Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T16:45:57.277Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

SOCIAL STRATIFICATION, CAPITAL–SKILL COMPLEMENTARITY, AND THE NONMONOTONIC EVOLUTION OF THE EDUCATION PREMIUM

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 June 2004

YISHAY D. MAOZ
Affiliation:
University of Haifa
OMER MOAV
Affiliation:
Hebrew University of Jerusalem
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper presents a model that generates a nonmonotonic evolution of the return to education. The model highlights the role played by socioeconomic stratification in the joint determination of the supply of educated labor and the supply of physical capital. The recent theoretical literature attributes the increased education premium of the last decades to skill-biased technological progress. In contrast, our explanation is based on capital–skill complementarity and endogenous accumulation of physical and human capital in an environment characterized by credit constraints.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2004 Cambridge University Press

INTRODUCTION

This paper develops a theory of physical and human capital accumulation that offers an explanation for the nonmonotonic evolution of the skill premium observed in the United States and in several other western economies since the Industrial Revolution.1

See Katz et al. (1995), Autor et al. (1998), and Goldin and Katz (2000).

The theory focuses on the role of capital–skill complementarity and socioeconomic stratification, in an environment characterized by credit constraints, in generating these nonmonotonic patterns.

Most of the recent theoretical literature attributes the increased education premium of the last decades to skill-biased technological progress.2

See, among others, Galor and Tsiddon (1997), Acemoglu (1998), Caselli (1999), Galor and Moay (2000), Hassler and Rodriguez Mora (2000), Eicher and Garcia-Penalosa (2001), Gould (2001), and Gould (2002).

However, Krusell et al. (2000) show that changes in observed inputs alone can account for most of the variations in the skill premium over the past 30 years, without invoking technical change. They estimate a model in which the elasticity of substitution between physical capital (equipment) and unskilled labor is higher than that between capital and skilled labor. As follows from this specification, and consistent with their empirical findings, the accumulation of physical capital has a positive effect on the education premium while the accumulation of human capital affects the education premium negatively. Because of these contradicting effects, the education premium can either rise or fall when the supply of both skilled labor and physical capital increases.

We extend the analysis by Krusell et al. (2000) by embedding it in a theoretical framework where the supply of production factors evolves endogenously. In particular, we introduce the assumptions that physical capital and educated labor are complements in the production process, whereas uneducated labor and physical capital are substitutes,3

In addition to Krusell et al. (2000), empirical support for the structure of the production function is presented by Griliches (1969), Katz and Murphy (1992), Krueger (1993), Baldwin and Cain (1997), and Goldin and Katz (1998).

into Galor and Zeira's (1993) model of wealth distribution and capital market imperfections.

Our explanation of the endogenous accumulation of physical and human capital highlights the role played by socioeconomic stratification in individuals' joint decisions regarding education and savings. We assume that individuals in different social groups differ in their access to education. Benabou (1996a,b) studies a variety of reasons for the stratification of access to education. Here, for simplicity, we focus on the case in which the economy is populated by groups of individuals who differ in their wealth; therefore, because of imperfections in capital markets, poorer individuals face higher costs of financing education.4

Our analysis of investment in human capital under capital market imperfections follows earlier studies by Loury (1981) and Becker and Tomes (1986), who focus on the impact of market imperfections on intergenerational mobility. Maoz and Moav (1999) extend this line of research by incorporating endogenously determined wage premium, and thereby offer an explanation for the observed relationship between income inequality, mobility, and economic growth. Here, however, in contrast to the existing literature, we offer an explanation for the nonmonotonic evolution of the education premium.

These wealth differences change endogenously along the economy's growth path, due to the accumulation of wealth by dynasties that form the different strata, affecting investment decisions and the evolution of the return to education.5

Stokey (1996), comparing growth in a closed economy with open regimes, makes the same assumptions regarding the properties of the production function as in our model. However, because of perfect capital markets and the absence of social stratification, her model does not generate nonmonotonic wage inequality dynamics.

