1. Introduction
Investment treaty law is a goldmine for academics with a compulsion for ordering chaos. Diverging opinions with regard to, for example, the very notion of investment for purposes of determining the scope of investment treaties and the jurisdiction of investment tribunals, the content of the various substantive protections guaranteed by investment treaties (such as the fair and equitable treatment standard or the notion of indirect expropriation), and the role of investment (arbitral) tribunals are simply a fact of life in investment treaty law. Following such compulsion, the article tackles one controversial question: what is the nature of an investment tribunal's review based on the reasonableness of the host state's conduct under an investment treaty? This is a particularly crucial question as investment tribunals are presently engaged in reviewing a very wide range of public acts including the acts of any state organ exercising legislative, executive, judicial or any other functions, whatever position it holds in the organization of the state, and whatever its character as an organ of the central government or of a territorial unit of the state.Footnote 1
Several international investment treaties expressly prohibit host states to adopt ‘unreasonable or discriminatory measures’ that impair the management, maintenance, use, enjoyment or disposal of foreign investmentsFootnote 2 and/or require host state to accord ‘equitable and reasonable treatment and protection’ to foreign investment.Footnote 3 Furthermore, several provisions contained in international investment treaties have been interpreted to impose substantive reasonableness requirements on host states.Footnote 4 For example, the tribunal in Saluka v. Czech Republic interpreted the ‘fair and equitable treatment’ (FET) standard in the Netherlands-Czech Republic Bilateral Investment Treaty (BIT) to include the prohibition to act in a way that is ‘unreasonable (i.e., unrelated to some rational policy), or discriminatory (i.e., based on unjustifiable distinctions).’Footnote 5 In AAPL v. Sri Lanka, the tribunal interpreted the ‘full protection and security’ standard in the United Kingdom-Sri Lanka BIT as imposing a due diligence obligation, which ‘requires undertaking all possible measures that could be reasonably expected to prevent the eventual occurrence of killings and property destructions’.Footnote 6 The tribunal in Glamis Gold v. USA interpreted the customary international law minimum standard of treatment, as codified in Article 1105 North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), to include the prohibition of conduct involving ‘a complete lack of reasons’.Footnote 7 Even in the context of determining the existence of an indirect expropriation, it has been argued that there is no right to compensation for the legitimate and bona fide exercise of sovereign police powers subject inter alia to an analysis of reasonableness.Footnote 8
While in general terms, reasonableness entails ‘a sufficient causal link between the legitimate objective sought and the behaviour that one seeks to establish as reasonable’,Footnote 9 a standard based on the reasonableness of public conduct may more specifically entail a variety of tests involving different levels of intrusiveness in the regulatory prerogatives of states. At the lower end of the intrusiveness spectrum, reasonableness may require that the conduct under review be, at least potentially, capable of positively contributing to the public policy objective at issue. In this context the relevant question is whether the conduct adopted is likely to achieve at least in part the legitimate policy aim.Footnote 10 A standard based on reasonableness may also require that the conduct chosen by the public authority entailed the lowest possible burden to achieve the specific policy goal. In this context, the underlying question is whether the conduct adopted is the most cost-effective in achieving the legitimate policy aim. At the other end of the spectrum, reasonableness may require a balancing of the conduct's costs and benefits with regard to the various interests at stake. Here the key question is whether the impact of the conduct on the investor is proportional to the legitimate policy aim.
