Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-10T23:54:43.897Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Entertainment Spending and Capturing Value from Innovation in Chinese Firms

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 March 2022

Guoguang Wan
Affiliation:
Nanjing University, China
Luqun Xie*
Affiliation:
Shanghai Jiaotong University, China
Jiatao Li
Affiliation:
Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Hong Kong
Dequan Jiang
Affiliation:
Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, China
*
Corresponding author: Luqun Xie (xieluqun0710@sjtu.edu.cn)
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This study examines how Chinese firms capture value from their innovations. We propose that relationship-building through business entertainment may be helpful. In particular, wining and dining key stakeholders, including clients, suppliers, distributors, and government officials, can help firms gain access to complementary resources necessary for commercializing their innovations, facilitating capturing value from innovations. However, business entertainment is less effective in regions with relatively developed market-supporting institutions, including factor markets and legal institutions. The analysis results of archival data and data from a World Bank survey of Chinese firms support all the above arguments.

摘要

本研究考察了中国企业是否可以通过商务招待的方法促进其创新产品的商业化并获取价值。我们假设通过商务招待(主要指宴请活动)与利益相关者,包括客户、供应商、分销商和政府官员--建立关系,可以帮助企业获得将其创新商业化所需的互补资源,促进从创新中获取价值。但是,在要素市场和法律制度等市场支持机构相对发达的地区,商务招待效果较差。通过对中国上市公司制造型企业在2009-2017数据的分析,以及世界银行对中国企业的调查数据的分析,我们发现结果支持上述所有论点。

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of The International Association for Chinese Management Research

INTRODUCTION

Theory and practice suggest that innovation can generate economic value because innovation resources are usually valuable, rare, and difficult to imitate or substitute, contributing to a firm's sustained competitive advantages (Barney, Reference Barney1991; Schumpeter, Reference Schumpeter1934). However, firms’ ability to capture value from their innovation resources may vary (He & Wang, Reference He and Wang2009; Qian, Wang, Geng, & Yu, Reference Qian, Wang, Geng and Yu2017; Teece, Reference Teece1986). One stream of research emphasizes that firms must maintain access to complementary resources, such as specialized manufacturing capability, access to distribution channels, service networks, and complementary technologies, if they are to capture maximum value from their innovations (King, Covin, & Hegarty, Reference King, Covin and Hegarty2003; Teece, Reference Teece1986, Reference Teece2006). In developed economies, firms can access such resources by dealing with market transactions and contracting resource holders through acquisitions or in-house development. However, emerging economies tend to have institutional voids – weak or absent market-supporting institutions, such as factor markets for firms to obtain technology, labor, and capital, and legal institutions to support legal enforcement of contracts (Khanna & Palepu, Reference Khanna and Palepu1997, Reference Khanna and Palepu1999; Li & Qian, Reference Li and Qian2013). In turn, firms in emerging economies may have difficulty obtaining access to the complementary resources they need. Thus, filling institutional voids is crucial for firms seeking complementary resources to capture value from innovation.

The institution-based view suggests that when market-supporting institutions are not well-developed, firms tend to depend on social relationships and connections with different stakeholders to secure their access to resources (Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015; Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik, & Peng, Reference Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik and Peng2009; Peng, Reference Peng2002; Peng & Luo, Reference Peng and Luo2000; Song, Ai, & Li, Reference Song, Ai and Li2015; Zhang, Marquis, & Qiao, Reference Zhang, Marquis and Qiao2016). These relationships are often personal connections of firm managers with other firms or government officials that can bring competitive corporate advantages (Luo & Chen, Reference Luo and Chen1997; Park & Luo, Reference Park and Luo2001; Peng & Luo, Reference Peng and Luo2000). Studies in China show that high-quality customer relationship management (Yan, Li, & Zhang, Reference Yan, Li and Zhang2021), close relationships with suppliers (Jean, Sinkovics, & Hiebaum, Reference Jean, Sinkovics and Hiebaum2014), and good relationships with distributors (Wang & Kess, Reference Wang and Kess2006) facilitate knowledge acquisition and exchange, promoting product innovations. Moreover, political connections affect firms’ research and development (R&D) investment (Zhou, Gao, & Zhao, Reference Zhou, Gao and Zhao2016), innovation outputs (Chung, Yen, & Wang, Reference Chung, Yen and Wang2020; Li, Xia, & Zajac, Reference Li, Xia and Zajac2018; Zhang, Qi, Wang, Zhao, & Pawar, Reference Zhang, Qi, Wang, Zhao and Pawar2019; Zhou et al., Reference Zhou, Gao and Zhao2016), and the efficiency of their innovation efforts (Song et al., Reference Song, Ai and Li2015). However, how such relationships help firms capture value from their innovations has received only limited scholarly attention.

As firms typically need to invest before obtaining valuable resources (Barney, Reference Barney1986), they may also need to cultivate relationships before exploiting them (Park & Luo, Reference Park and Luo2001). In the current study, we show how firms’ investments in relationships influence the value they can capture from innovation. We focus on one of the most prevalent relationship-building practices in China: business entertainment. Spending on business entertainment generally takes in drinking, dining, and gift-giving. Accordingly, we assume that such entertainment practices build relationships between firms and their key business partners and government officials (Cai, Fang, & Xu, Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011; Fung, Xu, & Zhang, Reference Fung, Xu and Zhang2007; Zhang & Fung, Reference Zhang and Fung2006). The resulting relationships provide access to complementary resources, helping firms commercialize and capture value from their innovations. A CEO from a high-tech firm stated in the interview that ‘the contract law cannot guarantee that suppliers supply materials with premium quality as promised in the contract. If not, then final innovating products lead to failure and thus bring great loss to us. Nothing but good relationships can guarantee a premium material supply offered in time as indicated in the contract’.

The institutional environment can vary among regions, especially in a vast economy, such as China. Some of them inevitably have weaker market-supporting institutions than others. The institution-based view of business predicts less reliance on social relationships and connections where market-supporting institutions are well-developed (Peng, Reference Peng2003). Consequently, entertainment spending should be less effective in such regions (Khanna & Palepu, Reference Khanna and Palepu1997; North, Reference North1990) as firms depend on the institutions for maintaining their access to complementary resources (Mair, Marti, & Ventresca, Reference Mair, Marti and Ventresca2012). When factor markets that provide labor, capital, and technology are well-developed, firms can conveniently obtain and develop the complementary resources they need. Well-developed legal institutions, which guarantee contract enforcement, can also help ensure contract fulfillment. Accordingly, the positive moderating effect of entertainment spending on the relationship between innovation and firm performance should be weak in regions with well-developed factor markets and legal institutions.

We examine the above assumptions using data from China, where firms have devoted substantial effort to innovation in recent years (Ang, Cheng, & Wu, Reference Ang, Cheng and Wu2014; Song et al., Reference Song, Ai and Li2015; Xie & Li, Reference Xie and Li2013, Reference Xie and Li2015). At the same time, relationship-building is rooted in the Chinese culture and remains a pervasive business practice (Chen, Chen, & Huang, Reference Chen, Chen and Huang2013; Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015). Given that institutional development is unequal among regions in China (Fan & Wang, Reference Fan and Wang2006; Yiu, Xu, & Wan, Reference Yiu, Xu and Wan2014), it is a good context for evaluating the utility of relationship-building. We use a dataset of Chinese publicly listed firms and a complementary dataset of responses to a World Bank survey to examine our hypotheses and test some intermediate mechanisms. The results empirically support our arguments.

Through this study, we aim to contribute to the conversation about how firms capture value from their innovations, particularly in emerging economies. Scholars generally discussed value appropriation in developed economies (e.g., Cohen, Nelson, & Walsh, Reference Cohen, Nelson and Walsh2000; Czarnitzki & Toole, Reference Czarnitzki and Toole2011), paying limited attention to the emerging economy situation (Zhang, Li, Hitt, & Cui, Reference Zhang, Li, Hitt and Cui2007) and not fully considering the role of relationships. Our study responds to a call from prior research (James, Leiblein, & Lu, Reference James, Leiblein and Lu2013) for further exploration of the value-appropriation mechanisms involved in exploiting innovations in different institutional contexts. We contribute to their effort by exploring how entertainment spending helps Chinese firms capture value from innovation.

In summary, existing studies examined how inter-department social relationships within a firm foster the success of R&D projects (Perks, Kahn, & Zhang, Reference Perks, Kahn and Zhang2009) or how relationships with external stakeholders affect firms’ R&D investment decisions, innovation performance, and innovation efficiency (Chung et al., Reference Chung, Yen and Wang2020; Li et al., Reference Li, Xia and Zajac2018; Song et al., Reference Song, Ai and Li2015; Zhou et al., Reference Zhou, Gao and Zhao2016). Using a new perspective, we determine how relationships help firms capture value from their innovations.

THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND HYPOTHESES DEVELOPMENT

Institutional Difficulties Experienced by Chinese Firms in Capturing Value from Innovation

Chinese firms have substantially increased their R&D investment since China joined the World Trade Organization in 2001 (Huang & Li, Reference Huang and Li2019). They have become more aware of the significance of innovation than before due to increased competition from foreign firms (Serger & Breidne, Reference Serger and Breidne2007). China's National Bureau of Statistics reported that the R&D spending of Chinese firms in 2014 was approximately nine times that in 2004 – the first time that the R&D spending of Chinese firms surpassed the mean of the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development countries. Moreover, the number of Chinese patent applications through the Patent Cooperation Treaty burgeoned to the third-largest worldwide in 2014.