The combination of the assumptions of capital–skill complementarity and social stratification enable an endogenous nonmonotonic evolution of the education premium. In early stages, only individuals from the rich stratum, for whom the cost of financing education is sufficiently low, purchase education. At this early phase, the increase in the supply of educated labor dominates the accumulation of physical capital and drives the education premium down. This process leads to a stage in which all of the individuals in the rich stratum acquire education, but the education premium is still not sufficiently high to encourage poorer individuals to acquire education. In this phase, the wealthy accumulate wealth by investing in physical capital. Therefore, the increase in the supply of physical capital is the dominant factor, positively affecting the demand for educated labor, negatively affecting the demand for uneducated labor and hence bringing about an increase in the education premium.6

This outline is consistent with the evidence provided by Gottschalk (1997) that much of the increase between 1979 and 1994 in the college premium in the United States stems from a 20% decline in the real wage of high school graduates. Also see Katz and Murphy (1992), Juhn et al. (1993), and Autor et al. (1998).

Eventually, the education premium becomes sufficiently high to induce the acquisition of education by individuals from poorer strata as well. When this stage is reached, the renewed growth in the supply of educated labor drives the education premium down again. Thus, we show that the stratification of access to education in the economy determines, for each period, whether the effect of an increased supply of educated labor will dominate the effect of increased demand and drive the education premium down, or whether the demand effect will be the dominant force, driving the education premium up.

BASIC STRUCTURE OF THE MODEL

Consider a closed overlapping-generations economy, where economic activity extends over infinite discrete time. In every period, the economy produces a single homogeneous good that can be used for either consumption or investment. The good is produced using three production factors: physical capital, educated labor, and uneducated labor. The supply of the production factors is endogenously determined and the process of development is an outcome of the accumulation of physical and human capital.

Production of Final Output

Production occurs within a period according to a constant-returns-to-scale production technology. Consistent with conventional wisdom and recent empirical evidence, the production function is characterized by capital–skill complementarity as well as substitutability between capital and uneducated labor. The output produced at time t uses capital, Kt, uneducated labor, Ut, and educated labor, Et, in the production process:

where kt≡(Kt+Ut)/Et and α∈ (0, 1).

Factor Prices and Capital Markets

Producers operate in a perfectly competitive environment. Given the factor prices, producers determine the level of employment of capital, educated labor, and uneducated labor in order to maximize profits. Given the structure of the production technology and the competitiveness of markets, the wage of educated labor, wet, the wage of uneducated labor, wut, and the return to capital, Rt, at time t are

where the derivatives have the following signs:

We assume that capital markets are imperfect. We model the imperfection by assuming that the interest rate for individual borrowers is higher than the interest rate for lenders, which is equal to the interest rate paid by firms. The difference between these interest rates is the real cost of keeping track of individual borrowers during their second period of life.

7

We take Galor and Zeira's (1993) result of a linear cost without repeating the detailed explanation.

Furthermore, we assume that capital fully depreciates. Thus, during period t, the interest rate for lenders and for firms that borrow is: Rt+1−1. We denote the interest rate for individuals who borrow during period t by RBt+1−1, where

Individuals

Our modeling of individuals' preferences and occupational choices, in an imperfect capital market environment, closely follows the framework of Galor and Zeira (1993). Individuals are identical in their preferences and their technologies of human capital formation within and across generations. They may differ, however, in their initial wealth, inherited from their parents. Thus, because of the imperfection of capital markets, their investment in human capital may differ. We assume that individuals live for two periods and have a single parent and a single child, that is, there is no population growth. When parents are in their second period of life, their children are in their first. In their first period of life, individuals who choose to become educated workers acquire an indivisible unit of education.8

We discuss the role of the indivisibility in the concluding remarks.

In their second period of life, individuals supply their unit-time endowment to the labor force. Individuals who acquired education work as educated workers and individuals who did not invest in human capital supply uneducated labor. We normalize the number of dynasties to unity and, therefore, Ut+Et=1 for all t.

Individuals' preferences are defined over second-period consumption and their bequests to their children.

9

For evidence supporting this form of altruism, see Altonji et al. (1997) and Wilhelm (1996).

The preferences of individual j born in period t are represented by the following utility function:

where cjt+1 is individual j's consumption in the second period of life and bjt+1 is individual j's bequest in the second period of life. Hence, it follows from the individual's maximization problem that j's bequest to the offspring is

where yjt+1 is individual j's wealth in the second period of life.

Occupational choice

Members of generation t face an occupational choice in the first period of their life. Since individuals derive utility only from second-period consumption and bequest, maximization of second-period wealth is necessary for utility maximization. Therefore, individuals choose to become educated workers if their second-period wealth as educated workers is higher than their second-period wealth as uneducated workers.

Unless they have acquired education in the first period of life, the individuals' second-period labor unit is of the uneducated type. Education can be acquired only in the first period of life and bears a fixed cost denoted by h.10

As will become apparent, the fixed cost of education is a simplifying assumption. An alternative assumption, discussed in the concluding remarks, of indexing this cost to the skilled wage, does not have a qualitative effect on the model's results.

Since individuals work only in their second period of life, their first-period wealth is the parental bequest. Those who inherit less than h have to borrow in order to acquire education.

We now examine individual j born in period t that inherits bjt. We define this individual's wealth in t+1 by yt+1e,j if j chooses to invest in education, and by yt+1u,j if j chooses not to. It follows from (2) and (4) that

which could be represented as

where the term min(0, bjth) (δ−1)Rt+1, is the additional cost for borrowing caused by the capital market imperfection.

Similarly, individual j's wealth in t+1 if he chooses not to acquire education is

Applying (7) and (9) in the condition

for individual j to invest in human capital, we find that individual j will invest in human capital if

where

is the share of self-financed investment and

is the share borrowed. The right-hand side of (10) presents the investment that includes the education cost, h, and a possible finance cost. The left-hand side presents the present value of the return on the investment.

We denote the period t education premium by Pt and define it by

From (3) it follows that the left-hand side of the condition for investment in education (10) is increasing in Pt+1. Based on that, we can define individual j's critical level of education premium, denoted by

as the level of the education premium, Pt+1, for which (10) holds as an equality: if

, individual j invests in human capital, if

, individual j does not invest, and if

, individual j is indifferent whether to invest or not. Note that

is unique, positive, decreasing in bjt and increasing in h and δ. In addition, it follows from (10) that the exact values of bjt and δ are relevant for the investment decision only if bjt<h. The rationale behind these relations is that in the range bjt<h the lower the bequest received by an individual, the stronger the liquidity constraints and the incentive, in the form of an education premium, required for investment.

Stratification of the Economy

From (7) and (9) it follows that the second-period wealth of individual j born in period t is a function of the parental bequest, btj, and prices in t+1. Since all individuals face the same prices, it follows that all individuals who inherit a bequest of the same size in period t will have the same wealth in period t+1. Therefore, by (6), these individuals' offspring will inherit identical bequests as well, implying that the economy is characterized by a composition of strata of dynasties, where dynasty wealth, which can evolve over time, is identical within each stratum.

Suppose that in period 0 the economy consists of two groups of adult individuals who differ only in their wealth. Members of group A are a fraction λ of all adult individuals in the society. Each member of group A is endowed with a wealth level y0A. Members of group B are a fraction 1−λ of all adult individuals in the society, each endowed with a wealth level y0B, where, y0A>y0B. In every period, therefore, a fraction λ of all adults are homogeneous members of group A, and a fraction 1−λ are homogeneous members of group B.