As the transnational public lawyer is well aware, these three distinct ‘reasonableness’ tests are neatly captured by the three prongs – ‘suitability’, ‘necessity’ and ‘strict proportionality’ – of the principle of proportionality, which finds its modern origin in German public law and its application in various domestic, regional and international legal systems.Footnote 11
It is on the latter, most intrusive test based on strict balancing or proportionality stricto sensu that this article wishes to focus. While many investment tribunals have referred to ‘reasonableness’ without clearly defining the nature of their review,Footnote 12 in a growing number of cases, investment tribunals appear to have engaged in balancing between the interests of the foreign investor, on the one hand, and the broader public policy interests of the host state. For example, in the context of determining the existence of an indirect expropriation, the tribunal in Tecmed v. Mexico stated that ‘[t]here must be a reasonable relationship of proportionality between the charge or weight imposed to the foreign investor and the aim sought to be realized by any expropriatory measure’.Footnote 13 In a similar context, the tribunal in Suez v. Argentina noted that:
States have a legitimate right to exercise their police powers to protect the public interest and that the doctrine of police powers . . . has been particularly pertinent in cases of expropriation where tribunals have had to balance an investor's property rights with the legitimate and reasonable need for the State to regulate.Footnote 14
In the context of applying the fair and equitable treatment (FET) standard, the tribunal in Saluka v. Czech Republic noted that such standard ‘requires a weighing of the Claimant's legitimate and reasonable expectations on the one hand and the Respondent's legitimate regulatory interests on the other’.Footnote 15 Similarly, the tribunal in Electrabel v. Hungary stated that reasonableness includes ‘the requirement that the impact of the measure on the investor be proportional to the policy objective sought’.Footnote 16
The uncertainty stemming from the growing arbitral practice with regard to the nature and contours of investment tribunals’ review based on reasonableness-type standards is accompanied by an equally growing number of voices calling for investment tribunals to adopt a ‘balanced approach’ in the interpretation of investment treaty standards (such as FET) taking both the interests of investor protection and other interests of social development and environmental protection into account.Footnote 17 More specifically, several commentators have pointed to the principle of proportionality as an instrument to (re)balance the need to afford protection to foreign investors, on the one hand, and the need to guarantee host state's right to regulate in the public interest, on the other.Footnote 18
The article's main argument is that, when reviewing host state conduct on the basis of reasonableness-type standards, investment tribunals should avoid a review based on strict balancing or proportionality in the strict sense (also known as ‘cost-benefit balancing’). This argument is per se not novel and has been justified on various grounds. For example, Ranjan has argued that cost-benefit balancing should be excluded because investment treaty arbitration lacks certain institutional safeguards and constitutional features like ‘independence of the judiciary, appellate review, separation of powers, and a written constitution that gives judges the right to decide which compelling interest should prevail’.Footnote 19 Pirker has justified a similar argument based on the fact that:
the rationale of subsidiarity of virtual representation set out for example in the ECHR [evidenced in the requirement of exhaustion of local remedies, the development of common standards of protection and a project of political integration] does not find its match in international investment protection.Footnote 20
The present article's argument against strict proportionality balancing is instead premised on the complex nature of investment treaties’ ‘object and purpose’, as the crucial element in imparting meaning to the open-textured treaty standards.Footnote 21 The argument is developed in the following three stages. The analysis begins with identifying the ‘object and purpose’ of investment treaties. My conclusion here is that, while investment protection has always been the principal (and often exclusive) focus of investment treaties, the underlying purpose of such treaties has evolved from economic prosperity to sustainable development (Section 2).Footnote 22
Secondly, the analysis addresses the evolving and multi-faceted concept of sustainable development. The focus here is on sustainable development as a policy objective rather than as legal principle. Sharing the views of those that believe that the principle of integration represents the key component of sustainable development, in this section I highlight that, at a primordial level, the concept of sustainable development leaves a wide margin of freedom to the decision-maker in the determination of the appropriate balance between its three key components: economic growth, environmental protection and social development (Section 3).
The third and final stage of the analysis focuses on demonstrating how the specific ‘object and purpose’ identified in the previous two sections justifies the argument against strict balancing or proportionality in the strict sense. As sustainable development revolves around the integration of different values without specifying the ultimate outcome of that balancing process, sustainable development, as the relevant purpose of investment treaties, demands an interpretation of reasonableness-based standards that leaves the balancing of the various interests or values at issue to the public decision-maker (i.e., the host state) (Section 4).
