Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-kw2vx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-07T08:08:16.098Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE SPIRIT OF CAPITALISM, ASSET RETURNS, AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 March 2007

MARTIN BOILEAU
Affiliation:
University of Colorado
REBECCA BRAEU
Affiliation:
California State University, Long Beach
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We evaluate whether the spirit of capitalism improves the ability of the real business cycle model to explain the main features of both asset return and the business cycle. In our model, the spirit of capitalism is embodied in the assumption that individuals have preferences for financial wealth. Our simulation results suggest that this assumption may improve the model's ability to explain the risk-free rate puzzle but not the equity premium puzzle. This assumption also markedly deteriorates the model's ability to account for the main features of the business cycle.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2007 Cambridge University Press

INTRODUCTION

A number of recent papers jointly study the asset return and business cycle implications of production economies. Notable examples include Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2001), Jermann (1998), Lettau (2003), Rouwenhorst (1995), and Tallarini (2000). These papers conclude that the standard model of production economies, the real business cycle (RBC) model, adequately replicates the main features of the business cycle but seriously fails to replicate the main features of asset returns. In particular, the RBC model does not explain the low average return on Treasury bills, the risk-free rate puzzle, nor does it explain the presence of a much larger average return on the stock market than on Treasury bills, the equity premium puzzle.

The standard solution to these puzzles is to add habit formation to the RBC model (see Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher, 2001; Jermann, 1998). In this paper, we evaluate a different mechanism to solve the puzzles. This mechanism is based on the idea that the acquisition of wealth is driven not only by a consumption motive but also by an intrinsic wealth accumulation motive. In particular, we assume that individuals have direct preferences for wealth. This assumption is motivated by the fact that individuals care about their societal status, and that higher levels of wealth signal higher status. Individuals then accumulate wealth both for future consumption (the consumption motive) and to raise their status (the wealth accumulation motive). Obviously, the wealth accumulation motive has important implications for the behavior of savings. The resulting behavior also has implications for the demand and pricing of assets and for economic growth.

There is a rapidly growing literature on the intrinsic wealth accumulation motive. Bakshi and Chen (1996) and Zou (1995) argue that this motive embodies the spirit of capitalism. In the literature, several studies argue that this motive helps to understand the behavior of savings and asset pricing.1

The literature includes papers on savings and consumption (Luo, Smith, and Zou, 2002; Luo and Young, 2004; Zou, 1995; Yang and Zou, 2003), on economic growth (Clemens, 2004; Corneo and Jeanne, 1997, 2001; Futagami and Shibata, 1998; Smith, 1999; Zou, 1994; Yang and Zou, 2003), on asset pricing (Bakshi and Chen, 1996; Gong and Zou, 2002; Evans, Joseph, and Kenc, 2003; Kuznitz, 2001; Smith, 2001; Yang and Zou, 2003), and even on the current account (Fisher, 2005; Fisher and Hof, 2005).

Among these studies, Zou (1995) argues that it solves the savings puzzle. That is, the accumulation motive explains why wealth increases with age, why individuals do not reduce their wealth after retirement, and why households with and without children have not shown significant differences in their savings behavior. Luo, Smith, and Zou (2002) argue that this motive solves the excess sensitivity and excess smoothness puzzles. That is, it explains why consumption reacts too much to expected changes in income but not enough to unexpected changes. More directly related to our study are the papers by Bakshi and Chen (1996) and Gong and Zou (2002), who argue that the wealth accumulation motive explains volatile stock prices and may solve the equity premium puzzle. Kuznitz (2001) argues that it also solves the risk-free rate puzzle.