Innovation can generate competitive advantage and economic value for firms because innovation resources are valuable, rare, and difficult to imitate or substitute (Barney, Reference Barney1991; Schumpeter, Reference Schumpeter1934). However, firms’ lack of access to complementary resources often prohibits them from capturing value from innovations (King et al., Reference King, Covin and Hegarty2003; Teece, Reference Teece1986, Reference Teece2006). The problem of access to complementary resources is especially salient in China due to the economy's institutional voids and its weak institutions (Acemoglu & Johnson, Reference Acemoglu and Johnson2005; Khanna & Palepu, Reference Khanna and Palepu1999; Li, Reference Li2013; Li & Xie, Reference Li and Xie2011). For example, innovating firms often face unfair evaluations from financial institutions, constricting their access to credit and impeding their late-stage commercialization efforts, such as in-house manufacturing and the acquisition of requisite complementary resources (Maine & Garnsey, Reference Maine and Garnsey2006; Meyer et al., Reference Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik and Peng2009). The weak contract enforcement in China also leads to ineffective contracts and high transaction costs for innovating firms (Li & Xie, Reference Li and Xie2016; Peng, Lee, & Wang, Reference Peng, Lee and Wang2005; Taussig & Delios, Reference Taussig and Delios2015; Zhou, Poppo, & Yang, Reference Zhou, Poppo and Yang2008). In the current study, the CEO of a high-tech firm confirmed in the interview that cheating on contracts is quite common. Thus, if a firm wants to internalize the complementary resources it needs (e.g., by acquiring a firm), such transactions need legal protection to deal with any conflicts and disputes.

Consequently, Chinese firms may fail to capture value from their innovations, and the relationship between their innovation and performance may not be positive. Thus, they should overcome the problem of weak supporting institutions to capture value from innovation. Entertainment may provide a solution.

Entertainment and Guanxi

Entertainment activities, such as wining and dining, remain prevalent relationship-building practices in China (Cai et al., Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011; Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015). Li (Reference Li2003: 88) has explained that ‘[to] be invited to sing karaoke [sic] is a sign of acceptance; it means that the Chinese are willing to reveal more of themselves to you, and it is an excellent way to establish close relations’. Mutual disclosure facilitates personal bonding and perhaps even emotional attachment (Li, Reference Li2003; Nguyen & Rose, Reference Nguyen and Rose2009; Nguyen, Weinstein, & Meyer, Reference Nguyen, Weinstein and Meyer2005). Good personal relationships, guanxi, are gradually formed by investing in entertainment activities (Collins, Reference Collins2014). This tradition is a typical dynamic in emerging economies (Cai et al., Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011; Ferrary, Reference Ferrary2003; Nguyen & Rose, Reference Nguyen and Rose2009).

Vietnamese firm managers develop inter-firm relationships with their partners by putting great effort into personal interactions, such as attending partners’ family events, drinking, and information sharing (Nguyen et al., Reference Nguyen, Weinstein and Meyer2005; Nguyen & Rose, Reference Nguyen and Rose2009). In China, business entertainment predominates (Cai et al., Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011; Fung et al., Reference Fung, Xu and Zhang2007; Zhang & Fung, Reference Zhang and Fung2006). For example, Cai et al. (Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011) estimated that a firm's investment in entertainment could be as high as 3% of its profits. Tung and Worm (Reference Tung and Worm1997) asked Chinese managers to rank the importance of relationship-building techniques. The responses were inviting executives on an all-expense-paid trip, entertaining executives by throwing parties, and giving modest gifts. The general manager of a high-technology firm in Shanghai observed that ‘in China, dining is a common method to make friends, understand business partners, and establish interpersonal relationships. Dinner banquets also allow for effective communication, as well as the exchange of feelings and ideas. Through dining together, two people can close the distance between themselves by understanding each other's personality, preferences, business background, needs, strengths, reputation, and other important [facts] pertinent to business. The Chinese people's tradition of emotional exchanges over a meal will continue to be preserved and maintained’. The general manager of an arts and crafts firm maintained that ‘[in accordance with] the ancient folk customs of the Chinese people, only close relatives and friends would sit together at the table to share a delicious meal. [In] business, [when] one is dining with clients, suppliers, or local officials, it is natural to want to build and strengthen relationships. When two people [can] act as friends, treating each other with honesty and respect, it is much easier to achieve effective connections and communications. As the saying goes, “if two people cannot even eat a single meal together, how will they be able to converse as like-minded fellows?” Thus, the traditional significance of the word “eat” in Chinese often indicates relationships between several people. In China, if two parties must remain unrelated, even over a dinner table, it will be impossible to develop a deeper relationship’.[Footnote 1]

Thus, the personal relationship between a firm's managers and key individuals in other organizations, such as firms and governments, guanxi, formed through business entertainment can affect organizational outcomes. In particular, guanxi as a source of social capital is a strategic tool that helps organizations build trust, acquire useful resources, and generally facilitate business operations (Hoskisson, Eden, Lau, & Wright, Reference Hoskisson, Eden, Lau and Wright2000; Park & Luo, Reference Park and Luo2001; Peng & Heath, Reference Peng and Heath1996; Xin & Pearce, Reference Xin and Pearce1996). Peng and Luo (Reference Peng and Luo2000) categorized guanxi into two domains: personal ties between a firm's managers and those of business partner firms, such as suppliers, buyers, and competitors, and personal ties between a firm's managers and government officials, often in relevant regulatory agencies. In the following section, we illustrate how guanxi can help firms capture value from innovations.

Guanxi and Capturing Value from Innovation

Innovation can contribute substantially to firm performance, but such a contribution usually depends on access to the complementary resources needed to commercialize the innovations (Teece, Reference Teece1986, Reference Teece2006; Wang & Chen, Reference Wang and Chen2010; Wang, He, & Mahoney, Reference Wang, He and Mahoney2009; Zhang et al., Reference Zhang, Li, Hitt and Cui2007). When effective economic and legal institutions are inadequate, which is common in China, good relationships with external stakeholders can be crucial in exploiting a firm's innovations for better performance. Good relationships with business partners can best ensure access to necessary complementary resources to some extent. For example, manufacturing partners can provide the required manufacturing technology, and distributors can pave the way into target markets. Strong relationships with them can reduce the risk of being extorted or cheated by such partners and the cost of drafting, negotiating, and monitoring contracts with them (Adler, Reference Adler2001; Dyer & Singh, Reference Dyer and Singh1998; Reuer & Arino, Reference Reuer and Arino2007).

Strong relationships with business partners can sometimes yield timely access to accurate and useful market information generally unavailable (Heide & John, Reference Heide and John1992). Such access can improve forecasting and timing (e.g., of a new product launch). Timely and reliable information can guide firms in selecting the best target markets and improving product quality (Poppo & Zenger, Reference Poppo and Zenger2002). Overall, good relationships facilitate resource and knowledge inflows (Rindfleisch & Moorman, Reference Rindfleisch and Moorman2001; Saxenian, Reference Saxenian1996; Uzzi, Reference Uzzi1997), leading to efficient commercialization of innovations and high innovation profitability.

In China, government relationships are particularly vital. Government relationships can provide a firm with protection and access to valuable resources (Peng & Luo, Reference Peng and Luo2000; Xin & Pearce, Reference Xin and Pearce1996; Zhang et al., Reference Zhang, Marquis and Qiao2016). For example, firms sometimes need government approval before internalizing complementary resources (Yan & Chang, Reference Yan and Chang2018). Financing can also be crucial for commercializing innovations as firms need to invest in complementary resources, such as manufacturing capability and distribution channels. Likewise, good government relationships can be useful, as evident in China. Specifically, bank loans can be supported by a government guarantee or mandated by government fiat (Allen, Qian, & Qian, Reference Allen, Qian and Qian2005; Haveman, Jia, Shi, & Wang, Reference Haveman, Jia, Shi and Wang2017; Zheng, Singh, & Chung, Reference Zheng, Singh and Chung2015). Although the law cannot fully protect firms in contracting, friendly government agencies may serve as powerful mediators to enforce formal contracts (Taussig & Delios, Reference Taussig and Delios2015). When partners have disputes, firms often turn to their government contacts to resolve the conflict in their favor as costly lawsuits are best avoided in emerging economies. Therefore, good relationships with the government are essential for innovative firms to capture value from innovation.

All of these effects make entertainment spending necessary for innovative firms. Following Andersson, Cuervo-Cazurra, and Nielsen's (Reference Andersson, Cuervo-Cazurra and Nielsen2014) suggestions on delineating interaction effects, we try to rule out the alternative argument that innovation may moderate the relationship between entertainment spending and firm performance. Entertainment spending builds social capital and may enhance access to resources and/or information, fostering improved performance (Luo & Chen, Reference Luo and Chen1997; Park & Luo, Reference Park and Luo2001). Yet, arguing that innovative firms benefit more from such social capital than less innovative ones is unreasonable. Firms can reduce their costs independently, improving their performance by exploiting resources and information obtained from social capital without innovating.

Following prior literature on value capture or appropriation from innovation (Qian et al., Reference Qian, Wang, Geng and Yu2017; Wang & Chen, Reference Wang and Chen2010), we use the increase in firm performance to reflect its value captured from innovation. Thus, we propose the following hypothesis:

Hypothesis 1: Business entertainment spending positively moderates the relationship between innovation and economic performance, which becomes stronger at higher levels of entertainment spending.

Influence of Market-Supporting Institutions

The institution-based view of business suggests that entertainment spending will be effective depending on developing market-supporting institutions and existing institutional voids (Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015; Meyer et al., Reference Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik and Peng2009; Peng, Reference Peng2002, Reference Peng2003). Such voids and weaknesses are common in emerging markets. The term ‘market-supporting institutions’ takes a wide range of elements, such as the labor market, the capital market, product markets, and legal institutions (Khanna & Palepu, Reference Khanna and Palepu1997, Reference Khanna and Palepu1999). However, even in an emerging market, institutional development varies across regions. In China, institutions in Shanghai and Guangdong Province are well-developed compared with those in the west (Fan & Wang, Reference Fan and Wang2006; Li & Qian, Reference Li and Qian2013). Strong market-supporting institutions ‘support the voluntary exchange underpinning an effective market mechanism’, whereas weak ones ‘fail to ensure effective markets or even undermine markets’ (Meyer et al., Reference Meyer, Estrin, Bhaumik and Peng2009: 63). Such regional differences affect the extent to which firms must rely on relationships to obtain access to complementary resources helpful for capturing value from their innovations.

First, we tackle the development of regional market-supporting institutions, including factor markets (e.g., financial market) and legal institutions (e.g., legal enforcement of contract). Then, we propose arguments on how they manage the effects of entertainment spending on the relationship between innovation and firm performance as follows.

Development of Factor Markets

In regions where factor markets are well-developed, firms can conveniently access the complementary resources they need. When the market for technology resources is well-developed, firms’ transaction costs caused by information asymmetry regarding a technology's value are low. Thus, they can conveniently obtain such complementary technology resources (Lichtenthaler, Reference Lichtenthaler2013; Nell & Lichtenthaler, Reference Nell and Lichtenthaler2011). When the financial market is well-developed and places fewer constraints on external financing, firms can reliably obtain any financing they need to acquire or build complementary resources, such as distribution and service networks (Rahaman, Reference Rahaman2011). When the equity market is well-developed, innovative firms with intangible assets of little value as collateral can still have equity financing with little collateral required (Hsu, Tian, & Xu, Reference Hsu, Tian and Xu2014).

When factor markets are poorly developed, firms may have difficulty accessing complementary resources through conventional channels. When the market for complementary technology is underdeveloped, information asymmetry tends to increase a firm's transaction costs in battling it. Similarly, in regions where the financial markets are less developed, firms may face unfair evaluations. In such circumstances, they may instead rely on business partners or a government agency to help them obtain loans (Peng, Reference Peng2002; Peng & Luo, Reference Peng and Luo2000). On the basis of the above discussion, we propose that the effects of relationships on the innovation–performance relationship may be weakened as a region's factor markets develop.

Hypothesis 2: The positive moderating effect of entertainment spending on the relationship between innovation and firm performance will be weaker in regions where factor markets are well developed.

Development of Legal Institutions

Legal institutions establish an order to which business activities in an economy must conform (North, Reference North1990). They set constraints designed to avoid dysfunctional competition and other harmful practices (Acemoglu & Johnson, Reference Acemoglu and Johnson2005; Acemoglu, Johnson, & Robinson, Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2005; Khanna & Palepu, Reference Khanna and Palepu1997; Liu & Li, Reference Liu and Li2019). In China, legal institutions are unevenly distributed across regions (Fan & Wang, Reference Fan and Wang2006; Yiu et al., Reference Yiu, Xu and Wan2014). In regions where legal institutions are well-developed, such institutions can protect the contracts between innovative firms and business partners (Beim & Calomiris, Reference Beim and Calomiris2003; Peng & Heath, Reference Peng and Heath1996; Williamson, Reference Williamson1992). Thus, innovative firms can count on receiving the complementary technology and services as they expect. When innovative firms establish a contractual relationship with their partners in their value chains, a well-developed legal enforcement system can guarantee contract fulfillment. In such a situation, good relationships with government officials are less necessary for resolving contractual disputes.

Well-developed legal institutions should provide comprehensive intellectual property rights (IPR) protection for innovative firms (Guo, Zou, Zhang, Bo, & Li, Reference Guo, Zou, Zhang, Bo and Li2020; Yan et al., Reference Yan, Li and Zhang2021; Zhao, Reference Zhao2006). Firms do not rely on relationships with government functionaries to protect them if their IPRs are violated. Well-developed IPR protection can also facilitate technology transactions (Arora, Reference Arora1995; Arora & Gambardella, Reference Arora, Gambardella, Hall and Rosenberg2010). Through them, firms can conveniently obtain complementary technology resources and capture value from innovation. Thus, well-developed legal institutions should weaken the need for relationships to ensure access to complementary resources (Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015; Peng & Luo, Reference Peng and Luo2000; Song et al., Reference Song, Ai and Li2015). In turn, the effects of entertainment spending on the innovation–performance relationship will be weakened by developing legal institutions.

In regions where legal institutions are poorly developed, relationships still have ample room to play a role. Therefore, they remain crucial for firms to build relationships with stakeholders through business entertainment. For such cases in which enforcing the contract between a firm and its distributors is difficult through the legal system, good government relations become extremely helpful. In turn, the effects of entertainment spending on the innovation–performance relationship can be strong.

Hypothesis 3: The positive moderating effect of entertainment spending on the relationship between innovation and firm performance will be weaker in regions with well-developed legal institutions.

METHODS

Sample and Data

We tested our hypotheses using data covering all manufacturing firms listed publicly on China's stock exchanges from 2009 to 2017 (cf. Zhou et al., Reference Zhou, Gao and Zhao2016). We lagged the independent variables by one year in the analyses. Thus, the values of the independent variables were from 2008 to 2016. We selected and analyzed this period because data describing vital moderators, such as the development of factor markets and legal institutions, were only available for that period.[Footnote 2] The firms considered were all those in the following two-digit sub-sectors of the standard industrial classification system of China's Securities Regulatory Commission: textiles and garments, food and beverages, wood and furniture, paper and printing, metals and metalloids, petrochemicals and plastics, electronics, machinery, pharmaceuticals, and others.

We obtained patenting and financial information from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database. The CMSAR is a commonly used database in many empirical studies of Chinese businesses (e.g., Li & Qian, Reference Li and Qian2013; Xia, Ma, Lu, & Yiu, Reference Xia, Ma, Lu and Yiu2014). We collected information on the development of factor market and legal institutions by region from publications of the National Economic Research Institute (NERI; Wang, Fan, & Hu, Reference Wang, Fan and Hu2018). Chinese publicly listed firms disclose business entertainment and travel expenses in their annual reports (Cai et al., Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011; Xu, Zhou, & Du, Reference Xu, Zhou and Du2019). They usually disclose this information as part of ‘Other cash flows related to operating activities’ but sometimes detailed it under ‘Management expenses’. In the current study, we compared the two sections, if available, for consistency and omitted conflicting reports.[Footnote 3] After combining these data and removing records with missing values, we obtained an unbalanced panel of 1,748 firms with 9,214 firm-year observations.[Footnote 4]

Dependent Variables

The dependent variable was return on assets (ROA) computed as net profit divided by total assets at the end of the fiscal year (Wang, Choi, & Li, Reference Wang, Choi and Li2008).

Independent Variables

The primary independent predictor was innovation quantified as the natural logarithm of the total number of valid invention patents owned by a firm plus one. We assumed successful patenting to capture each firm's innovation effort productivity irrespective of commercialization (Ahuja & Katila, Reference Ahuja and Katila2001; Zhou et al., Reference Zhou, Gao and Zhao2016). Given that our focus was value capture from innovation, valid patents owned by a firm confer potentially valuable property rights, so we took their number as a close proxy (Kamien & Schwartz, Reference Kamien and Schwartz1982; Scherer & Ross, Reference Scherer and Ross1990).

Moderating Variables

The entertainment spending variable included entertainment and travel expenses scaled by total firm assets. It was the principal moderating variable. We assumed the reported spending to include networking expenditures related to clients and suppliers and any managerial excesses and bribery (Cai et al., Reference Cai, Fang and Xu2011; Xu et al., Reference Xu, Zhou and Du2019). Following the lead of Xu et al. (Reference Xu, Zhou and Du2019), we partialled out irrelevant components, such as managerial perks, bribery, and employee expenditure, by regressing each firm's entertainment spending against an indicator of regional corruption, the number of a firm's employees, and the total compensation of its three highest-paid managers. We retained the residual as the moderator for hypothesis testing.[Footnote 5] Finally, we quantified regional corruption as the number of individuals involved in prosecuted cases of corruption, bribe-taking, or breach of duty as a percentage of the region's total population.

We quantified the development of factor markets variable using the average of three NERI regional indices: marketization of the financial industry, technical achievements, and the supply of human capital. The NERI publishes such indices for 31 provinces, municipalities, and autonomous regions annually. The financial industry index's marketization reflects the level of market competition in the financial industry and the extent to which credit is allocated on the basis of regional market principles. The supply of human capital index refers to technicians, managers, and skilled labor in a region. The technical achievements index's marketization is based on the value of regional technology transactions (Wang et al., Reference Wang, Fan and Hu2018). The details can be found in Supplementary Appendix I.

Finally, we quantified the development of legal institutions variable using the average of two NERI legal protection indices: legal protection for market transactions and protection of IPR in a region (Wang et al., Reference Wang, Fan and Hu2018). The NERI also publishes them annually. The higher the index, the more protection the legal system provides to contract enforcement and IPR. The details can be found in Supplementary Appendix II.

Control Variables

Governance structure can control the agency behavior of top managers to some extent. In turn, it can influence firm performance (Eisenhardt, Reference Eisenhardt1989; Fama, Reference Fama1980; Jensen & Meckling, Reference Jensen and Meckling1976). Accordingly, we included CEO duality in the analyses, represented by a dummy variable equal to one when a firm's CEO also chaired the board; otherwise, it was zero (Dowell, Shackell, & Stuart, Reference Dowell, Shackell and Stuart2011; Finkelstein, Reference Finkelstein1992). We calculated the blockholder ownership variable as the percentage of shares held by shareholders who each owned more than 5% of a company's shares (Thomsen, Pedersen, & Kvist, Reference Thomsen, Pedersen and Kvist2006).

We quantified firm size as the natural logarithm of a firm's total assets at the end of its fiscal year, given that size might affect firm performance through economies of scale or scope (Roberts & Dowling, Reference Roberts and Dowling2002). Firm age was the natural logarithm of the number of years since a firm's birth. Older firms tend to have greater inertia, affecting their performance (Barnett & Salomon, Reference Barnett and Salomon2006). We computed the financial leverage variable as total debt as a fraction of total assets (Barnett & Salomon, Reference Barnett and Salomon2006; Seifert, Morris, & Bartkus, Reference Seifert, Morris and Bartkus2004). We quantified the financial slack variable as a firm's total cash flow from operations, investments, and financing activities divided by its total assets (Seifert et al., Reference Seifert, Morris and Bartkus2004). Slack resources also influence firm performance (Tan & Peng, Reference Tan and Peng2003; Voss, Sirdeshmukh, & Voss, Reference Voss, Sirdeshmukh and Voss2008). We defined the R&D intensity variable as a firm's R&D spending divided by its total sales in a particular year. This variable reflects a firm's investment in innovation, which they hope will eventually affect the firm value (Qian et al., Reference Qian, Wang, Geng and Yu2017). We quantified the internationalization variable as a firm's foreign sales divided by its total sales in a particular year (Denis, Denis, & Yost, Reference Denis, Denis and Yost2002). International sales help a firm pursue and maintain sustainable competitive advantages, affecting firm performance (Hitt, Bierman, Uhlenbruck, & Shimizu, Reference Hitt, Bierman, Uhlenbruck and Shimizu2006; Nachum & Zaheer, Reference Nachum and Zaheer2005). We set state ownership as a dummy variable, equal to one if a firm described itself in the database as state-owned; otherwise, it was zero. State-owned firms often have more resources than private firms in China (Xia et al., Reference Xia, Ma, Lu and Yiu2014), influencing their performance. Finally, we included year industry indicator variables[Footnote 6] in all of the regression models.