2. The ‘object and purpose’ of investment treaties: From investment protection for economic prosperity to investment protection for sustainable development
Everyone recognizes the importance of identifying the ‘object and purpose’ of an investment treaty. This is indeed expressly required as part of applying the customary general rule of treaty interpretation codified in Article 31 of the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties (VCLT). More fundamentally, the open-textured nature of the various standards provided in an investment treaty makes the identification of the ‘object and purpose’ a crucial element in imparting meaning to those standards.Footnote 23 For purposes of determining the ‘object and purpose’ of a treaty, there are potentially several sources of guidance including the title, preamble, and entire text of the treaty.Footnote 24
Different views have emerged with regard to the question of what is the ‘object and purpose’ of an investment treaty. Focusing on the title of the 1991 Argentina-United States BIT, the Azurix tribunal stated simply that the purpose of the treaty is ‘to encourage and protect investment’.Footnote 25 On the other hand, the LG&E tribunal focused on the apparently broader language found in the preamble of the same US-Argentina BIT and noted that ‘in entering the BIT as a whole, the parties desired to “promote greater economic cooperation” and “stimulate the flow of private capital and the economic development of the parties”’.Footnote 26
For purposes of this discussion, I find it useful to distinguish between the ‘object’ and ‘purpose’ of an investment treaty, as suggested by Buffard and Zemanek. Accordingly, while the ‘object’ of a treaty is the substantial content of the treaty, that is the provisions, rights and obligations created by the treaty, the ‘purpose’ is the reason for establishing the substantial content of the treaty.Footnote 27 The relevance of distinguishing between ‘object’ and ‘purpose’ is to provide a guarantee against an excessively teleological interpretation, whatever the telos may be.Footnote 28
Following this methodology, it may be argued that the ‘object’ of international investment treaties is the protection of foreign investment and the ‘purpose’ of investment treaties is to intensify economic co-operation, encourage international capital flows and increase the prosperity of both contracting parties.Footnote 29 In other words, the investment protection guarantees provided for in the body of the treaty are the instruments with which to encourage capital flows between the two countries and in turn contribute to the prosperity and development of both contracting parties.Footnote 30
Two consequences flow from this argument. First, whether or not one follows the distinction between ‘object’ and ‘purpose’, the point is that ‘most treaties have no single, undiluted object and purpose but rather a variety of different, and possibly conflicting, objects and purposes’.Footnote 31 Accordingly, the object and purpose of an investment treaty cannot merely be the protection of foreign investments, as some tribunals have assumed,Footnote 32 but entails a variety of aims, interests and values. Secondly, and more fundamentally today, given the importance of the preamble in determining the ‘long-term purpose’ of a treaty,Footnote 33 the ‘prosperity’ or ‘development’ of both contracting parties become relevant terms in the identification of the treaty's long-term purpose and thus in imparting meaning to the various open-textured provisions of investment treaties.
Accordingly, the aim of this section is to investigate in more details the long-term purpose of investment treaties and particularly the meaning of the terms ‘prosperity’ and ‘development’, which one can find in the preamble of a great number of investment treaties. Based on an evolutionary interpretation of these terms, this section argues that the long-term ‘purpose’ of investment treaties is sustainable development.
2.1 Economic prosperity as the original, long-term purpose of investment treaties
Much like the 1959 Germany-Pakistan treaty, the great majority of investment treaties signed in the 1960s, 1970s and 1980s, by countries such as Germany, Switzerland, Belgium & Luxembourg, the United Kingdom, Italy and the Netherlands often referred to the ‘prosperity’ of both contracting parties as the treaty's ultimate goal.Footnote 34 Despite the vagueness of the term, in the post-war years ‘prosperity’ meant principally ‘economic growth’. These were the years of growth maximization and trickle-down policies pursued by governments and international assistance organizations alike based on classical economic development theory.Footnote 35 Raising the level of industrial output could increase GNP most rapidly; and as industrial output grew, it would generate more employment and higher incomes, which in turn would raise the level of demand for both agricultural and industrial goods, increase savings, allow for expanded capital formation and generate new investment spreading growth throughout the economic system.Footnote 36
Development scholars at the time emphasized that economic growth was the principal tool for reducing poverty in developing countries and that social services investments would be counterproductive.Footnote 37 National policy-makers believed that environmental protection and natural resource conservation programmes, for example, would inhibit rapid economic growth.Footnote 38
Unsurprisingly then, other investment treaties, particularly those concluded by France, the United States and Japan, contain express references to ‘economic development’ or ‘economic prosperity’ in the preamble of their investment treaties.Footnote 39 Reference to ‘economic development’ can also be found in the preambles of the two draft conventions on foreign investment that were very influential in the initial formation and steady growth of bilateral investment treaties. Both the 1959 Abs-Shawcross Draft Convention on Investments Abroad and the 1962 OECD Draft Convention on the Protection of Foreign Property recognized the ‘importance of promoting the flow of capital for economic activity and development’.Footnote 40 In 2000, