2007

Martin Elff
Affiliation:
Department of Social Sciences of the University of Mannheim, Germany, E-mail: elff@sowi.uni-mannheim.de
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

A new conventional wisdom characterizes the comparative study of electoral politics. Social cleavages, once a stabilizing factor of electoral behavior in Western Europe, are on the wane. Voting decisions have become individualized and old social cleavages have been superseded by new value-related cleavages. This article challenges that view as an exaggeration.Martin Elff is Assistant Professor in the Department of Social Sciences of the University of Mannheim, Germany (elff@sowi.uni-mannheim.de). The author wishes to thank William Maloney, Anthony Mughan, Betty Haire Weyerer, Thomas Gschwend, Jan van Deth, Sigrid Roßteutscher, Simone Abendschön, Daniel Stegmüller, and especially Jennifer Hochschildt and three anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and suggestions on earlier drafts.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© 2007 American Political Science Association

Introduction

The impact of social structure on politics is one of the classic topics of political science. It dates back to Aristotle's reflections on the role of social divisions for the stability of Greek polities. The influence of social characteristics on voting has also been on the agenda of electoral research from the outset. A common assumption in the study of comparative politics up to the 1960s was that social characteristics such as class, religion, regional and ethnic identity are major antecedents of the voting decision in Western Europe. Thus, when Lazarsfeld, Berelson, and Gaudet stated in 1948 that “a person thinks, politically, as he is, socially. Social characteristics determine political preference,” it rang true, especially for Western Europeans.1

Lazarsfeld, Berelson, and Gaudet 1968, 27.

West European parties were often perceived as representatives of certain social strata or interest groups. Social democratic, socialist, and communist parties, for example, were perceived as representing the industrial working class.2

Mair and Mudde 1998; Ware 1996; von Beyme 1985.

On the other side of the coin, the support of parties by certain social groups was taken for granted. It was assumed, for example, that British workers would rather vote for the Labour Party than for the Tories, while French workers would rather vote for the Parti socialiste or the Communists than the Gaullists. Such commonplace assumptions became standard examples in works on the philosophy of the social sciences.3

See for example, Hollis 1994.

Nevertheless, this socio-structural perspective on politics has become outmoded in recent decades. Instead, the finding of Franklin et al. that “almost all of the countries we have studied show a decline during our period in the ability of social cleavages to structure individual voting choice” has acquired the status of a “new conventional wisdom.4

Franklin et al. 1992, 385; Dalton 2002b, 199.

That the earlier stabilizing power of social cleavages has been weakening is now a widely accepted explanation for the increased volatility of electoral results of West European countries.5

Dalton 2002a,b; Kriesi 1998; Lane and Ersson 1997; Dogan 1995; Dalton and Wattenberg 1993; Franklin et al. 1992; Dalton, Flanagan, and Beck 1984.

Some authors even claim that social cleavages have become irrelevant and suggest completely disposing of the concept of cleavages.6

Lane and Ersson 1997.

The waning of social cleavages is typically attributed to fundamental changes at the societal level, which have become manifest in changes of the situations, attitudes, and behaviors of individuals. These changes have blurred the boundaries between social groups, such as social classes, have undermined the relevance of these divisions, or have directly affected the way in which individuals make voting decisions.7

de Graaf, Nieuwbeerta, and Heath 1995; Nieuwbeerta 1996; Inglehart and Rabier 1986; Inglehart 1984; Dalton 2002a.

According to Dalton's theory of cognitive mobilization, the spread of mass media and the rise in average levels of education have enabled individuals to make political choices that are independent of external cues given by social groups.8

Dalton 1984.

According to Inglehart's theory of value change, new value-related cleavages have emerged in voting behavior that have cross-cut or superseded older cleavages based on conflicts of economic interests.9

Inglehart 1997, 1990, 1977; Inglehart and Rabier 1986; Inglehart 1984

In this vein, Dogan states that “electoral volatility and dealignment from parties” stem “from individualization of voting”, which “is the result of the parallel decline of the class vote and the religious vote, and also of the decline in partisanship.”10

Dogan 1995, 536.

Although these claims fit well into a notion of a “postmodern society”—a notion quite popular among intellectual observers of Western society—they nevertheless are an exaggeration, as I show in this article.

The article is organized as follows. In the next section, I argue that even if changes in the relation between class or church attendance on electoral behavior can be observed, it cannot be ruled out that they are attributable to political rather than societal transformations. Then follows a section that considers the empirical evidence regarding changes in the impact of class and church attendance on electoral behavior. I show that although the impact of class has been in decline at least in some of the countries under study, the impact of church attendance has been almost stable. In the next two sections I argue that neither cognitive mobilization nor value change—although important factors according to the “new conventional wisdom”—can adequately explain the observable changes in class voting. Against this backdrop, I conclude that a further decline of social cleavages cannot be taken for granted and that political factors may be accountable for the changes in the structures of electoral behavior in Western Europe.

The Nature of Social Cleavages in Electoral Behavior

Social cleavages have long been viewed as a stabilizing force of electoral outcomes—an influence independent both of parties and of individual voters.11

Rose and Urwin 1969

A decline of social cleavages has often been inferred from an increase in the volatility of electoral results. The notion of cleavages as a stabilizing force finds a clear expression in the use of metaphors by Franklin et al. such as a party system being “'locked down' by the social structural determinants of voting choice” and that cleavage politics inhibit changes in party systems like a “straightjacket.”12

Franklin et al. 1992, 10, emphasis added.

Many authors, including those above, refer to Lipset and Rokkan's seminal account of the genesis of European party systems when they discuss the electoral impact of social cleavages.13

Lipset and Rokkan 1967.

In fact, Lipset and Rokkan point out and try to explain certain similarities and dissimilarities among European party systems. Most notably, they try to account for the variation in the structure of European party systems by referring to the patterns of allegiance and opposition among principal socio-political actors that emerged during the Reformation, the processes of state- and nation-building, and the Industrial Revolution. But the fact that parties can be traced back to these principal actors, that is, to social elites and to social movements that emerged during these processes, does not imply a constraint on voters' choices. Rather, their account leads them to a pessimistic prognosis about the ability of parties to adapt to changes in the social structure. That “the party systems of the 1960's reflect … the cleavage structures of the 1920's” seems to be a liability for the parties, but not a straightjacket for the voters.14

Ibid., 50

To them, the parties' failure to adapt to the “car and TV culture” is one of the reasons behind the discontent and protest among the younger generations.15

Ibid., 54, 55.

On the other hand, they consider the causes of continuities in voting patterns as an open question.16

Ibid., 51. For an extensive discussion of Lipset and Rokkan's “freezing hypothesis”, see Mair 1999; Lybeck 1985

While taking the Lipset-Rokkan account as their point of departure, authors like Franklin et al. have a quite different notion of the role of social cleavages. They understand cleavages as “reflecting broadly based and longstanding social and economic divisions within society, and the cleavage structure is thought of in terms of social groups and of the loyalties of members to their social groups.”17

Franklin et al. 1992, 4.

Therefore, a decline of social cleavages seems to imply a decline of group loyalties. But group loyalties are not a necessary condition for the existence of social cleavages.