For our analysis, we construct a one-sector production economy with spirit of capitalism. In this model, consumers have preferences over a composite of consumption and status. For our baseline, we adopt the absolute wealth is status framework of Bakshi and Chen (1996), where status corresponds to the level of financial wealth. Firms produce goods with capital and labor. Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000) argue that restrictions to the factor markets are necessary to ensure variations in the price of capital, and hence in capital gains. These variations greatly help in explaining the volatility of the risky return. For capital, we adopt the costly capital accumulation assumption of Jermann (1998). For labor, we employ two different assumptions. In the first version, we assume that workers supply labor using past information, as in Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000). The result is that the quantity of labor supplied does not react to the current state of the economy. In the second version, we assume that workers supply labor inelastically as in Jermann (1998). The result is that the quantity of labor supplied does not react.

We find that the baseline spirit-of-capitalism model produces a low risk-free rate, and may thus resolve the risk-free rate puzzle. The model produces reasonable volatilities for both the risk-free and risky rates but fails to produce a sizeable equity premium. Admittedly, the equity premium is much larger than that produced by a standard RBC model. Thus, in contrast to conjectures in Bakshi and Chen (1996) and in Gong and Zou (2002), the baseline spirit-of-capitalism model does not resolve the equity premium puzzle.2

When nearing the completion of our paper, we found a paper by Kuznitz (2001) that studies a variant of these preferences for an endowment economy. His conclusion parallels ours: the spirit of capitalism may resolve the risk-free rate puzzle but not the equity premium puzzle.

We also find that the spirit-of-capitalism model counterfactually predicts a large investment rate, a large volatility of consumption, and a low volatility of investment. In addition, the model fails to explain the behavior of employment.

We then study several modifications to the baseline model. The modifications include different definitions of status, different form of preferences over consumption and status, different framework to limit the mobility of capital, and different sources of risk. None of the modifications greatly alter our conclusions.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 presents the baseline spirit-of-capitalism model and its calibration. It also shows the financial and business cycle statistics produced by the model. Section 3 further explores the spirit-of-capitalism model. Section 4 concludes.

PRODUCTION ECONOMIES WITH SPIRIT-OF-CAPITALISM

The baseline spirit-of-capitalism (SOC) model assumes that consumers have direct preferences for financial wealth. This corresponds to the absolute wealth is status framework of Bakshi and Chen (1996). The model also adopts a one-sector production structure with frictions to factor markets. As argued in Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000), these frictions help generate fluctuations in the price of capital.

The Consumer's Problem

The economy is populated by consumers with expected lifetime utility,

where ct is consumption, st is the index of status, nt is employment, and 0<β<1. The functional form for u(c, s) follows Smith (2001):

where ηc≥0, ηs≥0, and γ≥1. The parameter ηs measures the extent to which individuals care about status. Importantly, the individual does not care about status when ηs=0. Using the terminology of Smith (2001), the effective coefficient of relative risk aversion is γe=1−(ηcs)(1−γ), the effective elasticity of intertemporal substitution is σe=1/[1+(γ−1)ηc], and the effective rate of time preferences is ρe=[ηc/(ηcs)][(1−β)/β]. This formulation of preferences, or a slight variant of, is used in Bakshi and Chen (1996), Futagami and Shibata (1998), Gong and Zou (2002), and Luo, Smith, and Zou (2002).

The functional form for the subutility function v(n) is:

where θ≥0 and ζ≥1. We explore the implications of the baseline model for two different versions. These versions are distinguished by their assumed labor market frictions. Version 1 assumes that workers choose current hours worked based on the information set available at the end of last period, as in Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000). The result is that date t labor supply cannot be adjusted in response to date t state of the world. Version 2 assumes that workers supply labor inelastically, as in Jermann (1998). The result is that labor supply is never adjusted.

Consumers face the budget constraint:

where wt is the wage rate, at and pt are the quantity and price of the risky asset, dt is dividends paid by the risky asset, and bt and qt are the quantity and price of the risk-free asset.

Finally, we focus our attention on the absolute wealth is status framework, in which status is defined exclusively as the level of financial wealth:

Consumers choose consumption, employment, and asset holdings to maximize expected lifetime utility subject to the budget constraint. For version 1, the problem yields the following first-order conditions:

where λct is the multiplier associated with the budget constraint (4) and

. The functions uc(ct, st) and us(ct, st) are the derivatives of u(ct, st) with respect to its arguments, and vn(nt) is the derivative of v(nt) with respect to its argument. Also, the risky return is:

The risk-free return is:

Finally, for version 2, the problem yields identical first-order conditions, except that condition (7) is replaced by nt=N.

The Firm's Problem

The firm wishes to maximize its value. The firm's value is (pt+dt)At, where At=1 is the total amount of shares issued. Using the equity return (10), the firm's value can be expressed as the discounted sum of future dividends:

where

and χ0=1.

Dividends are:

where yt is output and xt is investment. Output is produced using:

where zt is the level of technology or total factor productivity, kt is the capital stock, and 0<α<1. Capital accumulates via:

where 0<δ<1. Capital accumulation is costly. The adjustment cost function ϕ(xt/kt) is:

where ξ>0. The standard no-adjustment cost version is obtained when ξ→∞. Also, ω1 and ω2 ensure that ϕ(δ)=δ and ϕδ(δ)=1 in the deterministic steady state, where ϕδ(xt/kt) is the derivative of ϕ(xt/kt) with respect to its argument.

Finally, total factor productivity follows the stochastic process:

where

is the stationary level of technology, εzt is a mean zero random variable with variance σz2, and 0<ρz<1.

The firm chooses employment and investment to maximize its value subject to the different constraints. The firm's problem yields the following first-order conditions:

where μt is the multiplier associated with the capital accumulation equation (15).

Market Clearing Conditions

The economy is closed by the following market clearing conditions. The equity market clearing condition is:

the bond market clearing condition is:

and the goods market clearing condition is:

The consumers' constraints (2)–(5) and necessary conditions (6)–(9), the firm's constraints (13)–(17) and necessary conditions (18)–(20), and the market clearing conditions (21)–(23) are used to compute the economy's competitive equilibrium allocation. This allocation is then used to compute asset prices.

Simulation Method and Calibration

The asset pricing and business cycle implications of the above economic environment are analyzed using simulations. The simulation method is similar to that in Jermann (1998). The method combines the log-linear approximation of King, Plosser, and Rebelo (2002) to solve for quantities with a log-normal approximation to solve for the risk-free return.

The method works as follows. First, we employ the log-linear approximation to generate 1,000 time-series of 200 periods each for consumption, investment, capital, employment, and output. These series are then used to construct the risky return. As in Christiano, Boldrin, and Fisher (2000), we approximate the risky return as the return on capital:

where:

Note that

when investment is fully equity financed.

The quantity series are also used to construct the risk-free return. To do so, we rewrite condition (9) as

where

,

, and λc and λs are steady state values. As in Jermann (1998), we approximate the expectational terms as

This method requires numerical values for all parameters. To ease comparison with previous studies, we base our values on Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000) and Jermann (1998).3

Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000) set α=0.36, δ=0.021, ξ=0.23, θ=1, ζ=1 (to get indivisible labor), β=0.99999, γ=1, ρz=1, and σz=0.018. Jermann (1998) sets α=0.36, δ=0.025, ξ=0.23, γ=5, θ=ζ=0 (to get inelastic labor), β=0.99, and ρz=0.99. He also selects σz to ensure that the volatility of output growth is 1 percent.

We set α=0.36, δ=0.021, ξ=0.23. For version 1 of labor market frictions, we set ζ=1 to get indivisible labor and set θ to ensure that employment n=1 in the steady state. For version 2 of labor market frictions, we set θ=ζ=0 and set N=1 to get inelastic labor. We also set

, ρz=0.979, and σz=0.0072 as in King and Rebelo (2000).

For the remaining parameters, Bakshi and Chen (1996) provide estimates for a variant of the preferences displayed here. Using the notation of Smith (2001), their variant is

. This restricts the parameters to γ=γBC, ηc=1, and ηs=−λBC/(1−γBC). For an assumed value of β=1, their unrestricted estimates of γBC vary between 2.27 and 3.08, whereas those of λBC vary between 0.75 and 1.27. Following these estimates, we set β=0.99999, γ=2, ηc=1, and ηs=−λBC/(1−γ) for λBC=1.

We also reproduce the asset return and business cycle implications for two other popular specifications of the production economy. We do so because the popular specifications provide a good comparison benchmark, and to assure that the application of the method yields results that are similar to previous studies.

The first specification is that of a standard RBC model with indivisible labor. For this, we set β=0.99, γ=2, α=0.36, δ=0.021, and ζ=1. We also set θ to ensure that employment n=1 in the steady state. We remove the factor market frictions. That is, we let ξ→∞, ω1=1, and ω2=0, and we let labor supply depend on all current information.

The second specification is that of a habit formation model. For this, we retain the two versions of the SOC model, but change preferences to:

where ψ≥0. For the two versions of the habit formation model, we retain the previous calibrations and set ψ=0.90.4

Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000) set ψ=0.90, whereas Jermann (1998) sets ψ=0.82.

Simulation Results

Tables 1 and 2 report financial and business cycle statistics. The tables report historical statistics for United States data as well as statistics for simulated data.

The data statistics come from two sources. The financial statistics are those shown in Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2001) and are estimates taken from Cecchetti, Lam, and Mark (1993).5

For comparison, Jermann (1998) uses estimates from Mehra and Prescott (1985). These estimates are: mean annual risk-free rate E(rf)=0.80%, equity premium E(rkrf)=6.18%, standard deviations of risk-free and risky rates σrf = 5.67% and σrk = 16.54%, and Sharpe Ratio E(rkrf)/σrk = 0.37.

The statistics refer to average, volatility, and ratio of different variables. Average presents the mean annual risk-free rate and mean equity premium: E(rf)=1.19% and E(rkrf)=6.63%. Volatility presents the standard deviations of the risk-free and risky rates:

% and

%. Ratio presents the Sharpe Ratio:

.

The business cycle statistics are constructed from seasonally adjusted quarterly data for the 1964:1 to 2001:4 period. In all cases, the statistics are based on the logarithm of quarterly per capita real variables, where the logarithm of each variable is detrended using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of 1,600. The statistics refer to volatility, correlation, and persistence of different variables. Volatility presents the ratio of the standard deviations of consumption, investment, and employment to the standard deviation of output: σcy=0.80, σxy=2.61, and σny=0.99. Correlation presents the contemporaneous correlations of consumption, investment, and employment with output: ρ(c, y)=0.96, ρ(x, y)=0.94, and ρ(n, y)=0.80. Finally, persistence presents the first autocorrelation of consumption and output: ρ(c′, c)=0.86 and ρ(y′, y)=0.89.

The RBC model does not replicate the financial statistics but replicates several of the business cycle statistics. The RBC model generates too high a risk-free rate, no sizeable equity premium, and too low a volatility for both the risk-free and risky rates. Similar results are found in Jermann (1998), Lettau (2003), Tallarini (2000), and Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2001). As Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2001) argue, the RBC model does not generate an equity premium because the linearity of capital accumulation and the unrestricted labor adjustments allow consumers to smooth consumption too much. As shown in Lettau (2003), the implied reduction in the variance of the marginal utility of consumption (and, hence, the pricing kernel) raises the risk-free rate. Both factors work to reduce the volatility of the risky rate. In particular, the linearity of capital accumulation eliminates potential capital gains and effectively makes the supply of capital perfectly elastic. Furthermore, the ability of firms to adjust employment reduces the need to respond to productivity shocks by adjusting capital. Thus, the fluctuations in the price of capital are limited, which reduces the volatility of the risky rate and the appearance of an equity premium.

The Habit model replicates some of the financial statistics but fails to replicate the main business cycle facts. The Habit model explains a lower risk-free rate and a sizeable equity premium. Admittedly, version 1 of the Habit model generates too much volatility for both the risk-free and risky rates, and version 2 generates too low a risk-free rate. The Habit model's success comes from a correction of the main failure of the RBC model: the Habit model adds habit formation and restrictions to capital and labor adjustments. Habit formation forces consumers to care about the volatility of consumption. That is, habit formation generates a large volatility of the marginal utility from a small volatility of consumption. In addition, the restrictions to capital and labor adjustments ensure sizeable variations in the price of capital. Similar results are found in Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000) and Jermann (1998). As its stands, the Habit model does not explain the behavior of employment. Version 1 overpredicts the volatility of employment, and counterfactually predicts that employment is acyclical and that output is negatively autocorrelated. Version 2 eliminates the volatility of employment, but predicts that output is positively autocorrelated.

The baseline SOC model can partially replicate the financial statistics. The model predicts a very low (negative) risk-free rate. The low risk-free rate results from the preferences for status. To see this, the pricing equation of the risk-free rate of the RBC model is:

A comparison between equations (27) and (30) suggests that the SOC model produces a low risk-free rate because the marginal utility of status is positive. That is, the expected future return to financial assets includes not only higher future consumption, but also higher future status. This latter effect reduces the equilibrium risk-free rate, and helps resolve the risk-free rate puzzle. Otherwise, the baseline SOC model produces a reasonable amount of volatility for the risk-free rate but not enough for the risky rate. In addition, the model produces only a minimal equity premium. The equity premium is considerably larger than that produced by the RBC model, but it is an order of magnitude that is too small.

The baseline SOC model fails to replicate the business cycle statistics. The model seriously overpredicts the volatility of consumption and employment, while it underpredicts the volatility of investment. Version 1 overpredicts the volatility of employment, and incorrectly predicts that output and consumption are negatively autocorrelated. Version 2 eliminates the volatility of employment but predicts that output and consumption are positively autocorrelated.

A closer look at the SOC model reveals that its calibration implies a very large steady state investment rate (I/Y), and thus a very large capital output ratio. The investment rate of the baseline SOC model is roughly 68%. For comparison, the investment rate is only 24% in the RBC model and 36% in the Habit model. The large investment rate may be responsible for the negative risk-free rate. That is, the investment rate is large because the subjective discount factor β is large. In turn, the large value of β reduces the risk-free rate.

The large investment rate also may affect the volatility of consumption and investment. In the RBC model, large investment rates are associated with high volatility of consumption and low volatility of investment. This association might well carry over to the SOC model. Admittedly, the low volatility of investment might result from other parts of the calibration. The baseline calibration implies stringent adjustment costs to investment, in which the elasticity of investment with respect to Tobin's q (ξ) is small. In addition, the baseline calibration puts equal weights on consumption and status in preferences. This is important because consumers wish to smooth a composite of consumption and status, where status is linked to the capital stock.

For these reasons, we study an alternative calibration of the SOC model. In this alternative, we lower the subjective discount factor to match the observed risk-free rate of 1.19%. For version 1, this requires lowering the subjective discount factor to β=0.936, whereas, for version 2, it requires β=0.978. In both cases, the result is that the investment rate is 32%. This is higher than in the RBC model but smaller than in the Habit model. We also arbitrarily set the elasticity of investment with respect to Tobin's q to ξ=2.6

Note that further raising the elasticity does not significantly raise the volatility of investment.

Finally, we alter the values of ηc and ηs to match the volatility of consumption. In doing so, we keep the effective coefficient of risk aversion constant. The effective coefficient of risk aversion is γe=1−(ηcs)(1−γ). In the baseline calibration of the SOC model, γe=3. For version 1, this requires that we set ηs=1.18 and ηc=0.82. For version 2, this requires that we set ηs=0.60 and ηc=1.40.

Tables 1 and 2 report financial and business cycle statistics for the alternative calibration. Under this calibration, the SOC model no longer predicts a higher equity premium than the RBC model, and now underpredicts the volatility of asset returns. The model now predicts that investment is more volatile than output but the volatility of investment is still too low. Version 1 of the SOC model now correctly predicts the volatility of employment but incorrectly predicts that employment is countercyclical.

A FURTHER EXPLORATION OF PRODUCTION ECONOMIES WITH SPIRIT-OF-CAPITALISM

The results so far suggest that the baseline SOC model, in which status is defined as absolute financial wealth, may solve the risk-free rate puzzle. For certain parameter values, it predicts a larger equity premium than the standard RBC model, but the premium is still an order of magnitude that is too small. In addition, it seriously mispredicts the main business cycle statistics.

In this section, we attempt to correct some of these inadequacies by modifying the framework of status, the form of preferences over the composite of consumption and status, and the production technology. For simplicity, we only employ version 2 (inelastic labor) for these experiments. In any event, version 1 does not generate employment statistics that match the data. Results for all these experiments appear in Tables 3 and 4. For the most part, we retain the calibration of the baseline SOC model version 2 but set the subjective discount factor β to ensure that the investment rate is 32%. The financial and business cycle statistics for the recalibrated SOC model appear in Tables 3 and 4 under SOC v2 B.

Status

The baseline SOC model uses the absolute wealth is status framework of Bakshi and Chen (1996). These authors propose two other frameworks. The first alternative framework assumes that “the ratio of one's own wealth to the social index determines status.” In this case, status is defined as relative wealth:

where vt=pt−1at+qt−1bt and Vt is the social wealth index. In what follows, we assume that the social wealth index is Vt=pt−1At+qt−1Bt, and that every consumer is middle class in equilibrium (st=1). The second alternative framework assumes that “self-perception determines happiness.” In this case, although status is defined as relative wealth, the term that enters preferences is:

where κ≥0.

We introduce these definitions of status in version 2 of the SOC model. For the self-perception framework, we restrict 0<κ<1, because the social index is Vt=pt−1At+qt−1Bt and vt=Vt in equilibrium. We set κ=0.9, but the results are invariant in that range.

The results appear under Status in Tables 3 and 4. The different status frameworks of the SOC model do not significantly alter the financial nor the business cycle statistics. Note that the SOC model with the self-perception framework generates financial and business cycle statistics that are identical to those generated by the absolute wealth framework. The relative wealth framework generates a larger equity premium than the other status frameworks. The relative wealth framework, however, does not improve the ability of the SOC model to predict the business cycle statistics.

Composite

The baseline SOC model assumes that consumers have preferences over a Cobb-Douglas composite of consumption and status. The composite can be easily generalized. For this, we adopt a constant elasticity of substitution aggregator, such that preferences are modified to:

where 1/(1−e) is the elasticity of substitution. In addition to the Cobb-Douglas case, we study three alternative cases. The separable case sets e = 0 and γ = 1, so that consumption and status are separable and preferences reduce to u(ct, st)=ηcln(ct)+ηsln(st). The complement case sets e = −9, so that consumption and status are complements. The substitute case sets e=0.8, so that consumption and status are substitutes.

The results appear under Composite in Tables 3 and 4. The different form of preferences do not significantly alter the financial nor the business cycle statistics. The complement case produces a higher equity premium, a higher volatility of asset returns, and a higher volatility of investment, but none of these statistics are sufficiently high to match the data.

Capital Adjustment

The baseline SOC model adopts a one-sector production structure with adjustment costs similar to that of Jermann (1998). His structure limits capital adjustment by assuming that it is costly. Boldrin, Christiano, and Fisher (2000, 2001) study two other frameworks that limit capital adjustment. The time-to-plan framework replaces the adjustment cost assumption by a time-to-plan assumption. The two-sector framework uses a two-sector production structure in which capital cannot be reallocated across sectors.

For the time-to-plan framework, we eliminate the adjustment costs, so that kt+1 = xt +(1−δ)kt,

, and

. The time-to-plan assumption requires that firms make investment decisions based only on the information set available at the end of last period. This ensures that Et−1t)=1, instead of μt=1.

For the two-sector framework, we split the firm's problem in two. The firm in the consumption sector seeks to maximize the discounted sum of its future dividends dct=yctqctxctwtnct. The firm sells its output ct=yct to consumers, purchases new equipment goods xct from the investment sector firm at price qct, and hires labor nct. The firm produces goods using the production technology

and capital accumulates as kct+1=xct+(1−δ)kct, where kct is the capital stock of the firm in the consumption sector. The firm in the investment sector also seeks to maximize the discounted sum of its future dividends dit=qctxctwtnit. The firm sells part of its output xct to the firm in the consumption sector and hires labor nit. The firm produces goods using the production technology

and capital accumulates as kit+1=xit+(1−δ)kit, where kit is the capital stock of the firm in the investment sector and xt=yit=xit+xct.

The risky return in the two-sector model is:

The risky returns are

and

, where

and

.

The results appear under Capital Adjustment in Tables 3 and 4. The time-to-plan framework produces a small and negative equity premium, while the two-sector framework produces a larger equity premium. Note, however, that it is still an order of magnitude that is too small. The time-to-plan framework generates much more volatility for investment but still predicts a large volatility for consumption. The two-sector framework produces too large a volatility for both consumption and investment. In addition, investment is countercyclical. Interestingly, the correlation between fluctuations in consumption and investment (or the capital stock) is −0.97, which is consistent with consumers smoothing the composite of consumption and status.

Shocks

Finally, the baseline SOC model assumes that total factor productivity is the only source of risk in the economy. Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell (2000) suggest investment-specific technological change as another source of risk. This source of risk directly affects the price of capital.

We add investment-specific shocks to the baseline SOC model. For this, we modify the capital accumulation equation to:

where at is the stochastic investment-specific shock. The investment-specific shock follows the stochastic process:

where εat is a mean zero random variable with variance

, and 0<ρa<1. The risky return is as in the baseline SOC model but μt=1/[atϕδt] and

.

We calibrate the stochastic process as in Greenwood, Hercowitz, and Krusell (2000):

, ρa = 0.64, and σz = 0.035. We also assume that productivity shocks and investment-specific shocks are uncorrelated.

The results appear under Shocks in Tables 3 and 4. The addition of investment-specific shocks clearly raises the equity premium and the volatility of asset returns. The model with investment-specific shocks still incorrectly predicts a large volatility of consumption, and understates the extent to which consumption and investment are procyclical.

CONCLUSION

In this paper, we evaluate whether the spirit of capitalism improves the ability of models of production economies to explain the main features of both asset returns and the business cycle. In our model, the spirit of capitalism is embodied in the assumption that individuals care about their status, and that higher levels of financial wealth signal higher status.

Our simulation results suggest that the spirit of capitalism partially explains the main features of asset returns. That is, the model with direct preferences for wealth produces a low risk-free rate, volatile asset returns, and a much larger equity premium than a standard real business cycle model. The equity premium, however, is still an order of magnitude that is too small. In that sense, the spirit of capitalism may solve the risk-free rate puzzle but not the equity premium puzzle. In addition, our results suggest that the spirit of capitalism does not explain the main features of the business cycle. That is, the model with direct preferences for wealth produces too much volatility for consumption and not enough volatility for investment.

One drawback of our analysis is that the model is based (as in most of the literature) on a representative consumer. It might be important to account for the heterogeneity amongst consumers to get the full benefit of the spirit of capitalism. Luo and Young (2004) construct such an economy to study the effects of the spirit of capitalism on the distribution of wealth. In particular, they wish to evaluate whether the spirit of capitalism can raise the counterfactually low wealth inequality produced by standard general equilibrium model. Unfortunately, they find that the spirit of capitalism reduces rather than increase wealth inequality.