Since wealth, yjt+1, and therefore the bequest, bjt+1, are strictly increasing functions of the transfer received by the individual, bjt, it follows that bAt>bBt and yAt>ytB for all t and therefore

for all t. Although initially the two groups are distinct, they may converge to one another. By (10), the critical values,

and

, are equal if both bAt and bBt exceed h.

Since

is decreasing in bjt, it follows that the allocation of education among the economic strata is positively correlated with wealth. In particular, if bAt>bBt and h>bBt, then the following two results hold: First, if an individual from group B acquires education, then all individuals in group A acquire education; second, if an individual from group A does not acquire education, then no individuals in group B acquire education.

Based on the definition of the critical education premium, the curve denoted by Es in Figure 1 presents the supply of educated labor and the curve denoted by ED presents the demand for educated labor in period t+1. As the economy grows, the demand curve shifts up due to the accumulation of physical capital, and the supply curve shifts down due to the relaxation of liquidity constraints as a result of the decline in the return to physical capital and the accumulation of wealth by dynasties in the economy. In periods in which demand and supply cross at the horizontal part of the supply curve, the education premium falls since the swings in demand merely provoke matching increases in the supplied quantity of Et+1. Likewise, in periods in which these curves cross at the vertical part of the supply curve, the education premium increases. This exemplifies the role of the stratification of the economy in determining which of the effects—demand or supply—will dominate the dynamics of the education premium in each period.

Demand and supply in the market for educated labor.

In our model, the stratification of the economy arises merely from wealth heterogeneity. However, as Figure 1 shows, what is actually crucial for our results is stratification of the critical education premium,

. This stratification can also arise from heterogeneity in the costs of education, h, or in the interest requirements by lenders as captured by δ.

Figure 1 also makes clear that the main results of this paper are not restricted to the simplified discrete case analyzed in this section. Consider a case in which the joint distribution of y, h, and δ is smooth but leads to a distribution of

that has peaks in it. In that case, the supply curve will be smooth, in contrast to the one in Figure 1, but it can be sufficiently elastic in certain intervals and sufficiently inelastic in others to make changes in dominance across time between the demand and supply effects on the education premium.

Equilibrium and the Dynamical System

In this section we show that the distribution of bequests in period t, bAt and bBt, uniquely determines the equilibrium levels of human and physical capital in period t+1, Et+1, and Kt+1, and therefore uniquely determines period t+1 prices. Moreover, since prices in t+1 and the bequest bjt uniquely determine the bequest to the next generation, the initial bequest distribution (as determined by the initial wealth distribution) uniquely determines the evolution of the economy.

In each period, the economy's equilibrium is determined by the constraint on capital formation, the equality between savings and investments, and by individuals' occupational choices. Because of full depreciation of physical and human capital,

where St denotes aggregate saving in period t.

Savings are accrued by individuals in their first period of life. In the absence of first-period consumption, individuals save the bequest that they receive from their parents. Therefore, the aggregate savings in the economy is

and from (12) and (13),

Given the structure of the production technology (1), human capital is an essential factor of production, whereas physical capital can perfectly substitute for uneducated labor. Therefore, we restrict the analysis to parameter values for which Kt+1≥0 in the model's equilibrium. This implies that

.

The KK line in Figure 2 describes the capital formation equation (14), which presents Kt+1 as a decreasing linear function of Et+1. Based on Figure 1, the EE line in Figure 2 shows Et+1 as a function of Kt+1 for given bAt and bBt.11

In Figure 2, the parameter values ensure that bBt<h.

As Figure 2 shows, the equilibrium values of Kt+1 and Et+1 are unique functions of bAt and bBt since one equation presents a positive relationship between Kt+1 and Et+1, while the other presents a strictly negative relationship.

Equilibrium in the model.

Thus, since bAt and bBt determine Kt+1 and Et+1, which in turn determine bAt+1 and bBt+1, the economy can be characterized by a dynamic system of the form:

APPLICATIONS

In this section we present simulations of some possible patterns for the economy's evolution. We focus on the dynamics of output, Yt, education, Et, physical capital, Kt, and the skill premium. For some parameters, the economy follows a path in which Yt, Et, and Kt monotonically increase while the skill premium monotonically declines.12

The example is based upon the following parameter values: A=10, α=0.5, β=0.3, δ=3, h=2.5, λ=0.5, bA0=2, bB0=0.

This decline indicates that the effect of the increase in the supply for skilled labor dominates the effect of the increase in demand.

Nonmonotonic skill premium dynamics are also possible, as demonstrated by Figure 3.13

This example is based on the parameter values: A=10, α=0.5, β=0.3, δ=4, h=2.6, λ=0.35, bA0=1.98, bB0=0.

The figure shows the dynamics that accompany the economy's monotonic increase of output over time. In the first periods, the number of educated individuals is smaller than the number of individuals in the richer stratum; that is, Et<λ, which means that only individuals from the richer stratum purchase education. In those periods, the increase in Et leads to a decrease in the wage gap. Then, when Et=λ, i.e., when all of the individuals from the rich stratum purchase education, Et temporarily stops increasing and the wage gap begins to widen since Kt continues to grow. During these periods, the individuals in the poor stratum still do not purchase education since they have heavier liquidity constraints than the rich. The wage gap continues to widen until it provides a strong enough incentive for individuals in the poor stratum to purchase education. When this liquidity barrier is overcome, the output growth is once again accompanied by a decreasing wage gap due to an increasing supply of educated labor. In this example, the economy converges to a steady state in which individuals in group B are credit-constrained, that is, limt→∞bBt<h. Therefore, as depicted in Figure 3, wealth inequality, as captured by the wealth Gini coefficient, persists. This persistence of wealth inequality stems from our use of the Galor and Zeira (1993) framework, in the modeling of individuals.

E, K, the wage gap, and the wealth Gini coefficient along the dynamic path that starts at bA=1.98 and bB=0, given A=10, β=0.3, α=0.5, h=2.5, δ=4, λA=0.35, and λB=0.65.

STRATIFICATION AND CYCLES

In this section we show that when the economy's stratification is extended beyond the case of two strata, the wage-gap dynamics may be characterized by profound cyclical behavior. To enhance the role of economic stratification, we use the following utility function:

which is a generalization of the utility function used thus far. Under this utility function, the bequest function is

where

. Thus, the share of bequests is an increasing function of income.

The analysis for the case of three strata (denoted A, B, C, and assuming yA0>yB0>yC0) is similar to the one performed in the previous sections for the case of two strata. Figure 4 shows the evolution of the economy, demonstrating a cyclical pattern of the skill premium.14

This example is based on the parameter values: A=10, α=0.5, h=2.5, β=0.5, a=2.7, δ=3, λA=0.5, λB=0.4, λC=0.1, yA0=2, yB0=1, yC0=0.

E and the wage gap along the dynamic path that starts at bA=2, bB=1, and bC=0, given A=10, α=0.5, h=2.5, β=0.5, δ=3, λA=0.5, λB=0.4, and λC=0.1.

CONCLUDING REMARKS

In this paper we present a general equilibrium model, in which growth stems from physical and human capital accumulation, where skilled labor and physical capital are complementary factors in the production process, and unskilled labor and physical capital are substitutes. We show that the combination of imperfections in the capital markets and socioeconomic stratification can generate nonmonotonic skill premium dynamics.

In the model, the economy's social groups differ in their initial wealth. Because of capital market imperfections, the differences in wealth induce differences in the decisions regarding the purchase of education. Wealth differences can be replaced by stratification based on other variables, such as access to capital markets, differences in the direct cost of education, geographic location, or social barriers. As long as different strata differ in their access to education, the qualitative results of the theory should hold.

The cost of education in our model should not be viewed merely as the college tuition. For example, the social spillover discussed in several recent articles, for example, Benabou (1996a,b), may force the family to move to an appropriate neighborhood, at a large cost, in order to make higher education feasible for the offspring. Moreover, even in the absence of tuition, credit-constrained individuals may avoid higher education due to the consumption cost associated with forgone income during the time spent in school.

We take the simplifying assumption that there is only one level of education. Given the strong empirical evidence that returns to education are highest at the lowest levels of education, this assumption makes our model relevant mostly to the analysis of the decision to purchase higher levels of education.15

For such evidence on the return to education, see Psacharopoulos and Patrinos (2002).

Note that in contrast to Galor and Zeira (1993) and the related literature that focuses on poverty traps and multiple equilibria, the indivisibility of the investment in human capital is not designed to generate persistence of poverty.16

However, note that the nonconvexity of the investment technology is a crucial assumption for the persistence of wealth inequality that could emerge in the model under some parameters.

Its role here is to amplify the impact of credit constraints on investment in human capital, by denying it completely from social groups that are not sufficiently wealthy at a given point in time. Alternatively, preventing investment in education from the poor can be a result of a convex bequest function, as demonstrated by Moav (2002). If, however, the assumption of indivisibility would be partly relaxed, then the model could generate empirical predictions regarding the effect of the return to education on the level of investment in education by the different strata of the economy. In particular, both the less educated (high school dropouts, for instance) and the more educated (individuals with more than 12 years of schooling, for instance) would have a stronger incentive to graduate from high school and college, respectively. This response would introduce an additional mechanism that would offset the increase in the return to education in periods of growth in which the accumulation of physical capital is the main engine of growth.

Finally, a more realistic modeling of the production of human capital would involve an indexation of the cost of education to the wage rate of skilled workers. This modification, however, would demand sacrificing simplicity. Moreover, it would have no qualitative impact on the results since the basic structure of the model, in which individuals differ only in their means of financing education, while the cost of education is identical across all individuals, is unchanged. Nevertheless, this modification can generate an interesting quantitative impact on the magnitude of changes in the education premium, and the duration of the stages of increasing or decreasing premium. A high wage of skilled workers, due to a relatively low supply of skilled workers, can further limit the access of individuals to skilled occupations, potentially increasing both the duration of periods in which the skill premium increases and the magnitude of the increase. In contrast, when the supply of skilled workers is relatively high, their wage, and therefore the cost of education, is low, further easing the access to skilled occupations, and increasing the duration of periods in which the skill premium declines and the magnitude of this decline.

We would like to thank Daron Acemoglu, Oded Galor, Joram Mayshar, Joseph Zeira, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the Ben-Gurion University, University of Haifa, and Hebrew University of Jerusalem for their helpful comments. We thank the Maurice Falk Institute for financial support.

References

Acemoglu D. 1998 Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 1055 1089.Google Scholar
Altonji J.G., F. Hayashi & L.J. Kotlikoff 1997 Parental altruism and inter vivos transfers: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy 105, 1121 1166.Google Scholar
Autor D.H., L.F. Katz & A.B. Krueger 1998 Computing inequality: Have computers changed the labor market? Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 1169 1213.Google Scholar
Baldwin R.E. & G.G. Cain 1997 Shifts in the U.S. Relative Wages: The Role of Trade, Technology and Factor Endowments. NBER working paper 5934.
Becker G.S. & N. Tomes 1986 Human capital and the rise and fall of families. Journal of Labor Economics 4, S1S39.Google Scholar
Benabou R. 1996a Heterogeneity, stratification, and growth: Macroeconomic implications of community structure and school finance. American Economic Review 86, 584 609.Google Scholar
Benabou R. 1996b Equity and efficiency in human capital investment: The local connection. Review of Economic Studies 63, 237 264.Google Scholar
Caselli F. 1999 Technological revolutions. American Economic Review 89, 78102.Google Scholar
Eicher T.S. & C. Garcia-Penalosa 2001 Inequality and growth: The dual role of human capital in development. Journal of Development Economics 66, 173 197.Google Scholar
Galor O. & O. Moav 2000 Ability-biased technological transition, wage inequality, and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115, 469 497.Google Scholar
Galor O. & D. Tsiddon 1997 Technological progress, mobility, and economic growth. American Economic Review 87, 363 382.Google Scholar
Galor O. & J. Zeira 1993 Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies 60, 35 52.Google Scholar
Goldin C. & L.F. Katz 1998 The origins of technology–skill complementarity. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113, 693 732.Google Scholar
Goldin C. & L.F. Katz 2000 Education and income in the early twentieth century: Evidence from the prairies. Journal of Economic History 60, 782 818.Google Scholar
Gottschalk P. 1997 Inequality, income growth and mobility: The basic facts. Journal of Economic Perspectives 11, 21 40.Google Scholar
Gould E.D. 2002 Rising wage inequality, comparative advantage, and the growing importance of general skills in the United States. Journal of Labor Economics 20, 105 147.Google Scholar
Gould E.D., O. Moav & B.E. Weinberg 2001 Precautionary demand for education, inequality and technological progress. Journal of Economic Growth 6, 285 315.Google Scholar
Griliches Z. 1969 Capital–skill complementarity. Review of Economics and Statistics 51, 465 468.Google Scholar
Hassler J. & J. Rodriguez Mora 2000 Intelligence, social mobility, and growth. American Economic Review 90, 888 908.Google Scholar
Juhn C., K.M. Murphy & B. Pierce 1993 Wage inequality and the rise in returns to skill. Journal of Political Economy 101, 410442.Google Scholar
Katz L.F. & K.M. Murphy 1992 Changes in relative wages 1963-87: Supply and demand factors. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 35 78.Google Scholar
Katz L.F., G.W. Loveman & D.G. Blanchflower 1995 A comparison of changes in the structure of wages in four OECD countries. In R.B. Freeman & L.F. Katz (eds.), Differences and Changes in Wage Structure, pp. 25 65. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Krueger A.B. 1993 How computers have changed the wage structure: Evidence from microdata 1984–1989. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 33 60.Google Scholar
Krusell P., L.E. Ohanian, J.-V. Rios-Rull & G.L. Violante 2000 Capital-skill complementarity and inequality: A macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica 68, 1029 1053.Google Scholar
Loury G.C. 1981 Intergenerational transfers and the distribution of earnings. Econometrica 49, 843 867.Google Scholar
Maoz Y.D. & O. Moav 1999 Intergenerational mobility and the process of development. Economic Journal 109, 677 697.Google Scholar
Moav O. 2002 Income distribution and macroeconomics: The persistence of inequality in a convex technology framework. Economics Letters 75, 187 192.Google Scholar
Psacharopoulos G. & H.A. Patrinos 2002 Returns to Investment in Education: A Further Update. World Bank working paper 2881.Google Scholar
Stokey N.L. 1996 Free trade, factor returns, and factor accumulation. Journal of Economic Growth 1, 421 448.Google Scholar
Wilhelm M.O. 1996 Bequest behavior and the effect of heirs' earnings: Testing the altruistic model of bequests. American Economic Review 86, 874 892.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Demand and supply in the market for educated labor.

Figure 1

Equilibrium in the model.

Figure 2

E, K, the wage gap, and the wealth Gini coefficient along the dynamic path that starts at bA=1.98 and bB=0, given A=10, β=0.3, α=0.5, h=2.5, δ=4, λA=0.35, and λB=0.65.

Figure 3

E and the wage gap along the dynamic path that starts at bA=2, bB=1, and bC=0, given A=10, α=0.5, h=2.5, β=0.5, δ=3, λA=0.5, λB=0.4, and λC=0.1.