A necessary condition for the existence of a social cleavage in voting behavior is that members of the groups delimited by a social division share characteristics that may become politically relevant. But such a condition may also be satisfied if government policies affect different groups in different ways. For example, cuts in welfare expenditures may specifically harm unskilled workers, who may be more at risk of unemployment than are professionals and managers. But if that is the case, then the electoral relevance of cleavages will depend on the extent to which parties differ regarding the support they give to such policies. Indeed, there have long been systematic differences in this respect between parties from different party families.18

Mair and Mudde 1998; Ware 1996.

Social democratic parties have typically supported the expansion of welfare states, while liberal and conservative parties (in the European sense) have advocated limitation on welfare expenditures. In so far as party policies conform to the interests of certain social groups, one may say that parties represent these groups, and this conformity may have existed since these parties were founded. This does not imply, however, that parties are constrained to such a degree as to prevent their adaptation to changing societal environments. Quite the contrary. It is a matter of choice for parties either to limit their electoral appeal to their original constituencies or to compete for newly emerging groups of voters. Programmatic changes in social democratic parties after World War II show clearly that they are able to make such choices.19

The adoption of the “Godesberger Programm” by the German SPD in 1959, which ended the Marxist orientation of the party, is a notable example, as is the transformation of the British Labour Party to “New Labour” under the leadership of Tony Blair. See also Przeworski and Sprague 1986; Kitschelt 1994.

Thus, one finds at least two variant views on the role of social cleavages in the relevant literature. For Lipset and Rokkan, the origins of party systems from social cleavages of the past serve as a constraint on contemporary party competition. Accordingly, changes in the social structure of contemporary countries may lead to a decline in the electoral relevance of anachronistic social cleavages. Indeed, Lipset24 is one of the supporters of the general decline thesis of class cleavages.20

Lipset 1981, 503ff; Clark and Lipset 1991, 1993, 2001.

For Franklin et al., social cleavages are mainly structures of group loyalty. Processes of individualization erode group loyalties, while the success of democratic governments in solving social conflicts tends to blur group divisions.21

Franklin et al. 1992, 421.

Rather than considering the dynamics of party competition, they view changes in the electoral role of social cleavages as an expression of a ubiquitous trend. Cross-national differences in the strength and pace of the decline of social cleavages are not viewed as contingent on political factors, but rather as an expression of a general process that has occurred in different countries at a different pace—some are “leaders”, while others are “laggards.”22

Ibid., 390.

Beside the fundamental difference regarding the nature of social cleavages, both views simply ignore or downplay the programmatic flexibility of parties. Consequently it is this perspective on party competition combined with an increased volatility of electoral outcomes and the emergence of new parties that led to the impression of a decline of social cleavages.

Social Cleavages and Party Preferences of European Voters: Persistence or Change?

Although Lipset and Rokkan enumerate four different lines of cleavage—the church/state, center/periphery, urban/rural, and owner/worker lines of cleavage—this does not mean that all four types of social cleavages are present in all West European countries. Only the owner/worker line of cleavage has been more or less uniformly present in European party systems. It has become manifest in the competition between labor and all other “bourgeois” parties.23

Lipset and Rokkan 1967, 35.

The remaining lines of cleavages were present during the formation of party systems and mainly prior to the enfranchisement of larger portions of the population.24

Ibid., 35

Therefore, these cleavages largely led to a political division between social elites, such as the Crown, the Catholic Church, the landed gentry, or the urban business class. In general, groups such as farmers or ethnic minorities were not explicitly represented in European party systems. Agrarian parties had a presence mainly in some Scandinavian countries, while ethnic parties are found only in countries with clearly delineated ethnic subcultures, like Belgium, Great Britain, and Spain. Church/state cleavages in their various forms may, however, have gained new expressions and new saliency as a consequence of the secularization of European societies.25

See e.g., Madeley 1991.

Increasingly many people are less attached to religious institutions and seek forms of self-actualization beyond the bounds of traditional and religious morals and religious-minded people may find increasingly more occasions to take offense at modern, secular lifestyles. Therefore, only two types of cleavages are considered in the analyses below: religious-secular and class cleavages. If any claim regarding the general decline or irrelevance of social cleavages is true, it will especially concern cleavages of these two types.

According to Lipset and Rokkan, the expression of social cleavages in party systems is essentially dichotomous. Class cleavages pit labor parties against all other “bourgeois” parties, while religious/secular cleavages set Christian and conservative parties against the remaining parties. On the level of individual voters and their membership in social groups, social cleavages are not strictly dichotomous, but allow for ambiguous positions. For example, class cleavages pit wage-earning manual workers against the self-employed and the service class or salariat, whose members enjoy career opportunities and delegated entrepreneurial discretion and authority over rank-and-file employees and workers.26

See Goldthorpe 1982, 1995. Many earlier studies on class voting are based on a dichotomous class schema, which lumps together routine non-manual, management, and self-employed occupations into a broad “white collar” category. Such a dichotomy may, however, lead to erroneous diagnoses of a decline in class voting if the composition of this “white collar” category changes over time. See Korpi 1974, Heath, Jowell, and Curtice 1985, Nieuwbeerta 1996.

Employees of various ranks below that of the service class, however, have an ambiguous position with respect to cleavages of this type. By the same token, religious/secular cleavages set devout churchgoers against agnostics, atheists, and other secularized urban people, whereas non-regular churchgoers have an ambiguous position with respect to this cleavage. Therefore, the difference between manual workers and the “bourgeois” classes of managers, professionals, and the self-employed with respect to the support for labor parties are the main manifestations of class cleavages, whereas differences between regular churchgoers (those who attend church at least once a week) and non-churchgoers with respect to the support for Christian or conservative parties are the main manifestation of religious/secular cleavages.

If social cleavages really have become irrelevant for electoral behavior, one will not be able to find any systematic differences between voters from various social groupings with respect to their support for “cleavage-based” parties or party families, that is, for labor parties (social democratic, socialist, and communist parties) or for Christian (denominational and Christian democratic) and conservative parties. In Western Europe, however, this is clearly not the case, as demonstrated in figures 1 and 2.27

The data come from the Eurobarometer, a series of general social surveys conducted on behalf of the Commission of the European Union since 1973. These surveys are especially designed to track over time developments of political attitudes in Western European publics. The seven countries considered in figures 1 and 2 and in the following analyses are those that have been included in the Eurobarometer since its inception in 1973. Details on the surveys and variables used in this article can be obtained from the supplementary material on the author's website (http://webrum.uni-mannheim.de/sowi/elff/) and from the Eurobarometer websites (European Commission: http://ec.europa.eu/public_opinion/; ICPSR: http://webapp.icpsr.umich.edu/cocoon/ICPSR-SERIES/00026.xml; GESIS: http://www.gesis.org/en/data_service/eurobarometer/). Major parts of the pooled data set used in the analyses of this article were compiled by the author during his work on the research project “Political Interest, Engagement, and Affect” at the Mannheim Center for European Social Research (MZES) funded by the German Research Foundation (DFG Grant DE 630/2-1),), see van Deth and Elff 2004. The author thanks Jan W. van Deth, the director of the research project, for allowing to use the data in this publication. Further thanks go to Evi Scholz for assistance in obtaining the data and Peter Kotzian for assistance in constructing the pooled data set.

In four of the seven countries, a majority of the manual workers supported labor parties at the turn of the millennium (see figure 1). In that respect, manual workers differ clearly from the two “bourgeois” classes, the salariat (employed professionals and managers), and the self-employed. The difference in support for labor parties between manual workers and the salariat and the self-employed is at least twenty percentage points in most countries. These differences are both substantial in size and highly statistically significant. Clearly, class cleavages should not be written off as a major factor for voting behavior in European countries.28

All these differences are statistically significant, even if with control variables such as education, income, and gender are taken into account.

Class and support for labor parties, 1995–2002

Even more striking are the differences between voters that reflect religious-secular cleavages (see figure 2). In the 1990s, up to sixty percent or even more of those who attend church at least once a week supported Christian (denominational and Christian democratic) or conservative parties. In the Netherlands, three out of four voters who regularly attend church intend to vote for one of the Dutch denominational or Christian democratic parties. On the other hand, in all seven countries except Great Britain, no more than every fifth, in Belgium and in Italy no more than every tenth, of those voters who never go to church intended to support Christian or conservative parties. The difference between these two groups of voters is some forty to sixty percentage points in five of the seven countries. While one finds lower, but still marked inter-group differences in Denmark, Great Britain seems to be a deviant case with respect to religious/secular cleavages. In contrast to other countries, support for the conservatives is the highest in the middle category, while regular churchgoers' support for the conservatives is only seven percent higher than that of the non-churchgoers. However, given the history of church/state relations in the United Kingdom, the weakness of the religious/secular cleavage is not particularly surprising.29

The opposition between Conservatives and Liberals and British Labour is not so much an expression of cleavages between secular or Protestant nation-building elites and the trans-national Catholic Church as in much of continental Europe, but of a cleavage between an established church and non-established churches, see Madeley 1982, but also see Kotler-Berkowitz 2001. That many of those who attend church weekly are working-class Irish immigrants may also be conducive to this result. All differences in figure 2 are statistically significant, with or without controlling for education, income, and gender.

Church attendance and support for Christian and conservative parties, 1990–1994

That social cleavages are still relevant for electoral behavior does not preclude their decline. Indeed, class cleavages have undergone a decline in some countries during the last couple of decades, as shown in figures 3 and 4. But the trends in percentage differences in these figures are ambivalent with respect to the claim that a general decline of class voting has occurred. First, class cleavages seem to be stable in Belgium, with manual workers failing to become more similar to either the salariat or to the self-employed (with respect to the support for labor parties). Neither a statistically significant trend in the respective percentage differences nor in the respective log odds-ratios can be found for this country (see table 1). Only the expected value of the difference between self-employed and manual workers in France, and only the expected value of the difference between the salariat and the manual workers in Great Britain has declined by more than twenty percentage points. Furthermore, there is no statistically significant downward trend in the difference between manual workers and the self-employed in Italy, while in the Netherlands, the rather slight decline in percentage differences between the salariat and the manual workers fails to attain conventional levels of statistical significance. On the other hand, in Denmark, the decline of the percentage difference between manual workers and the salariat is staggering; from the mid-1970s to 2003, on average it amounts to almost forty percentage points.

Class differences regarding the support for labor parties, working class versus salariat 1975–2002

Class differences regarding the support for labor parties, working class versus self-employed, 1975–2002

Class and support for labor parties, 1975–2002

With regard to a decline in class cleavages, the glass appears to be either half-full or half-empty.30

A referee of an earlier version of this article has pointed me to this interpretation.

Only three of the seven countries under study exhibit an unambiguous decline in class voting, while in two countries, the decline of class voting is only partial. In Belgium, however, the impact of class on electoral choice seems almost stable.

An examination of trends in religious/secular cleavages results in a less ambivalent conclusion. In some of the countries electoral divisions along religious/secular cleavages are not only larger than along class cleavages, but in general they are also more stable. Although statistically significant downward trends of the odds ratios are found in Denmark, France, and the Netherlands (see table 2), the corresponding decline of the corresponding percentage differences are negligible (see figure 5). Only France shows an unambiguous downward trend in terms of both odds-ratios and percentage differences. Italy shows a decline of percentage differences between regular churchgoers and non-churchgoers, but no statistically significant trend in the odds ratios. The support for the Democrazia Cristiana seems to show an overall downward trend. But as support among non-churchgoers was already very low, it cannot have declined as much as it has among regular churchgoers. Thus, the decline in percentage differences found in figure 4 seems to be the result of a bottom effect.

Differences between weekly churchgoers and non-churchgoers regarding the support for Christian parties, 1975–1994

Church attendance and support for Christian and conservative parties, 1975–1994

It is ironic that despite the turmoil in the Dutch party system in the early 1970s and in the Italian party system in the 1990s, religious/secular cleavages appear quite stable. In the Netherlands, the three major denominational parties, the Anti-Revolutionaire Partij, the Christelijk-Historisch Unie, and the Katholieke Volkspartij merged into the Christen Democratisch Appel. As a consequence, differences in voting behavior between Catholics, liberal Calvinist (Hervormde), and orthodox Calvinists (Gereformeerde) evaporated.31

Andeweg 1982; Irwin and van Holsteyn 1997; van Holsteyn and Irwin 2000.

But this occurred mainly because the major denominational parties were superseded by a non-denominational Christian democratic party.32

de Graaf, Heath, and Need. 2001. Nevertheless, there are still minor denominational parties like the SGP, the GPV, and the RPF on the Dutch political market.

But the new Christen Democratisch Appel still has an unambiguous position on the religious/secular cleavage and attracts churchgoers rather than non-churchgoers, as the results reported earlier in this article indicate. A far more dramatic turmoil occurred in Italy in the early 1990s. Except for the Partito Comunista Italiano (which had been already transformed into a post-communist, almost social democratic Partito Democratia della Sinistra), all major parties collapsed under the pressure of major Mafia and corruption scandals. Nevertheless, liberals and the moderate left re-emerged in the form of various parties that later formed the Olive Tree coalition, while several smaller Christian democratic parties (Partito Popolare Italiano, Centro Cristiano Democratico, and Cristiani Democratici Uniti) succeeded the Democrazia Cristiana as manifestations of the Christian democratic famille spirituelle. But the Forza Italia—a new conservative party—inherited much of the former DC vote.33

Morlino 1996.

Despite these transformations, there is no sudden decline in the religious/secular cleavage in Italy (although the data is only available to 1994). This suggests that the continuity of certain types of ideological appeals rather than the continuity of party organizations and partisan attachment is crucial for the stability of social cleavages in electoral behavior. If a Christian democratic party disappears along with its secularist opponents and new Christian democratic parties and new secularist parties take their positions, the continuity of a religious/secular cleavage may be possible.

The conclusions with regard to a decline in the electoral relevance of social cleavages are mixed at best. In the majority of the countries under study, at least one or both aspects of the political divide between manual workers and the “bourgeois classes” of the salariat and the self-employed has weakened. Furthermore, the decline of these divisions has been greatest where they were largest at the beginning of the observation period, in Denmark. This fits well to Franklin et al.'s argument that a decline of social cleavages is a general process that occurs in different countries at different times. Denmark would be a “laggard” in this process, catching up with the other countries that have converged to an average level of twenty percentage point differences between manual workers and the “bourgeois” classes. But if this notion of a general process of decline with different timings and different paces was correct, one would expect to find that if one aspect of the class divide weakens, then so will the other, and that class cleavages are stable only in countries where their impact has already been comparatively low. Neither of these two expectations is completely substantiated. Furthermore, if social cleavages were in general decline, this would also find expression in a weakening of the electoral division along religious-secular cleavages and it would affect especially those cleavages that had been relatively strong. In fact, in two countries where a substantial decline of class cleavages has occurred—Denmark and France—also a statistically significant, though very modest decline of religious/secular cleavages is found. But in terms of percentage differences, the impact of religious/secular cleavages is relatively stable, especially in countries where they have been comparatively strong, such as Belgium, the Netherlands, and West Germany.

While the debate about the decline of social cleavages originally centered on the question of a decline in class voting in single countries, especially in Britain, the debate has taken a different turn in recent decades.34

Manza, Hout, and Brooks 1995, and Evans 2000 give a comprehensive overview of recent discussions about changes in class voting. The volumes edited by Evans 1999, and Clark and Lipset 1991, are notable compilations of contending views on this matter. The discussion about changes in the relation between religion and voting is less heated. A recent compilation of comparative research on confessional and religious/secular voting can be found in Broughton and ten Napel 2000. On social cleavages and voting behavior in the U.S., see Hout, Brooks, and Manza 1995; Brooks and Manza 1997; Manza and Brooks 1997; 1999.

Critics of the notion of a general decline of class cleavages no longer deny that class voting has weakened in some European countries. Rather they point to cross-national variations, which may indicate the relevance of factors originating in the context of the individual country, most notably political factors.35

Mair et al. 1999; Evans, Heath, and Payne 1999; Evans 2000.

Indeed, these criticisms may find support in the stability of class cleavages in Belgium and in the relative stability of religious/secular cleavages in most of the countries under study. Of course, the notion of a general decline of social cleavages is a very strong claim if it is held to imply that social cleavages are in decline in each and every country—and this claim is easily refuted by counterexamples. But no one will claim nowadays that there are no exceptions to the decline of social cleavages. Rather, proponents of the notion of a general decline claim that it is a process taking place in the majority of advanced industrial countries. From their perspective, countries where the impact of social cleavages is stable are the exceptions that prove the rule, are laggards in a process that is ubiquitous in principle.

After acknowledging these caveats, an uninvolved observer of this debate may wonder what it is all about now. Can the debate ever by resolved with empirical evidence from several countries? In order to find an answer to this question, it may be worthwhile shifting attention from the occurrence or non-occurrence of changes in the patterns of party preferences to the processes that are held to underlie those changes.

Does Cognitive Mobilization Undermine Cleavage-Based Alignments?

According to several authors, a long-term, large-scale process of change has been taking place in Western democracies, a displacement of old cleavage-based voter alignments by a “New Politics,” which ultimately culminates in the emergence of a “New Political Culture”.36

Clark and Hoffman-Martinot 1998.

One aspect of this process is cognitive mobilization. Rising levels of education and the spread of mass media have made many voters independent of political cues provided by social groups and are thus undermining the connection between social structure and electoral behavior. Another aspect of this process is value change. The level of physical and economic security achieved by Western advanced industrial societies has led many citizens to attach less weight to material concerns in making political decisions than in earlier decades and to place more emphasis on non-material values. As a consequence, cleavages based on conflicting socio-economic interests have been on the wane. Political phenomena of recent decades such as the student protests of the 1960s, the decline of party identification, and the rise of the new social movements and green parties in West European countries lend much plausibility to these notions. However, if political changes are conceived as originating from outside the realm of politics, only an incomplete understanding of these changes can be achieved at best.

According to Dalton, “the increasing sophistication of contemporary electorates may lessen voter reliance on social cues as individuals make their own political decisions.”37

Dalton 2002a, 143.

The following line of thought leads from cognitive mobilization to a decline of social cleavages.
  1. The more dependent individuals are on cues provided by social groups, the stronger the impact of social structure on electoral behavior.
  2. The higher an individual's education, and the easier the access to, and more frequent her use of, mass media is, the more her political decision-making is independent of cues provided by social groups.
  3. The higher an individual's education, the easier the access to, and the more frequent her use of, mass media is, the less likely her social location is to influence her party preferences.
  4. Consequently, increasing levels of education and increasing mass media consumption in a country's population lead to a decline of the relevance of social cleavages for electoral behavior in that country. This may be called the scenario of general subversion of cleavage-based alignments by cognitive mobilization.

This seems to rest on findings of Berelson and Lazarsfeld's classic election studies: Social groups are politically homogeneous, which is brought about by interpersonal communications among group members.38

Berelson, Lazarsfeld, and McPhee 1954, 88ff, Huckfeldt 1984.

But these findings do not imply that social groups act as unitary actors providing cues for and exerting pressure on individual members. Rather, interpersonal communication within social groups has a specific structure. Politically aware group members influence others either by being asked for advice or by engaging in active persuasion. However, among opinion leaders, the relation between social location and political preference is relatively strong.39

Berelson, Lazarsfeld, and McPhee 1954, 109f.

Cognitive mobilization may increase the number of opinion leaders, but this will lead to a decrease in the political homogeneity of social groups only if opinion leaders are now more politically diverse than they were at the time of the Berelson and Lazarsfeld's electoral studies. Moreover, this is a precondition of electoral change that is not brought about by cognitive mobilization itself.

The rise of the mass media, especially of television, may have led to a loss of importance of cues supplied by group opinion leaders, but for reasons other than those envisioned by Dalton. According to Putnam, rising television consumption is one of the factors that have loosened or severed social bonds and have led to a decline in social capital.40

Putnam 1995; 2000, 216ff.

Thus, social isolation inhibits group influence. Conversely, the expansion of mass media need not lead to a higher level of political knowledge if they are used mainly for entertainment.41

Prior 2005.

In fact, much of the literature on the effects of the expansion of television deplores its deleterious effects on political awareness.42

See, however, Norris 2000.

Social isolation and extended consumption of television entertainment may have an effect more appropriately termed cognitive demobilization.

Increasing political awareness will weaken the relevance of voters' social location for party choice only if an orientation to one's social position precludes an orientation to issues and runs counter to an enlightened self-interest. But this is not self-evident. Rather, if labor parties claim to pursue the interests of members of the working class, and if Christian and conservative parties promise to uphold and defend values held dear by traditionally-minded churchgoers, a strong relation between being a member of the working class and voting for a labor party, or a strong relation between going to church at least once a week and voting for a Christian or conservative party is a clear expression of self-interest. This consideration is in fact backed by empirical evidence provided, for example, by Weakliem and Heath.43

Weakliem and Heath 1994.

Seeking advice from knowledgeable others of the same social location is indeed a formidable means of reducing the costs of finding and processing politically relevant information.44

Downs 1957, 228ff; Lupia and McCubbins 1998

Under certain circumstances, it may even be rational to refrain from seeking the advice of others and to form a voting habit instead. Such a habit will be rational once a voter has formed her party preference in the light of her own interests and of parties' issue positions and if she can correctly expect that neither her own interests nor the party's issue positions will change.45

Achen 2002; Robertson 1976.

If this reasoning is correct, cognitive mobilization will break voting habits and undermine cleavage-based alignments on the condition that either the voter's interests change, such as a change in her occupational class, or the parties' issue positions change, for example, as a consequence of the decision to seek the support of new and wider segments of the electorate. Consequently, one should not expect the effects of cognitive mobilization on the patterns of electoral behavior to be unconditional. Instead, these effects are conditional on the parties' strategic and tactical choices in the competition for votes. Of course, these choices may vary across countries, across parties, and across elections within individual countries. This corresponds to a scenario of a varying role of cognitive mobilization, in which increasing levels of education and increasing mass media consumption in a country's population may have led to a decrease, to stability, or even to an increase in the electoral relevance of social cleavages.

This scenario seems to be the most plausible one (recalling the findings of the previous section). The absence of a ubiquitous decline of social cleavages contradicts the scenario of a general subversion of cleavage-based alignments. If cognitive mobilization really is a process that has taken place in all advanced industrial or post-industrial societies, then it does not seem to have led to a decline of social cleavages in all of these countries. Nevertheless, the scenario of a varying role of cognitive mobilization may serve to reconcile cognitive mobilization theory with the absence of a universal decline of social cleavages, if cognitive mobilization is accountable for a decline in class voting in those countries. This, however, is not the case (see table 3). The effect of watching news on television upon the levels of class voting does not lead to a prediction of a decline in class voting in any of the five countries that showed such a decline. The effect of education on levels of class voting leads to the prediction of much weaker declines of class voting in Denmark, France, Great Britain, the Netherlands, and West Germany than those that actually have occurred in these countries. But the spread of mass media use and rising levels of education in advanced industrial societies are assumed to be the main driving forces of cognitive mobilization. If cognitive mobilization directly leads to a decline in class voting, or if cognitive mobilization plays at least a moderating role, then predicted changes in the differences between manual workers and the salariat and the self-employed should be close to the changes observed. Even if one considers a more direct indicator for the political consequences of cognitive mobilization, one does not find evidence that cognitive mobilization is accountable for the observed changes in class voting. Hardly any change in class voting can be attributed to the effect of the frequency with which citizens discuss politics with friends on the level of class voting (again, see table 3).

Predicted and observed trends in class voting and associated Cox-test statistics

The two main “New Politics” theories mentioned at the beginning of this section each postulate a displacement of old cleavages based on social structure by new political divisions, but they differ in the postulated causal chain. According to Dalton, the decline of class-based cleavages is a precondition for the emergence of electoral divisions over new political issues, including those over value priorities, whereas the decline of class-based cleavages is driven by the cognitive mobilization of mass electorates.46

Dalton 2002a, 2002b.

According to Inglehart, it is the rise of postmaterialism itself that has caused the decline of class-based cleavages.47

Inglehart 1984; Inglehart and Rabier 1986.

Cognitive mobilization may lead to an increase in the readiness to adopt elite-challenging forms of political behavior, that is, to an increase of “unconventional” forms of political participation, but it is not a precondition for the displacement of class-based cleavages by value-based cleavages.48

Inglehart 1977, 1979.

Since Dalton's account is not supported by the findings of this section, the explanatory power of value change for observed declines in class voting is examined next.

Does Value Change Lead to the Displacement of Class Cleavages?

Ronald Inglehart's theory of value change is a prominent and much discussed attempt to explain and predict longterm changes in the patterns of political behavior that have occurred in Western publics.49

Inglehart 1977, 1990, 1997.

According to Inglehart, rising levels of material security experienced by the population of Western advanced industrial societies have especially led members of the younger generations to de-emphasize materialist values, which were central for a society in an environment of physical and economical insecurity. Inglehart designates those who give non-material values priority over material ones as “postmaterialists”.

Inglehart's theory of value change has often been praised for its generality and parsimony. Nevertheless, if the consequences of value change on class voting are considered, its implications are ambiguous. The different priority of economic concerns among materialists and postmaterialists suggests the following line of thought:

  1. Class cleavages are based on opposing economic interests between the working class and the middle and upper classes.
  2. For postmaterialists, material concerns, including economic interests, are of lesser importance than for materialists.
  3. Consequently, postmaterialists are less divided than materialists on contrary economic interests related to class.
  4. Therefore, an increasing proportion of postmaterialists in the population of a country leads to a decline in class voting, a scenario that may be called the scenario of direct displacement of class cleavages by value-based cleavages.

Inglehart's own account of the consequences of value change for class voting is somewhat different, however:50

Inglehart 1984; Inglehart and Rabier 1986; Inglehart 1997;. Knutsen 1995.

Postmaterialists vote for the political left because they favor social change. They support social change because the society in which they live is centered on the priority of materialist values. Since postmaterialists mainly come from social strata that belong to the middle classes (especially the salariat), which were originally supporters of the political right, differences between the middle classes and the working classes lessen. The decline of class divisions may even be reinforced if postmaterialist issues come to dominate the political agenda. In that case, a materialist reaction may be stimulated such that many working-class voters turn to the political right; predominantly materialist, they oppose the changes pressed for by postmaterialists. This leftward movement of postmaterialist members of the middle classes and the rightward movement of materialist members of the working class may also lead to a displacement of class cleavages, but Inglehart adds some qualifications to the political consequences of value change. A leftward movement of middle-class postmaterialists occurs only if parties of the left actually take up the political agenda of postmaterialists or if “New Left” or green parties that act on the postmaterialist agenda emerge.51

Inglehart 1997, 243ff, 252.

Yet these two preconditions can be viewed as leading to the same political consequences only if one puts the label “left party” indistinctively both on traditional labor parties and on new-left or green parties. Ironically, Inglehart himself emphasizes the difference between the “Old Left” and the “New Left” political agenda.52

For example Inglehart 1997, 246.

Whether traditional labor parties take up the postmaterialist agenda, or New Left or green parties emerge, are different types of processes with different political consequences.53

See also Rohrschneider 1993; Heath et al. 1990.

The first type of political developments leads to a greening-of-the-Left scenario, in which an increase in the proportion of postmaterialists in a country's population leads to a decline of class voting in that country as traditional labor parties attract postmaterialist voters from the middle classes and alienate materialist voters from the working class. The second type of political developments may, however, lead to a split-within-the-middle-classes scenario, in which an increase in the proportion of postmaterialists in a country's population leads to an increase of support for New Left or green parties among the middle classes and to a split within the middle classes between a New Left faction and an Old Right faction. In this scenario, class differences with respect to the support for labor parties remain unaffected.

There is still another possibility. Established parties may choose to ignore the postmaterialist agenda, as they can expect to lose as much as they would gain by adopting it, while hurdles inherent to the electoral system prevent New Left or green parties from gaining electoral relevance. This possibility results in a scenario of electoral irrelevance of value change, in which an increase in the proportion of postmaterialists in a country's population has no consequences for electoral behavior, and thereby no impact on the relationship between class and vote.

While this last scenario seems quite unlikely, it is nevertheless consistent with Inglehart's theory. In fact, according to Inglehart, dissatisfaction of postmaterialists with established parties, which ignored their specific demands, was one of the main reasons for the student protests in the 1960s and for the emergence of new social movements in the 1970s.54

Inglehart 1989; 1997.

If one acknowledges that a rise of postmaterialist value orientations does not determine a decline of class cleavages, but poses instead new risks and opportunities for parties, one finds that Inglehart's theory is rich in interesting implications. The variety of scenarios just presented may serve to reconcile the notion of a general change towards postmaterialist value priorities with the finding of the previous section that there are clear exceptions to a decline in class voting.

Such a reconciliation would be supplied by a finding that declines in class voting, which have occurred in several of the countries under study, can be predicted by the effect of value priorities on the level of class voting. This, however, is not the case, as can be concluded from the results presented in table 3. The actual changes in the log odds-ratios between the salariat and manual workers and between the self-employed and manual workers with respect to the support for labor parties are generally much larger than the ones predicted. Although value priorities fare better in predicting changes in class voting than do the various indicators of cognitive mobilization considered in the preceding section, the differences between predictions and actual changes are in several countries still statistically significant and non-trivial. For example, while the coefficient of change of the log odds-ratio of the salariat versus manual workers is 1.15 in Denmark, the predicted change is only 0.43. Even allowing for changes in the effect of value priorities on the support for labor parties does not lead to better predictions of changes in class voting. Only in cases where actual changes in class voting are merely modest are the differences to the predictions statistically insignificant, such as in the case of the self-employed in Denmark and in the Netherlands. (Note however that the period of observation is different from that of table 1.)

Obviously, a constant effect of value priorities on class voting cannot completely explain changes in class voting, even if one takes into account the possibility that the overall relevance of value priorities for electoral behavior increases. If value change has consequences for class voting, then it is not by way of a direct displacement of old class-based cleavages by new value-based ones.

Of course, an adoption of the postmaterialist agenda by left parties may be a process that has been taking place during the period of observation. If the “greening of the Left” just started in the 1970s, then the effect of postmaterialism should not be constant but increasing. In that case, however, the explanatory power of value change cannot be tested by a comparison of predicted changes with observed changes as in table 3. An examination of the changes among materialists and postmaterialists would be more appropriate instead. One should then expect that in countries where class voting has been declining, labor parties have been losing support mainly among materialist workers while simultaneously gaining support mainly from postmaterialist middle-class voters. As figure 6 shows, this type of change does not occur in any of the countries under study.

Class, value priorities, and the support for Labor parties, 1976–1994

In Denmark, France, and the Netherlands, labor parties have lost at least as much support among postmaterialist as among materialist members of the working class. In Great Britain, the labor party has hardly lost support among materialist members of the working class, but has gained support among postmaterialist members. Furthermore, Great Britain is the only country where the support for a labor party has increased among postmaterialist members of the middle classes. Although, consistent with Inglehart's ideas, the support for labor parties is much higher among postmaterialist members than among materialist members of the middle classes, this support has decreased overall in Denmark, France, the Netherlands, and West Germany, with the exception of the Danish salariat. Ironically, the relevance of value priorities for the support for labor parties has decreased in the middle classes of these countries. Furthermore, since in the Netherlands and West Germany the decline in support for labor parties among postmaterialists is stronger in the middle classes than in the working class, class voting has increased among postmaterialists in these countries.

To conclude, neither the direct displacement scenario, nor the greening of the left scenario, nor the split-within-the-middle-classes scenario, nor the irrelevance-of-value-change scenario is borne out completely by the results presented in this section. The changes that have occurred in West European countries may be more complex than envisioned in any of the scenarios discussed thus far. For example, in some countries, a greening of the left may have occurred in the early 1970s, but may have been reversed by the split of the New Left from traditional labor parties and the emergence of green parties, such as in West Germany. Also another type of change, completely independent from the process of value change, may have occurred. Labor parties, realizing that their traditional working class constituency was shrinking, have been moderating their socialist stances and trying to appeal to middle-class voters on materialist grounds. The transformation of the British Labour Party under Tony Blair's leadership is a prime example of this process.

Conclusion

Reports of the death of social cleavages are exaggerated.55

I am indebted to one of the reviewers who coined this phrase.

While the consequences of class positions seem to have weakened in some of the countries, the consequences of the division between religious and secular people have not. If changes in the relation between voters' social characteristics and party choice are not universal, but rather limited to one type of social division and to only some countries, a general transformation of Western publics by cognitive mobilization or value change can hardly be the sole cause. Value change may have played some part in the changes affecting class voting, but it has not been leading to a displacement of old socially-based cleavages by new value-based cleavages.

Those who claim that class voting is in general decline have often been criticized either for ignoring or for too easily writing off the central role of political parties' ideologies and strategies.56

For example, Mair et al. 1999.

But it is a truism that parties are not just passive, immutable objects of voters' attitudes and evaluations; they are actively seeking their support.57

Evans 2000; Kitschelt 1994; Przeworski and Sprague 1986; Sartori 1969.

In doing so, parties take on issue positions and propose policies that may affect voters with different social characteristics in different ways. Therefore, parties' actions in competition for votes make a difference for the relevance of social cleavages. One may follow Converse, who in 1958 noted that “the impact of status on vote decision is dependent on the degree to which the political parties proffer clear and equally polarized policy alternatives”58

Converse 1958, 397.

and conclude that observable changes in class voting can be attributed to parties' political actions and other political factors. In fact, recent evidence provided by Evans, Heath, and Payne clearly emphasizes that parties' actions in the competition for votes have consequences for the level of class voting.59

See also Evans, Heath, and Payne 1999.

Great Britain is obviously one of the countries where the clearest changes in class voting have occurred. But the history of the Labour and Conservative parties in Great Britain is an unambiguous story of programmatic changes; compare the convergence of early post-war consensus about welfare expansion with the ideological polarization of the 1970s and 1980s and with the reorientation of the Labour party in the late 1990s under the “New Labour” branding. Under the leadership of Tony Blair, the British Labour Party gave up the aim of nationalizing major industries, and even accepted parts of the Thatcher agenda of welfare-state retrenchment. These are changes exemplary of a tendency towards ideological moderation in most European labor parties after World War II, followed by further moderations after the fall of the Iron Curtain. Nevertheless, the extent to which parties change their platforms is the outcome of political decisions by party leaders, as well as the result of internal struggles within parties. Thus, platform changes may vary across countries, and this provides quite a natural explanation of the cross-country variation in the development of class voting presented in the analyses of this article.

My main argument is that changes in the electoral relevance of social cleavages—insofar as they have actually occurred—are unlikely to be aspects or consequences of an irreversible, large-scale, long-term process of social change. Rather, it is only natural to attribute cross-country variations in the development of class and religious–secular voting to contingent political choices of parties about which social groups to appeal to. This seems to be bad news for social science, as it reduces the prospects for any long-term predictions. Alternatively, if political factors play a major role in changing patterns of electoral behavior, this could very well be considered to be good news for political science. Future research on changing patterns in the relation between social structure and electoral behavior should therefore focus on questions such as the identification of those dimensions of issues that are the most effective in producing group differences in electoral behavior.60

Mair et al. 1999; Evans 2000.

There are already examples of such work. Chhibber and Torcal show how electoral strategies of major parties led to the re-emergence of a class cleavage in voting behavior after the end of the Franco regime in Spain.61

Chhibber and Torcal 1997.

Nieuwbeerta and Ultee use measures of “class as a political issue” (from Lane and Ersson) in order to test various approaches to explaining cross-country differences in the levels and trends of manual/non-manual class voting.62

Nieuwbeerta and Ultee 1999; Lane and Ersson 1994.

Evans, Heath, and Payne find evidence for an effect of party competition on class voting by comparing measures of association between class and vote with measures of party polarization along an economic left-right scale derived from data of the Comparative Manifesto Project.63

Evans, Heath, and Payne 1999; Budge et al. 2001.

I also find that, using Comparative Manifesto Project data, changes in class voting can be predicted quite well on the basis of parties' electoral platforms, as reported elsewhere.64

Elff 2005.

Although the combined analysis of data on electoral platforms and on voting behavior poses considerable methodological challenges, it seems to open up promising avenues of future research.

Appendix: Predicting Changes in Class Voting

Major parts of the argument of this article are based on the comparison of predictions about changes in class voting generated from the effect of cognitive mobilization and of value change on class voting to observed changes in class voting. This appendix briefly describes the method used for this type of analysis.

As a first step, a random-effects logit model of the influence of cognitive mobilization or of value change is constructed and fitted to respondents' vote intentions. Such a model contains, for example, the main effects of class and of value priorities as well as the interaction effect of class and value priorities on respondents' vote intentions. While such a model implies that the effect of value priorities on class voting is constant, it does not imply any restrictions on the over-time development of value priorities—value priorities are an external variable of this model. As a second step, expected vote intentions are computed from such a predictor model. As a third step, a model of change in class voting is fitted to these expected vote intentions. Such a target model contains the main effects of time and of class as well as the interaction effect of both time and class on respondents' vote intentions. As a fourth step, the target model is fitted to the observed vote intentions. Finally, estimates for the target model based on expected vote intentions and on observed vote intentions are compared, by means of Cox's extended Wald-statistics.65

Cox 1961.

If, for example, there is no statistically significant difference between observed changes in class voting and changes in class voting predicted on the bose of the effect of value changes, one may conclude that changes in class voting are adequately explained by value change. If differences between observed changes in class voting and predicted changes in class voting are statistically significant and substantial, then value change alone cannot account for these changes. This procedure is repeated for each country under study. Details on this procedure can be obtained from the supplemental material to this article, which can be found at the author's homepage (http://webrum.uni-mannheim.de/sowi/elff/.

References

Achen, Christopher H. 2002. Parental Socialization and Rational Party Identification. Political Behavior 24 (2): 15170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andeweg, Rudolf B. 1982. Dutch Voters Adrift: On Explanations of Electoral Change 1963–1977. Leiden: Rijksuniversiteit Leiden.Google Scholar
Berelson, Bernard R., Paul F. Lazarsfeld, and William N. McPhee. 1954. Voting: A Study of Opinion Formation in a Presidential Campaign. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Beyme, Klaus von. 1985. Political Parties in Western Democracies. Aldershot: Gower.Google Scholar
Brooks, Clem, and Jeff Manza. 1997. Social cleavages and political alignments: U. S. presidential elections, 1960 to 1992. American Sociological Review 62 (4): 93746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broughton, David, and Hans-Martien ten Napel. 2000. Religion and Mass Electoral Behaviour in Europe. London and New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budge, Ian, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Judith Bara, Eric Tanenbaum et al. 2001. Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945–98. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Chhibber, Pradeep, and Mariano Torcal. 1997. Elite strategy, social cleavages, and party systems in a new democracy: Spain. Comparative Political Studies 30: 2754.Google Scholar
Clark, Terry Nichols, and Vincent Hoffman-Martinot, eds. 1998. The New Political Culture. Boulder, CO: Westview.Google Scholar
Clark, Terry Nichols, and Seymour Martin Lipset. 1991. Are social classes dying? International Sociology 6 (4): 397410.Google Scholar
Clark, Terry Nichols, and Seymour Martin Lipset. 1993. The declining political significance of class. International Sociology 8 (3): 397410.Google Scholar
Clark, Terry Nichols, and Seymour Martin Lipset. 2001. The Breakdown of Class Politics: A Debate on Post-Industrial Stratification. Washington, Baltimore, and London: Woodrow Wilson Center Press und Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Converse, Philip E. 1958. The shifting role of class in political attitudes and behavior. In Readings in Social Psychology, ed. Eleanor E. Maccoby, Theodore M. Newcomb, and Eugene L. Hartley. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Cox, D. R. 1961. Tests of separate families of hypotheses. In Proceedings of the Fourth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, vol. 1, ed. Jerzy Neyman. Berkeley and CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Dalton, Russel J. 1984. Cognitive mobilization and partisan dealignment in advanced industrial democracies. Journal of Politics 46 (1): 26484.Google Scholar
Dalton, Russel J. 2002a. Citizen Politics in Western Democracies: Public Opinion and Political Parties in Advanced Industrial Democracies. 3d ed. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House Publishers.Google Scholar
Dalton, Russel J. 2002b. Political cleavages, issues, and electoral change. In Comparing Democracies 2. New Challenges in the Study of Elections and Voting, ed. Lawrence Le Duc, Richard G. Niemi, and Pippa Norris. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Dalton, Russell J., Scott C. Flanagan, and Paul Allen Beck. 1984. Electoral Change: Realignment and Dealignment in Advanced Industrial Democracies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dalton, Russell J., and Martin P. Wattenberg. 1993. The not so simple act of voting. In Political Science. The State of the Discipline II, ed. Ada Finifter. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association.Google Scholar
De Graaf, Nan Dirk, Anthony Heath, and Ariana Need. 2001. Declining cleavages and political choices: The interplay of social and political factors in the Netherlands. Electoral Studies 20 (1): 115.Google Scholar
De Graaf, Nan Dirk, Paul Nieuwbeerta, and Anthony Heath. 1995. Class mobility and political preference: Individual and contextual effects. American Journal of Sociology 100 (4): 9971027.Google Scholar
Dogan, Mattei. 1995. Erosion of class voting and of the religious vote in Western Europe. International Social Science Journal 146: 52538.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Elff, Martin. 2005. Ideology, social cleavages, and voting behavior: Party manifestos and voter responses in European countries in the postwar era. Paper presented at the ECPR General Conference, Corvinus University of Budapest, Hungary, September 8–10.Google Scholar
Evans, Geoffrey. 1999. The End of Class Politics? Class Voting in Comparative Context. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Evans, Geoffrey. 2000. The continued significance of class voting. Annual Review of Political Science 3: 40117.Google Scholar
Evans, Geoffrey, Anthony Heath, and Clive Payne. 1999. Class: Labour as a catch-all party? In Critical Elections. British Parties and Voters in Long-Term Perspective, ed. Geoffrey Evans and Pippa Norris. London, Thousand Oakes, New Delhi: Sage.Google Scholar
Franklin, Mark N., Thomas T. Mackie, Henry Valen et al. 1992. Electoral Change: Response to Evolving Social and Attitudinal Structures in Western Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Goldthorpe, John H. 1982. On the service class: Its formation and future. In Social Class and the Division of Labour, ed. Anthony Giddens and G. Mackenzie. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Goldthorpe, John H. 1995. The service class revisited. In Social Change and the Middle Classes, ed. Tim Butler and Mike Savage. London: UCL Press.Google Scholar
Heath, Anthony, Roger Jowell, John Curtice, and Geoff Evans. 1990. The rise of the new political agenda? European Sociological Review 6 (1): 3148.Google Scholar
Heath, Anthony F., Roger Jowell, and John Curtice. 1985. How Britain Votes. Oxford: Pergamon Press.Google Scholar
Hollis, Martin. 1994. The Philosophy of Social Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hout, Michael, Clem Brooks, and Jeff Manza. 1995. The democratic class struggle in the United States, 1948–1992. American Sociological Review 60 (6): 80528.Google Scholar
Huckfeldt, R. Robert. 1984. Political loyalties and social class ties: The mechanisms of contextual influence. American Journal of Political Science 28 (2): 399417.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald. 1977. The Silent Revolution: Changing Values and Political Styles in Western Publics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald. 1979. The impact of values, cognitive level, and social background. In Samuel H. Barnes, Max Kaase et al. Political Action: Mass Participation in Five Western Democracies. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald. 1984. The changing structure of political cleavages in Western society. In Electoral Change: Realignment and Dealignment in Advanced Industrial Democracies, ed. Russel J. Dalton, Scott C. Flanagan, and Paul Allen Beck. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald. 1990. Culture Shift in Advanced Industrial Society. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald. 1997. Modernization and Postmodernization: Cultural, Economic, and Political Change in 43 Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald, and Jacques René Rabier. 1986. Political realignment in advanced industrial society: From class-based politics to quality-of-life politics. Government and Opposition 21 (4): 45779.Google Scholar
Irwin, Galen A., and Joop van Holsteyn. 1997. Where to go from here? Revamping electoral politics in the Netherlands. West European Politics 20 (2): 93118.Google Scholar
Kitschelt, Herbert P. 1994. The Transformation of European Social Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Knutsen, Oddbjørn. 1995. Party choice. In The Impact of Values. Beliefs in Government Volume Four, ed. Jan W. van Deth and Elinor Scarbrough. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Korpi, Walter. 1974. Some problems in the measurement of class voting. American Journal of Sociology 78 (3): 62742.Google Scholar
Kotler-Berkowitz, Laurence A. 2001. Religion and voting behaviour in Great Britain: A reassessment. British Journal of Political Science 31 (3): 52354.Google Scholar
Kriesi, Hanspeter. 1998. The transformation of cleavage politics: The 1997 Stein Rokkan lecture. European Journal of Political Research 33 (2): 16585.Google Scholar
Lane, Jan-Erik, and Svante Ersson. 1994. Politics and Society in Western Europe. 3d ed. London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Lane, Jan-Erik, and Svante Ersson. 1997. Parties and voters: What creates the ties? Scandinavian Political Studies 20 (2): 17996.Google Scholar
Lazarsfeld, Paul F., Bernard Berelson, and Hazel Gaudet. 1968 [1948]. The People's Choice: How the Voter Makes up His Mind in a Presidential Campaign. 3d ed. New York and London: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1981. Political Man: The Social Basis of Politics. Expanded edition. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Lipset, Seymour Martin, and Stein Rokkan. 1967. Cleavage structures, party systems, and voter alignments: An introduction. In Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-National Perspectives, ed. Seymour Martin Lipset and Stein Rokkan. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Lupia, Arthur, and Mathew D. McCubbins. 1998. The Democratic Dilemma: Can Citizens Learn What They Need To Know? Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lybeck, Johan A. 1985. Is the Lipset-Rokkan hypothesis testable? Scandinavian Political Studies 8 (1–2): 10513.Google Scholar
Madeley, John. 1982. Politics and the pulpit: The case of Protestant Europe. West European Politics 5 (2): 14971.Google Scholar
Madeley, John. 1991. Politics and religion in Western Europe. In Politics and Religion in the Modern World, ed. George Moyser. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Mair, Peter. 1999. The freezing hypothesis: An evaluation. In Party Systems and Voter Alignments Revisited, ed. Lauri Karvonen and Stein Kuhnle. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Mair, Peter, Seymour Martin Lipset, Michael Hout, and John H. Goldthorpe. 1999. Critical commentary: Four perspectives on the end of class politics. In The End of Class Politics? Class Voting in Comparative Context, ed. Geoffrey Evans. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mair, Peter, and Cas Mudde. 1998. The party family and its study. Annual Review of Political Science 1: 21129.Google Scholar
Manza, Jeff, and Clem Brooks. 1997. The religious factor in U. S. presidential elections, 1960–1992. American Journal of Sociology 103 (1): 3881.Google Scholar
Manza, Jeff, and Clem Brooks. 1999. Social Cleavages and Political Change: Voter Alignments and U.S. Party Coalitions. Oxford: Oxford University, Press.Google Scholar
Manza, Jeff, Michael Hout, and Clem Brooks. 1995. Class voting in capitalist democracies since World War II: Dealignment, realignment, or trendless fluctuation? Annual Review of Sociology 21: 13762.Google Scholar
Morlino, Leonardo. 1996. Crisis of parties and change of party system in Italy. Party Politics 2 (1): 530.Google Scholar
Nieuwbeerta, Paul. 1996. The democratic class struggle in postwar societies: Class voting in twenty countries, 1945–1990. Acta Sociologica 39 (4): 34583.Google Scholar
Nieuwbeerta, Paul, and Wout Ultee. 1999. Class voting in Western industrialized countries, 1945–1990: Systematizing and testing explanations. European Journal of Political Research 35 (1): 12360.Google Scholar
Norris, Pippa. 2000. A Virtuous Circle: Political Communications in Postindustrial Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prior, Markus. 2005. News vs. entertainment: How increasing media choice widens gaps in political knowledge and turnout. American Journal of Political Science 49 (3): 57792.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, and John Sprague. 1986. Paper Stones: A History of Electoral Socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 1995. Tuning in, tuning out: The strange disappearance of social capital in America. PS: Political Science & Politics 28 (4): 664683.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 2000. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Robertson, David. 1976. Surrogates for party identification in the rational choice framework. In Party Identification and Beyond, ed. Ian Budge, Ivor Crewe, and Dennis Farlie. London and New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Rohrschneider, Robert. 1993. New party versus Old Left realignments: Environmental attitudes, party policies, and partisan affiliations in four West European countries. Journal of Politics 55 (3): 682701.Google Scholar
Rose, Richard, and Derek W. Urwin. 1969. Social cohesion, political parties and strains in regimes. Comparative Political Studies 2 (1): 767.Google Scholar
Sartori, Giovanni. 1969. From the sociology of politics to political sociology. In Politics and the Social Sciences, ed. Seymour Martin Lipset. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Van Deth, Jan W., and Martin Elff. 2004. Politicisation, economic development and political interest in Europe. European Journal of Political Research 47 (3): 477508.Google Scholar
Van Holsteyn, Joop J. M., and Galen A. Irwin. 2000. The bells toll no more: The declining influence of religion on voting behaviour in the Netherlands. In Religion and Mass Electoral Behaviour in Europe, ed. David Broughton and Hans-Martien ten Napel. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ware, Alan. 1996. Political Parties and Party Systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Weakliem, David L., and Anthony F. Heath. 1994. Rational choice and class voting. Rationality and Society 6 (2): 24370.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Class and support for labor parties, 1995–2002

Figure 1

Church attendance and support for Christian and conservative parties, 1990–1994

Figure 2

Class differences regarding the support for labor parties, working class versus salariat 1975–2002

Figure 3

Class differences regarding the support for labor parties, working class versus self-employed, 1975–2002

Figure 4

Class and support for labor parties, 1975–2002

Figure 5

Differences between weekly churchgoers and non-churchgoers regarding the support for Christian parties, 1975–1994

Figure 6

Church attendance and support for Christian and conservative parties, 1975–1994

Figure 7

Predicted and observed trends in class voting and associated Cox-test statistics

Figure 8

Class, value priorities, and the support for Labor parties, 1976–1994

Supplementary material: Link
Link