Estimation Method

Given that a firm's innovation may be affected by factors affecting its performance, we evaluated a two-stage least squares fixed effects estimator with instrument variables to handle the endogeneity issue (Mayer, Stadler, & Hautz, Reference Mayer, Stadler and Hautz2015; Wooldridge, Reference Wooldridge2001). The first-stage model was to handle the endogeneity related to innovation and its interaction terms, and the second-stage model was for hypothesis testing. We employed the xtivreg2 command in the Stata software suite version 15.0 to execute the two-stage regression (Mayer et al., Reference Mayer, Stadler and Hautz2015; Schaffer, Reference Schaffer2015).

We set regional innovation as an instrumental variable in the first-stage regressions predicting the number of valid patents owned by a firm because regional innovation practices might sometimes constitute an institutional context affecting a firm's innovation efforts (DiMaggio & Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983; Meyer & Rowan, Reference Meyer and Rowan1977; Xie & Li, Reference Xie and Li2018). We evaluated the number of valid patents owned by the publicly listed firms in a province before a fiscal year separately for each Chinese province where a firm had its headquarters. Previous research on the relationship between innovation and performance in China also employed regional innovation as an instrument for firm innovation (Qian et al., Reference Qian, Wang, Geng and Yu2017).

We also instrumented several endogenous interaction terms associated with firm innovation in the models. One was an interaction between firm innovation and entertainment spending. The interactions between firm innovation and factor market development and legal institution development were another two. We also created terms referring to interaction among firm innovation, entertainment spending, and factor market development and legal institution development. We instrumented them by the interaction between regional innovation and entertainment spending, between regional innovation and factor market development, and between regional innovation and legal institution development. The interaction among regional innovation, entertainment spending, and factor market development was another predictor, as was the interactions among regional innovation, entertainment spending, and legal institution development (Wooldridge, Reference Wooldridge2001). Finally, we included other control variables in both stages.

RESULTS

Table 1 presents a correlation matrix along with the means and the standard deviations of all variables. Firm innovation had a mean of 1.55 and a standard deviation of 1.41, and the residual value of entertainment spending had a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 0.01. Although some significant correlations existed among the variables, all of the variance inflation factors were less than 2.00, and the mean was 1.34, suggesting that multicollinearity was not a serious issue (O'Brien, Reference O'Brien2007).

Table 1. Summary statistics and correlations describing the variables

Notes: N = 9,214. Correlations with an absolute value of 0.03 or greater are significant at the p ≤ 0.05 confidence level.

ROA, return on assets; SD, standard deviation.

Table 2 reports some key coefficients of the first-stage regressions. M1 includes all of the predictors of firm innovation. The key variables were mean-centered before generating interaction terms as recommended by Aiken and West (Reference Aiken and West1991). The coefficient of the instrument, the regional innovation term, was positive and significant (coefficient = 0.162, p = 0.000, standard error [s.e.] = 0.028). Holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase in regional innovation predicts a 0.946 increase in firm innovation indicated by the number of valid invention patents owned by a firm. M2 includes all the predictors and the interaction between firm innovation and entertainment spending. The coefficient of the instrument, the term representing an interaction between regional innovation and entertainment spending, was positive and significant (coefficient = 0.633, p = 0.000, s.e. = 0.015). Holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase in regional innovation * entertainment spending predicted a 0.01 increase in firm innovation * entertainment spending. M3 includes all the predictors and a term representing an interaction among firm innovation, entertainment spending, and factor market development. The coefficient of the instrument, the term representing an interaction among regional innovation, entertainment spending, and factor market development, was positive and significant (coefficient = 0.855, p = 0.000, s.e. = 0.016). Holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase in regional innovation * entertainment spending * development of factor markets predicted a 0.03 increase in firm innovation * entertainment spending * development of factor markets. M4 includes all the predictors and the interaction among firm innovation, entertainment spending, and legal institutions development. The coefficient of the instrument, the term representing interaction among regional innovation, entertainment spending, and legal institution development, was positive and significant (coefficient = 0.813, p = 0.000, s.e. = 0.019). Holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase in regional innovation * entertainment spending * development of legal institutions predicted a 0.067 increase in firm innovation * entertainment spending * development of legal institutions. The validity of instrumental variables comprised two aspects: relevance and exogeneity (Kennedy, Reference Kennedy2008). The Cragg–Donald Wald F statistics for most models were larger than 10, indicating strong and relevant instrumental variables (Semadeni, Withers, & Trevis Certo, Reference Semadeni, Withers and Trevis Certo2014). However, we could not examine exogeneity of the instrumental variables because the test requires multiple instruments (Kennedy, Reference Kennedy2008). In particular, the number of instruments needs to be larger than the number of endogenous variables. Accordingly, we employed regional education investment as an additional instrument in the robust test (Qian et al., Reference Qian, Wang, Geng and Yu2017) and obtained similar empirical results.

Table 2. Key coefficients of first-stage firm fixed effects models predicting firm innovation and its interaction terms

Notes: N = 9,214. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and p-values in brackets.

A coefficient significant at the *p ≤ 0.05 (p ≤ 0.1, **p ≤ 0.01, ***p ≤ 0.001) confidence level.

M1 did not show any significant predictive power for a firm's innovation of R&D intensity, state ownership, or entertainment spending. Because the dependent variable is a firm's total number of valid patents, R&D intensity in any one year may not significantly affect such a patent stock. In addition, prior research has demonstrated a double-edged relationship between state ownership and innovation (Zhou et al., Reference Zhou, Gao and Zhao2016). On the one hand, state-owned firms have abundant resources to invest in R&D and other innovation. On the other hand, they may misallocate the resources, resulting in inefficient innovation efforts. So, the overall relationship between state ownership and firm innovation is unclear. Similarly, entertainment spending may help a firm obtain resources and thus facilitate innovation, but on the other hand, it may nurture a relationship-oriented culture in which a firm focuses unduly on relationship-building and puts less emphasis on innovation. Such contradictory tendencies may lead to a relationship between entertainment spending and firm innovation which is not very significant overall. In models 2–4, the interaction terms were instrumented for econometric reasons (Wooldridge, Reference Wooldridge2001), so it is reasonable to observe coefficients that are not significant.

Table 3 shows the second-stage empirical results, and the key variables were mean-centered before generating interaction terms as recommended by Aiken and West (Reference Aiken and West1991). Model A1 includes the control variables and firm innovation. The results suggested that the number of a firm's valid patents did not solely significantly predict ROA in Chinese firms. Model A2 adds one interaction term. The term coefficient representing an interaction between innovation and entertainment spending was 0.670, positive and significant (p = 0.003, s.e. = 0.225). When entertainment spending was one standard deviation above the mean, holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase in patents predicted a 190.17% increase in ROA (from 0.004 to 0.012). When entertainment spending was one standard deviation below the mean, holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase in innovation predicted a 67.20% decrease in ROA (from −0.004 to −0.007). Such a decrease in ROA was aligned with Teece's (Reference Teece1986) arguments that innovators may lose if they cannot appropriate the value of their innovations. For example, if they do not possess complementary assets, imitators who have them will capture the value of innovations. Given that the cost of R&D is not trivial, the firm performance of the innovators may suffer. We could apply such logic in China, where the legal protection for innovations may not be that perfect. Figure 1 illustrates this situation, where ‘high’ and ‘low’ are defined as one standard deviation above and below the mean of entertainment spending, respectively. When the level of entertainment spending was high, the number of patents was positively related to ROA, supporting H1.

Figure 1. The moderating role of entertainment spending on the relationship between patents and return on assets (ROA)

Table 3. Coefficients of second-stage firm fixed effects models predicting return on assets (ROA)

Notes: N = 9,214. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and p-values in brackets.

A coefficient significant at the *p ≤ 0.05 (**p ≤ 0.01, ***p ≤ 0.001) confidence level.

Model A3 adds the three-way moderating effect of factor market development, and its coefficient was negative and significant (coefficient = −0.183, p = 0.048, s.e. = 0.093), supporting H2. When the level of development of factor markets in a region was one standard deviation below the mean, a one standard deviation increase in patents predicted a 27.99% (from −0.005 to −0.004) and a 431.06% (from 0.003 to 0.018) increase in ROA. The former and the latter were observed when the level of entertainment spending was one standard deviation below and above the mean. Accordingly, the effectiveness of drinking and dining was salient in regions with underdeveloped factor markets.

When the level of development of factor markets in a region was one standard deviation above the mean, a one standard deviation increase in patents predicted a 158.94% (from −0.007 to 0.004) and a 168.56% (from 0.008 to 0.018) increase in ROA. The former and the latter were observed when the level of entertainment spending was one standard deviation below and above the mean. On the basis of this result, Figure 2 plots the effect size.

Figure 2. The three-way interaction of the level of development of factor markets with entertainment spending and return on assets (ROA)

Model A4 adds the three-way moderating effect of the development of regional legal institutions. The coefficient of the three-way interaction term was negative and significant (coefficient = −0.072, p = 0.035, s.e. = 0.034), supporting H3. When the level of development of a region's legal institutions was one standard deviation below the mean, a one standard deviation increase in patents predicted a 38.57% (from −0.005 to −0.003) and a 284.62% (from 0.005 to 0.018) increase in ROA. The former and the latter were observed when the level of entertainment spending was one standard deviation below and above the mean. Thus, the effectiveness of drinking and dining was also salient in regions with underdeveloped legal institutions.

However, when the level of development of a province's legal institutions was one standard deviation above the mean, a one standard deviation increase in patents predicted a 91.82% (from −0.005 to −0.000) and a 225.30% (from 0.005 to 0.016) increase in ROA. The former and the latter were observed when the level of entertainment spending was one standard deviation above the mean. Figure 3 plots these effects. In addition, these relationships have been graphed in Supplementary Appendices III–VI. In each case, the y-axis is ROA (firm performance) and the x-axis is the firm innovation measure. Supplementary Appendix III depicts the full sample with all of the observations. Supplementary Appendix IV splits the sample into two sub-samples based on the level of entertainment spending. Supplementary Appendices Va and Vb split the sample into four sub-samples based on the level of entertainment spending and the level of development of factor markets. Supplementary Appendices VIa and VIb split the sample into four sub-samples based on the level of entertainment spending and the development of legal institutions in a region. The graphs were generally consistent with the hypotheses.

Figure 3. Three-way interaction of the level of development of legal institutions with entertainment spending and return on assets (ROA)

In Table 3, neither firm age, financial leverage, CEO duality, internationalization, development of factor markets, development of legal institutions, nor firm innovation significantly predicts firm performance. While older firms often have more slack resources which may contribute to better performance (Sharfman, Wolf, Chase, & Tansik, Reference Sharfman, Wolf, Chase and Tansik1988), they also tend to have greater inertia which may dampen their performance (Hannan & Freeman, Reference Hannan and Freeman1984; Ranger-Moore, Reference Ranger-Moore1997). That may to some extent explain the lack of any significant relationship between firm age and firm performance. More financial leverage exposes a firm to closer monitoring, which might tend to improve performance (Jensen, Reference Jensen1986), but high leverage entails significant financial limitations which may dampen performance (Berger & Di Patti, Reference Berger and Di Patti2006). That may explain the lack of any significant relationship of financial leverage with performance. Academics tend to condemn CEO duality because it weakens monitoring, potentially threatening performance (Rediker & Seth, Reference Rediker and Seth1995). But on the other hand, one-man decision-making can have speed and decisiveness benefits in an uncertain environment (Boyd, Reference Boyd1995; Dowell et al., Reference Dowell, Shackell and Stuart2011). So CEO duality may not affect firm performance in any consistent way. Internationalization too would be expected to entail both benefits and costs, so it too showed no consistent predictive power for firm performance. Multinationals can normally benefit from economies of scale and scope, better access to resources, and perhaps superior technology (Hennart, Reference Hennart2007) but those advantages only counteract the serious liabilities of newness and foreignness with which they must deal (Hymer, Reference Hymer1976; Lu & Beamish, Reference Lu and Beamish2004). So internationalization too is not a consistent predictor. The state of development of a region's factor markets and legal institutions are certainly important as they provide abundant resources and good legal environment for firms (Khanna & Palepu, Reference Khanna and Palepu1997, Reference Khanna and Palepu1999), but again their relationships with ROA are not significant. Note too that with a firm fixed effects model specification the variances of the two regional development indexes can be too small to explain the within-firm variance of ROA. For the insignificant effect of innovation variable on ROA, as we analyzed above, innovative firms may face institutional difficulties in capturing value from their innovations in China, so innovation output may in many cases not be a predictor of good firm performance.

In addition, the unexplained variance (48%) in Table 3 suggests that there may be other processes acting which account for some of the unexplained variances. A larger market share may increase a firm's profitability by increasing its economies of scale and market power (Buzzell, Gale, & Sultan, Reference Buzzell, Gale and Sultan1975; Gale, Reference Gale1972). In addition, location may affect firm performance in China, as regional differences can influence the resources a firm can obtain and the cost of a firm's business activities (Chan, Makino, & Isobe, Reference Chan, Makino and Isobe2010; Choi, Jiang, & Shenkar, Reference Choi, Jiang and Shenkar2015). Market share (a firm's sales as a percentage of total industry sales) and region dummies were therefore added to the models. This led to an increase of 0.008 in R 2. The details are reported in Supplementary Appendix VII. The 47% unexplained variance in firm performance is consistent with the findings of prior research (Misangyi, Elms, Greckhamer, & Lepine, Reference Misangyi, Elms, Greckhamer and Lepine2006; Rumelt, Reference Rumelt1991).

To test the robustness of the above results, we computed an alternative measure of firm innovation using the total number of invention patents granted to a firm in the most recent three years. The results using the alternative measures also supported Hypothesis 1 (H1), Hypothesis 2 (H2), and Hypothesis 3 (H3). Next, we tested entertainment spending scaled by total sales as an alternative measure of entertainment spending, and the results were similar. Then, we employed the NERI's general market development index encompassing all market dimensions as an alternative in predicting the effect of entertainment spending, and the results were again similar. Finally, we employed regional education investment as an additional instrument (Qian et al., Reference Qian, Wang, Geng and Yu2017), and the empirical results generally remained.

SUPPLEMENTARY STUDY

Relationships with stakeholders may contribute to a firm's innovation (Zhang & Li, Reference Zhang and Li2010) without necessarily contributing to commercialization. Accordingly, we performed a post hoc empirical analysis to test this effect to determine how relationship-building might help Chinese firms gain access to complementary resources. In this analysis, we used data from a World Bank Enterprise Survey. The survey was published in 2005 and has been frequently used in academic research (Cull & Xu, Reference Cull and Xu2005; Iriyama, Kishore, & Talukdar, Reference Iriyama, Kishore and Talukdar2016). The survey's initial sample size was 12,400 Chinese firms. After removing observations with missing values, we obtained a sample with 9,214 observations.

Here, long-term collaboration with clients was a dependent variable, measured by the tenures of the relationships. The original survey asked, ‘…[the] number of years of cooperation between your company and your wholesalers and retailers’. We measured the long-term collaboration with suppliers variable similarly. We set access to financial resources as a dummy variable, equal to one if a firm said it received favorable treatment from financial institutions; otherwise, it was zero. In particular, they answered the survey question, ‘does your company enjoy favorable terms on overdraft[s] or have loan quotas'? Access to legal contract/property protection was another dependent variable describing the extent to which firms said they enjoyed legal protection for their contracts or property. The original survey asked, ‘in commercial or other legal disputes, [in] what percent of cases were your company's legal contracts or properties protected (a favorable verdict was passed and enforced)'? We assumed a high value to indicate good access to legal protection. The four variables indicated firms’ ability to obtain access to resources complementary to innovation. For example, if a firm has long-term collaborations with large wholesalers or suppliers, it may easily access market channels or technology for commercializing its innovations. If a firm has ‘favorable terms on overdraft[s] or…loan quotas', it may easily obtain access to financing for promoting its innovations. Fair verdicts passed and enforced in a firm's legal disputes may also help a firm acquire complementary resources (such as distribution channels) for its innovative products.

We also used entertainment spending as the independent variable of interest. However, it was the natural logarithm of entertainment expenses because no total assets data were available from the survey. In this part of the study, the control variables were financial performance (measured by return on total fixed assets), firm size (the natural logarithm of the total number of employees), firm age, and state ownership.[Footnote 7]

Tables 4 and 5 present the results. Table 4 shows the summary statistics and correlations. All of the variance inflation factors were below 2, indicating that multicollinearity was again not a serious concern (O'Brien, Reference O'Brien2007).

Table 4. Summary statistics and correlations describing the World Bank data

Notes: N = 9,456. Correlations with an absolute value of 0.02 or greater are significant at the p ≤ 0.05 confidence level.

Table 5. Coefficients of models with the World Bank data testing for mechanisms

Notes: N = 9,456. Standard errors are reported in parentheses and p-values in brackets.

A coefficient significant at the *p ≤ 0.05 (†p≤0.1,**p ≤ 0.01, ***p ≤ 0.001) confidence level.

Table 5 reports the regression results. The models with long-term collaboration with clients or suppliers as the dependent variable were OLS models, the model with access to financial resources as the dependent variable was a logit model, and the last model was a Tobit model. The results indicated that relationship-building was positively and significantly associated with long-term collaboration with clients (coefficient = 0.106, p = 0.000, s.e. = 0.010), long-term collaboration with suppliers (coefficient = 0.116, p = 0.000, s.e. = 0.009), access to financial resources (coefficient = 0.279, p = 0.000, s.e. = 0.017), and access to legal protection for contracts or property (coefficient = 0.994, p = 0.008, s.e. = 0.373). In M1, holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase in entertainment spending predicted a 0.20 increase in long-term collaboration with clients. In M2, holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase in entertainment spending predicted a 0.22 increase in long-term collaboration with suppliers. In M3, again holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase from the mean in entertainment spending predicted an increase in the odds ratio from 0.35 (probability = 0.26) to 0.60 (probability = 0.37). In other words, the probability of obtaining financial resources has increased by about 50% with more lavish entertainment spending. The marginal effects were also tested in the Tobit model (M4).[Footnote 8] Holding the other variables constant, a one standard deviation increase from the mean in entertainment spending predicted a 1.65 increase in cases in which a company's legal contractual rights or property were protected as a percentage of total cases.

There is a substantial unexplained variance in the models of Table 5. That is probably due to a lack of industry information, but there can be other alternative explanations. When CEO tenure, CEO tenure squared, and a customized products variable were added to M1, CEO tenure displayed an inverted U-shaped relationship with the relationship between the firm and its customers (Luo, Kanuri, & Andrews, Reference Luo, Kanuri and Andrews2014). The explanation could be that in the early stages of a new CEO's tenure he or she is actively learning about customer needs, and in that process, firm-customer relationships gradually improve. In the late stages of a CEO's tenure, a CEO may become more and more inclined to stick to certain learned paradigms. If so, the firm has difficulty keeping up with changing customer demands, resulting in firm-customer relationships less warm than they might be. Customized products encourage customer loyalty (Dewan, Jing, & Seidmann, Reference Dewan, Jing and Seidmann2003; Murthi & Sarkar, Reference Murthi and Sarkar2003) and a long-term relationship between a firm and its customer. So, customized products as a percentage of all products were also tested as a predictor. Including these explanatory variables increased the M1's R 2 from 0.136 to 0.165. CEO tenure and CEO tenure squared were also added to M2, tenure again showed an inverted U-shaped relationship with firm-supplier relationship quality, leading to an increase in R 2 from 0.132 to 0.165. The post hoc analysis is reported in Supplementary Appendix VIII.