References

Bakshi G.S. and Z. Chen 1996 The spirit of capitalism and stock-market prices. American Economic Review 86, 133157.Google Scholar
Boldrin M., L.J. Christiano and J.D.M. Fisher 2000 Habit Persistence, Asset Returns and the Business Cycle. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 280.Google Scholar
Boldrin M., L.J. Christiano and J.D.M. Fisher 2001 Habit persistence, asset returns and the business cycle. American Economic Review 91, 149166.Google Scholar
Cecchetti S.G., P. Lam and N.C. Mark 1993 The equity premium, and the risk free rate: Matching the moments. Journal of Monetary Economics 31, 2145.Google Scholar
Clemens C. 2004 Status, risk-taking and intertemporal substitution in an endogenous growth model. Journal of Economics 83, 10323.Google Scholar
Corneo G. and O. Jeanne 1997 On relative wealth effects and the optimality of growth. Economics Letters 54, 8792.Google Scholar
Corneo G. and O. Jeanne 2001 On relative-wealth effects and long-run growth. Research in Economics 55, 349358.Google Scholar
Evans L., N. Joseph and T. Kenc 2003 Foreign Exchange Risk Premia: A Model of the Spirit of Capitalism, Risk and Monetary Policy Uncertainty. Mimeo, University of Durham.
Fisher W. and F.X. Hof 2005 Status seeking in the small open economy. Journal of Macroeconomics 27, 209232.Google Scholar
Fisher W. 2005 Current account dynamics in a small open-economy model of status seeking. Review of International Economics 13, 262282.Google Scholar
Futagami K. and A. Shibata 1998 Keeping one step ahead of the Joneses: Status, the distribution of wealth, and long run growth. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 36, 109126.Google Scholar
Gong L. and H. Zou 2002 Direct preferences for wealth, the risk premium puzzle, growth, and policy effectiveness. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 26, 247270.Google Scholar
Greenwood J., Z. Hercowitz and P. Krusell 2000 The role of investment-specific technological change in the business cycle. European Economic Review 44, 91115.Google Scholar
Jermann U.J. 1998 Asset pricing in production economies. Journal of Monetary Economics 41, 257275.Google Scholar
King R.G. and S.T. Rebelo 2000 Resuscitating Real Business Cycles. NBER Working Paper No. 7534.Google Scholar
King R.G., C.I. Plosser and S.T. Rebelo 2002 Production, growth and business cycles: Technical appendix. Computational Economics 20, 87116.Google Scholar
Kuznitz A. 2001 Direct Wealth Preference in an Endowment Economy. Mimeo, Tel Aviv University.
Lettau M. 2003 Inspecting the mechanism: Closed-form solutions for asset prices in real business cycle models. Economic Journal 113, 550575.Google Scholar
Luo Y. and E. Young 2004 The Wealth Distribution and the Demand for Status, Mimeo, Princeton University.
Luo Y., W.T. Smith and H. Zou 2002 The Spirit of Capitalism, Precautionary Savings, and Consumption. Mimeo, Princeton University.
Mehra R. and E.C. Prescott 1985 The equity premium: A puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics 15, 145161.Google Scholar
Rouwenhorst K.G. 1995 Asset returns and business cycles. In T.F. Cooley (ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research, pp. 294330. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Smith W.T. 2001 How does the spirit of capitalism affect stock market prices? Review of Financial Studies 14, 12151232.Google Scholar
Smith W.T. 1999 Risk, the spirit of capitalism, and long-term growth. Journal of Macroeconomics 21, 241262.Google Scholar
Tallarini T.D. 2000 Risk-sensitive real business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 45, 507532.Google Scholar
Yang Y. and H. Zou 2003 Social Status, Non-Expected Utility, Asset Pricing, and Growth. Mimeo, Peking University.
Zou H. 1995 The spirit of capitalism and savings behavior. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 28, 131143.Google Scholar
Zou H. 1994 The spirit of capitalism and long-run growth. European Journal of Political Economy 10, 279293.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Benchmark financial statistics

Figure 1

Benchmark business cycle statistics

Figure 2

Financial statistics: Extensions SOC v2

Figure 3

Business cycle statistics: Extensions SOC v2