DISCUSSION

Our results generally support the argument that relationship-building through entertainment helps Chinese firms capture value from their innovations. In line with our expectations, relationship-building is less effective in regions with well-developed factor markets and legal institutions. These findings offer new insights into value capture from innovation, a crucial matter for scholars and firm managers. They demonstrate the enduring relevance of wining and dining in contexts where profiting from innovation can be difficult with weak institutions.

To sum up, this study contributes to business scholarship as follows. First, our findings contribute to the literature, which can be dated back to the early Yale studies (Levin, Klevorick, Nelson, Winter, Gilbert, & Griliches, Reference Levin, Klevorick, Nelson, Winter, Gilbert and Griliches1987) and business scholars at Carnegie Mellon University (Cohen et al., Reference Cohen, Nelson and Walsh2000), who focused on the appropriability of firm innovation. However, their large-sample surveys were performed in the US and Japan, both developed economies. Following the efforts of Zhang et al. (Reference Zhang, Li, Hitt and Cui2007), we extend such work to a different context with underdeveloped factor markets and legal institutions and illuminate a channel for value capture from innovation in an emerging economy. Consistent with previous findings, we highlight the critical role of complementary resources in innovation success (Alvarez & Barney, Reference Alvarez and Barney2001; King et al., Reference King, Covin and Hegarty2003). Moreover, we emphasize that relationship-building, which results from business entertainment spending, remains a vital channel for Chinese firms to obtain complementary resources.

Scholars examined different types of resource bundles and their effects on firm performance (Brush & Artz, Reference Brush and Artz1999; Sirmon & Hitt, Reference Sirmon and Hitt2009) but ignored the bundle of innovation supplemented by relational resources, especially in emerging markets. Thus, in the present study, we demonstrate the joint effects of innovation and relationships in terms of economic benefit. Previous research suggested that social capital is a necessary component of a firm's dynamic capability to acquire complementary resources (Blyler & Coff, Reference Blyler and Coff2003). Through our findings, we further demonstrate how social capital provides access to resources needed to complement innovation, helping firms improve their value capture from innovation.

We also extend the scholarly understanding of entertainment spending (Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015; Nguyen & Rose, Reference Nguyen and Rose2009). Although eating, drinking, singing karaoke, and gift-giving sometimes are considered helpful tactics in China (Fung et al., Reference Fung, Xu and Zhang2007; Zhang & Fung, Reference Zhang and Fung2006), our findings demonstrate that their effectiveness varies depending on the institutional environment. Some scholars suggested that relationship-building can be a double-edged sword for firms (Adler, Reference Adler2001; Dyer & Singh, Reference Dyer and Singh1998; Marquis & Raynard, Reference Marquis and Raynard2015; Opper, Nee, & Holm, Reference Opper, Nee and Holm2017; Poppo & Zenger, Reference Poppo and Zenger2002). However, in the innovation context, the risks may be worth taking specifically as a complement to a firm's primary activities.

Limitations and Future Research Implications

This study may have suffered from certain limitations that suggest avenues for future research. First, the substantial unexplained variances in the regression models suggest scope for alternative, competing theories. We have tested some explanatory variables such as market share, region dummies, CEO tenure, and customized products in the supplementary study, but there certainly may be others. Future studies might fruitfully explore other important factors in the Chinese context. For example, the current literature has not paid enough attention to the effect of Chinese culture on a firm's value capture from innovation. As important elements of Chinese culture, Buddhist teachings emphasize a long-term orientation (Du, Reference Du2013; Liu, Xu, Zhou, & Li, Reference Liu, Xu, Zhou and Li2019). Therefore, firms under strong Buddhist influence may be engaged in innovations with long-term impacts which may generate value for firms continuously. Also, entertainment may help Chinese firms capture value from internationalization (Li & Wan, Reference Li and Wan2016; Li, Tian, & Wan, Reference Li, Tian and Wan2015).

Then, the information on total entertainment spending offered does not offer a lot of detail. Detailed spending on different stakeholder domains would offer a clearer picture of the relationships explored in this study. For example, some firms may spend primarily on entertaining their customers, while others may spend a lot on building relationships with government officials or suppliers. Probing the detailed expenses may help elucidate the mechanisms involved. To date, no published research has attempted such detailed analysis. So this is a promising area for future research. Moreover, other than monetary expense, relationship-building requires significant time and effort. Future research may expand relationship-building with more comprehensive measures to strengthen these findings.

These findings have established that relationship-building helps a firm capture value from its innovations in China, entertainment spending per se can only be viewed as a lubricant. Excessive entertainment spending will leave fewer resources for other investments. Also, emphasis on relationship-building may direct a firm's attention away from innovation, because relationship-building can directly enhance firm performance in general (Luo & Chen, Reference Luo and Chen1997). Thus, although this study did not explore such possible drawbacks of entertainment spending, any firm should strike a balance between entertainment spending and other productive uses of its limited resources. Future studies might consider investigating that balance and the trade-offs in greater detail.

Finally, the three-way moderators were evaluated using a higher regional level than the other firm-level variables, so some cross-level issues may intrude (Andersson et al., Reference Andersson, Cuervo-Cazurra and Nielsen2014). However, integrating two-stage least squares with cross-level techniques is difficult. Scholars can explore this possibility too in the future.

In conclusion, the results generally support the argument that entertainment spending helps a firm capture more value from its innovations. But it is less effective in regions with well-developed factor markets and legal institutions.

Supplementary Material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/mor.2021.65

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Replication code for this article has been published in Open Science Framework at: https://osf.io/bsxd6/

Footnotes

ACCEPTED BY Senior Editor Can Huang

The authors thank Jun Xia, Tony Tong, Mike Peng, and seminar participants at the Hong Kong University of Science & Technology and Nanjing University for their valuable comments and suggestions. Guoguang Wan acknowledges financial support from China's National Natural Science Foundation (Grant No. 7197099 and No. 71632005). Luqun Xie acknowledges financial support from China's National Natural Science Foundation (Grant No. 72002127). Jiatao Li acknowledges financial support from the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong (HKUST#16507219). Dequan Jiang gratefully acknowledges financial support from China's National Natural Science Foundation (Grant No. 71632006) and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (No. 2019110043). The four authors have contributed equally.

[2] The indices before 2008 were of different statistical specifications from those after, so we only used the post-2008 indices.

[3] We omitted less than 1% of observations for this reason.

[4] Replication data and code for this study are available at Open Science Framework at: https://osf.io/bsxd6/

[5] We also tested the original measure of entertainment spending as a moderator, and the empirical results were similar. These results are available on request.

[6] Some firms changed industry affiliation during the sampling period.

[7] No industry information was available from the survey, so we did not include industry effects.

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D., & Johnson, S. 2005. Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5): 949995.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. 2005. Institutions as the fundamental cause of long-run growth. Handbook of Economic Growth, 1(1): 385472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, P. S. 2001. Market, hierarchy, and trust: The knowledge economy and the future of capitalism. Organization Science, 12(2): 215234.Google Scholar
Ahuja, G., & Katila, R. 2001. Technological acquisitions and the innovation performance of acquiring firms: A longitudinal study. Strategic Management Journal, 22(3): 197220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aiken, L. S., & West, S. G. 1991. Multiple regression: Testing and interpreting interactions. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Allen, F., Qian, J., & Qian, M. 2005. Law, finance, and economic growth in China. Journal of Financial Economics, 77(1): 57116.Google Scholar
Alvarez, S. A., & Barney, J. B. 2001. How entrepreneurial firms can benefit from alliances with large partners. Academy of Management Perspectives, 15(1): 139148.Google Scholar
Andersson, U., Cuervo-Cazurra, A., & Nielsen, B. 2014. From the editors: Explaining interaction effects within and across levels of analysis. Journal of International Business Studies, 45(9): 10631071.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ang, J. S., Cheng, Y., & Wu, C. 2014. Does enforcement of intellectual property rights matter in China? Evidence from financing and investment choices in the high-tech industry. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(2): 332348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arora, A. 1995. Licensing tacit knowledge: Intellectual property rights and the market for know-how. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 4(1): 4159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arora, A., & Gambardella, A. 2010. The market for technology. In Hall, B. H. & Rosenberg, N. (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of innovation: 641678. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Barnett, M. L., & Salomon, R. M. 2006. Beyond dichotomy: The curvilinear relationship between social responsibility and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 27(11): 11011122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. B. 1986. Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and business strategy. Management Science, 32(10): 12311241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1): 99120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beim, D. O., & Calomiris, C. W. 2003. Emerging financial markets. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Berger, A. N., & Di Patti, E. B. 2006. Capital structure and firm performance: A new approach to testing agency theory and an application to the banking industry. Journal of Banking & Finance, 30(4): 10651102.Google Scholar
Blyler, M., & Coff, R. W. 2003. Dynamic capabilities, social capital, and rent appropriation: Ties that split pies. Strategic Management Journal, 24(7): 677686.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyd, B. K. 1995. CEO duality and firm performance: A contingency model. Strategic Management Journal, 16(4): 301312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brush, T. H., & Artz, K. W. 1999. Toward a contingent resource-based theory: The impact of information asymmetry on the value of capabilities in veterinary medicine. Strategic Management Journal, 20(3): 223250.3.0.CO;2-M>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buzzell, R. D., Gale, B. T., & Sultan, R. G. 1975. Market share - A key to profitability. Harvard Business Review, 53(1): 97106.Google Scholar
Cai, H., Fang, H., & Xu, L. C. 2011. Eat, drink, firms, government: An investigation of corruption from the entertainment and travel costs of Chinese firms. The Journal of Law and Economics, 54(1): 5578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, C. M., Makino, S., & Isobe, T. 2010. Does subnational region matter? Foreign affiliate performance in the United States and China. Strategic Management Journal, 31(11): 12261243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, C. C., Chen, X. P., & Huang, S. 2013. Chinese guanxi: An integrative review and new directions for future research. Management and Organization Review, 9(1): 167207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, J. J., Jiang, C., & Shenkar, O. 2015. The quality of local government and firm performance: The case of China's provinces. Management and Organization Review, 11(4): 679710.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chung, H. F., Yen, D. A., & Wang, C. L. 2020. The contingent effect of social networking ties on Asian immigrant enterprises’ innovation. Industrial Marketing Management, 88: 414425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, W. M., Nelson, R. R., & Walsh, J. P. 2000. Protecting their intellectual assets: Appropriability conditions and why US manufacturing firms patent (or not). National Bureau of Economic Research working paper No. 7552.Google Scholar
Collins, R. 2014. Interaction ritual chains. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cull, R., & Xu, L. C. 2005. Institutions, ownership, and finance: The determinants of profit reinvestment among Chinese firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 77(1): 117146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Czarnitzki, D., & Toole, A. A. 2011. Patent protection, market uncertainty, and R&D investment. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 93(1): 147159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denis, D. J., Denis, D. K., & Yost, K. 2002. Global diversification, industrial diversification, and firm value. The Journal of Finance, 57(5): 19511979.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewan, R., Jing, B., & Seidmann, A. 2003. Product customization and price competition on the internet. Management Science, 49(8): 10551070.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Collective rationality and institutional isomorphism in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2): 147160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dowell, G. W., Shackell, M. B., & Stuart, N. V. 2011. Boards, CEOs, and surviving a financial crisis: Evidence from the internet shakeout. Strategic Management Journal, 32(10): 10251045.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Du, X. 2013. Does religion matter to owner-manager agency costs? Evidence from China. Journal of Business Ethics, 118(2): 319347.Google Scholar
Dyer, J. H., & Singh, H. 1998. The relational view: Cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(4): 660679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisenhardt, K. 1989. Agency theory: An assessment and review. Academy of Management Review, 14(1): 5774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fama, E. F. 1980. Agency problems and the theory of the firm. Journal of Political Economy, 88(2): 288307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fan, G., & Wang, X. 2006. NERI index of marketization of China's provinces. Beijing: Economics Science Press.Google Scholar
Ferrary, M. 2003. The gift exchange in the social networks of Silicon Valley. California Management Review, 45(4): 120138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finkelstein, S. 1992. Power in top management teams: Dimensions, measurement, and validation. Academy of Management Journal, 35(3): 505538.Google ScholarPubMed
Fung, H. G., Xu, X. E., & Zhang, Q. Z. 2007. On the financial performance of private enterprises in China. Journal of Developmental Entrepreneurship, 12(4): 399414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gale, B. T. 1972. Market share and rate of return. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 54(4): 412423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guo, F., Zou, B., Zhang, X., Bo, Q., & Li, K. 2020. Financial slack and firm performance of SMMEs in China: Moderating effects of government subsidies and market-supporting institutions. International Journal of Production Economics. in press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. 1984. Structural inertia and organizational change. American Sociological Review, 49(2): 149164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haveman, H. A., Jia, N., Shi, J., & Wang, Y. 2017. The dynamics of political embeddedness in China. Administrative Science Quarterly, 62(1): 67104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
He, J., & Wang, H. 2009. Firm innovative knowledge assets and economic performance: The asymmetric roles of incentive- and monitoring-based governance mechanisms. Academy of Management Journal, 52(5): 919938.Google Scholar
Heide, J. B., & John, G. 1992. Do norms matter in marketing relationships? Journal of Marketing, 56(2): 3244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hennart, J. F. 2007. The theoretical rationale for a multinationality-performance relationship. Management International Review, 47(3): 423452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hitt, M. A., Bierman, L., Uhlenbruck, K., & Shimizu, K. 2006. The importance of resources in the internationalization of professional service firms: The good, the bad, and the ugly. Academy of Management Journal, 49(6): 11371157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoskisson, R. E., Eden, L., Lau, C. M., & Wright, M. 2000. Strategy in emerging economies. Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 249267.Google Scholar
Hsu, P. H., Tian, X., & Xu, Y. 2014. Financial development and innovation: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 112(1): 116135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, K. G., & Li, J. 2019. Adopting knowledge from reverse innovations? Transnational patents and signaling from an emerging economy. Journal of International Business Studies, 50(7): 10781102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hymer, S. H. 1976. A study of direct foreign investment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Iriyama, A., Kishore, R., & Talukdar, D. 2016. Playing dirty or building capability? Corruption and HR training as competitive actions to threats from informal and foreign firm rivals. Strategic Management Journal, 37(10): 21522173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, S. D., Leiblein, M. J., & Lu, S. 2013. How firms capture value from their innovations. Journal of Management, 39(5): 11231155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jean, R. J. B., Sinkovics, R. R., & Hiebaum, T. P. 2014. The effects of supplier involvement and knowledge protection on product innovation in customer–supplier relationships: A study of global automotive suppliers in China. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 31(1): 98113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, M. C. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic Review, 76(2): 323329.Google Scholar
Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4): 305360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kamien, M. I., & Schwartz, N. L. 1982. Market structure and innovation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kennedy, P. 2008. A guide to econometrics. Malden, MA: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. 1997. Why focused strategies may be wrong for emerging markets. Harvard Business Review, 75(4): 4148.Google Scholar
Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. 1999. The right way to restructure conglomerates in emerging markets. Harvard Business Review, 77(4): 125125.Google Scholar
King, D. R., Covin, J. G., & Hegarty, W. H. 2003. Complementary resources and the exploitation of technological innovations. Journal of Management, 29(4): 589606.Google Scholar
Levin, R. C., Klevorick, A. K., Nelson, R. R., Winter, S. G., Gilbert, R., & Griliches, Z. 1987. Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3: 783831.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J. 2003. Passport China: Your pocket guide to Chinese business, customs & etiquette. Novato, CA: World Trade Press.Google Scholar
Li, J. 2013. The internationalization of entrepreneurial firms from emerging economies: The roles of institutional transitions and market opportunities. Journal of International Entrepreneurship, 11(2): 158171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J., & Qian, C. 2013. Principal-principal conflicts under weak institutions: A study of corporate takeovers in China. Strategic Management Journal, 34(4): 498508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J., & Wan, W. 2016. China's cross-border mergers and acquisitions: A contextual distance perspective. Management and Organization Review, 12(3): 449456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J., & Xie, Z. 2011. Global R&D strategies in an emerging economy: The development and protection of technological competencies. European Management Review, 8(3): 153164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J., & Xie, Z. 2016. Governance structure and the creation and protection of technological competencies: International R&D joint ventures in China. Management International Review, 56(1): 123148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J., Tian, L., & Wan, G. 2015. Contextual distance and the international strategic alliance performance: A conceptual framework and a partial meta-analytic test. Management and Organization Review, 11(2): 289313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J., Xia, J., & Zajac, E. J. 2018. On the duality of political and economic stakeholder influence on firm innovation performance: Theory and evidence from Chinese firms. Strategic Management Journal, 39(1): 193216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtenthaler, U. 2013. The collaboration of innovation intermediaries and manufacturing firms in the markets for technology. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 30(S1): 142158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, W., & Li, J. 2019. Unbalanced institutions in market transition: How do they matter for firm strategic choices and performance in emerging economies? Management International Review, 59(5): 675702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, Z., Xu, Z., Zhou, Z., & Li, Y. 2019. Buddhist entrepreneurs and new venture performance: The mediating role of entrepreneurial risk-taking. Small Business Economics, 52(3): 713727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lu, J. W., & Beamish, P. W. 2004. International diversification and firm performance: The S-curve hypothesis. Academy of Management Journal, 47(4): 598609.Google Scholar
Luo, X., Kanuri, V. K., & Andrews, M. 2014. How does CEO tenure matter? The mediating role of firm-employee and firm-customer relationships. Strategic Management Journal, 35(4): 492511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luo, Y., & Chen, M. 1997. Does guanxi influence firm performance? Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 14(1): 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maine, E., & Garnsey, E. 2006. Commercializing generic technology: The case of advanced materials ventures. Research Policy, 35(3): 375393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mair, J., Marti, I., & Ventresca, M. J. 2012. Building inclusive markets in rural Bangladesh: How intermediaries work institutional voids. Academy of Management Journal, 55(4): 819850.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marquis, C., & Raynard, M. 2015. Institutional strategies in emerging markets. The Academy of Management Annals, 9(1): 291335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83(2): 340363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, K. E., Estrin, S., Bhaumik, S. K., & Peng, M. W. 2009. Institutions, resources, and entry strategies in emerging economies. Strategic Management Journal, 30(1): 6180.Google Scholar
Mayer, M. C., Stadler, C., & Hautz, J. 2015. The relationship between product and international diversification: The role of experience. Strategic Management Journal, 36(10): 14581468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Misangyi, V. F., Elms, H., Greckhamer, T., & Lepine, J. A. 2006. A new perspective on a fundamental debate: A multilevel approach to industry, corporate, and business unit effects. Strategic Management Journal, 27(6): 571590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murthi, B. P. S., & Sarkar, S. 2003. The role of the management sciences in research on personalization. Management Science, 49(10): 13441362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nachum, L., & Zaheer, S. 2005. The persistence of distance? The impact of technology on MNE motivations for foreign investment. Strategic Management Journal, 26(8): 747767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nell, P. S. V., & Lichtenthaler, U. 2011. The role of innovation intermediaries in the markets for technology. International Journal of Technology Intelligence and Planning, 7(2): 128139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nguyen, T. V., & Rose, J. 2009. Building trust: Evidence from Vietnamese entrepreneurs. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(2): 165182.Google Scholar
Nguyen, T. V., Weinstein, M., & Meyer, A. D. 2005. Development of trust: A study of interfirm relationships in Vietnam. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 22(3): 211235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. 1990. Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, R. M. 2007. A caution regarding rules of thumb for variance inflation factors. Quality & Quantity, 41(5): 673690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Opper, S., Nee, V., & Holm, H. 2017. Risk aversion and guanxi activities: A behavioral analysis of CEOs in China. Academy of Management Journal, 60(4): 15041530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, S. H., & Luo, Y. 2001. Guanxi and organizational dynamics: Organizational networking in Chinese firms. Strategic Management Journal, 22(5): 455477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2002. Towards an institution-based view of business strategy. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 19(2-3): 251267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W. 2003. Institutional transitions and strategic choices. Academy of Management Review, 28(2): 275296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W., & Heath, P. S. 1996. The growth of the firm in planned economies in transition: Institutions, organizations, and strategic choice. Academy of Management Review, 21(2): 492528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peng, M. W., & Luo, Y. 2000. Managerial ties and firm performance in a transition economy: The nature of a micro-macro link. Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 486501.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., Lee, S. H., & Wang, D. Y. 2005. What determines the scope of the firm over time? A focus on institutional relatedness. Academy of Management Review, 30(3): 622633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perks, H., Kahn, K., & Zhang, C. 2009. An empirical evaluation of R&D–marketing NPD integration in Chinese firms: The guanxi effect. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 26(6): 640651.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poppo, L., & Zenger, T. 2002. Do formal contracts and relational governance function as substitutes or complements? Strategic Management Journal, 23(8): 707725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qian, C., Wang, H., Geng, X., & Yu, Y. 2017. Rent appropriation of knowledge-based assets and firm performance when institutions are weak: A study of Chinese publicly listed firms. Strategic Management Journal, 38(4): 892911.Google Scholar
Rahaman, M. M. 2011. Access to financing and firm growth. Journal of Banking & Finance, 35(3): 709723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ranger-Moore, J. 1997. Bigger may be better, but is older wiser? Organizational age and size in the New York life insurance industry. American Sociological Review, 62(6): 903920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rediker, K. J., & Seth, A. 1995. Boards of directors and substitution effects of alternative governance mechanisms. Strategic Management Journal, 16(2): 8599.Google Scholar
Reuer, J. J., & Arino, A. 2007. Strategic alliance contracts: Dimensions and determinants of contractual complexity. Strategic Management Journal, 28(3): 313330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rindfleisch, A., & Moorman, C. 2001. The acquisition and utilization of information in new product alliances: A strength-of-ties perspective. Journal of Marketing, 65(2): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, P. W., & Dowling, G. R. 2002. Corporate reputation and sustained superior financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 23(12): 10771093.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rumelt, R. P. 1991. How much does industry matter? Strategic Management Journal, 12(3): 167185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saxenian, A. 1996. Regional advantage. Boston: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schaffer, M. 2015. xtivreg2: Stata module to perform extended IV/2SLS, GMM and AC/HAC, LIML and k-class regression for panel data models.Google Scholar
Scherer, F. M., & Ross, D. 1990. Industrial market structure and economic performance. University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign's Academy for entrepreneurial leadership historical research reference in entrepreneurship, Working paper.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. 1934. The theory of economic development: An inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest and business cycle. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Seifert, B., Morris, S. A., & Bartkus, B. R. 2004. Having, giving, and getting: Slack resources, corporate philanthropy, and firm financial performance. Business & Society, 43(2): 135161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Semadeni, M., Withers, M. C., & Trevis Certo, S. 2014. The perils of endogeneity and instrumental variables in strategy research: Understanding through simulations. Strategic Management Journal, 35(7): 10701079.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Serger, S. S., & Breidne, M. 2007. China's fifteen-year plan for science and technology: An assessment. Asia Policy, 4: 135164.Google Scholar
Sharfman, M. P., Wolf, G., Chase, R. B., & Tansik, D. A. 1988. Antecedents of organizational slack. Academy of Management Review, 13(4): 601614.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sirmon, D. G., & Hitt, M. A. 2009. Contingencies within dynamic managerial capabilities: Interdependent effects of resource investment and deployment on firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 30(13): 13751394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Song, M., Ai, H., & Li, X. 2015. Political connections, financing constraints, and the optimization of innovation efficiency among China's private enterprises. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 92: 290299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tan, J., & Peng, M. W. 2003. Organizational slack and firm performance during economic transitions: Two studies from an emerging economy. Strategic Management Journal, 24(13): 12491263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taussig, M., & Delios, A. 2015. Unbundling the effects of institutions on firm resources: The contingent value of being local in emerging economy private equity. Strategic Management Journal, 36(12): 18451865.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, D. J. 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6): 285305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teece, D. J. 2006. Reflections on ‘Profiting from innovation’. Research Policy, 35(8): 11311146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomsen, S., Pedersen, T., & Kvist, H. K. 2006. Blockholder ownership: Effects on firm value in market and control based governance systems. Journal of Corporate Finance, 12(2): 246269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tung, R. L, & Worm, V. 1997. The importance of networks (guanxi) for European companies in China. Paper presented at the Academy of Management Conference, Boston.Google Scholar
Uzzi, B. 1997. Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: The paradox of embeddedness. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(1): 3567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voss, G. B., Sirdeshmukh, D., & Voss, Z. G. 2008. The effects of slack resources and environmental threat on product exploration and exploitation. Academy of Management Journal, 51(1): 147164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, H., & Chen, W. 2010. Firm-specificity in technological innovation and rent appropriation: The roles of environmental dynamism and technological diversity. Research Policy, 39(1): 141154.Google Scholar
Wang, H., Choi, J., & Li, J. 2008. Too little or too much? Untangling the relationship between corporate philanthropy and firm financial performance. Organization Science, 19(1): 143159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, H. C., He, J., & Mahoney, J. T. 2009. Firm-specific knowledge resources and competitive advantage: The roles of economic- and relationship-based employee governance mechanisms. Strategic Management Journal, 30(12): 12651285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, L., & Kess, P. 2006. Partnering motives and partner selection: Case studies of Finnish distributor relationships in China. International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management, 36(6): 466478.Google Scholar
Wang, X., Fan, G., & Hu, L. 2018. Marketization index of China's provinces: NERI report. Beijing: Social Sciences Academic Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. 1992. Markets, hierarchies, and the modern corporation: An unfolding perspective. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 17(3): 335352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wooldridge, J. M. 2001. Applications of generalized method of moments estimation. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(4): 87100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xia, J., Ma, X., Lu, J. W., & Yiu, D. W. 2014. Outward foreign direct investment by emerging market firms: A resource dependence logic. Strategic Management Journal, 35(9): 13431363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xie, Z., & Li, J. 2013. Internationalization and indigenous technological efforts of emerging economy firms: The effect of multiple knowledge sources. Journal of International Management, 19(3): 247259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xie, Z., & Li, J. 2015. Demand heterogeneity, learning diversity and innovation in an emerging economy. Journal of International Management, 21(4): 277292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xie, Z., & Li, J. 2018. Exporting and innovating among emerging market firms: The moderating role of institutional development. Journal of International Business Studies, 49(2): 222245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xin, K. K., & Pearce, J. L. 1996. Guanxi: Connections as substitutes for formal institutional support. Academy of Management Journal, 39(6): 16411658.Google Scholar
Xu, D., Zhou, K. Z., & Du, F. 2019. Deviant versus aspirational risk taking: The effects of performance feedback on bribery expenditure and R&D intensity. Academy of Management Journal, 62(4): 12261251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yan, J. Z., & Chang, S. J. 2018. The contingent effects of political strategies on firm performance: A political network perspective. Strategic Management Journal, 39(8): 21522177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yan, Y., Li, J., & Zhang, J. 2021. Protecting intellectual property in foreign subsidiaries: An internal network defense perspective. Journal of International Business Studies: 1-21. DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41267-021-00430-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yiu, D. W., Xu, Y., & Wan, W. P. 2014. The deterrence effects of vicarious punishments on corporate financial fraud. Organization Science, 25(5): 15491571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, J., Marquis, C., & Qiao, K. 2016. Do political connections buffer firms from or bind firms to the government? A study of corporate charitable donations of Chinese firms. Organization Science, 27(5): 13071324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, M., Qi, Y., Wang, Z., Zhao, X., & Pawar, K. S. 2019. Effects of business and political ties on product innovation performance: Evidence from China and India. Technovation, 80: 3039.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Q., & Fung, H. G. 2006. China's social capital and financial performance of private enterprises. Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development, 13(2): 198207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Y., & Li, H. 2010. Innovation search of new ventures in a technology cluster: The role of ties with service intermediaries. Strategic Management Journal, 31(1): 88109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Y., Li, H., Hitt, M. A., & Cui, G. 2007. R&D intensity and international joint venture performance in an emerging market: Moderating effects of market focus and ownership structure. Journal of International Business Studies, 38(6): 944960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhao, M. 2006. Conducting R&D in countries with weak intellectual property rights protection. Management Science, 52(8): 11851199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zheng, W., Singh, K., & Chung, C. N. 2015. Ties to unbind political ties and firm sell-offs during institutional transition. Journal of Management, 43(7): 20052036.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhou, K. Z., Gao, G. Y., & Zhao, H. 2016. State ownership and firm innovation in China: An integrated view of institutional and efficiency logics. Administrative Science Quarterly, 62(2): 375404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhou, K. Z., Poppo, L., & Yang, Z. 2008. Relational ties or customized contracts? An examination of alternative governance choices in China. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(3): 526534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Summary statistics and correlations describing the variables

Figure 1

Table 2. Key coefficients of first-stage firm fixed effects models predicting firm innovation and its interaction terms

Figure 2

Figure 1. The moderating role of entertainment spending on the relationship between patents and return on assets (ROA)

Figure 3

Table 3. Coefficients of second-stage firm fixed effects models predicting return on assets (ROA)

Figure 4

Figure 2. The three-way interaction of the level of development of factor markets with entertainment spending and return on assets (ROA)

Figure 5

Figure 3. Three-way interaction of the level of development of legal institutions with entertainment spending and return on assets (ROA)

Figure 6

Table 4. Summary statistics and correlations describing the World Bank data

Figure 7

Table 5. Coefficients of models with the World Bank data testing for mechanisms

Supplementary material: File

Wan et al. supplementary material

Wan et al. supplementary material

Download Wan et al. supplementary material(File)
File 922.2 KB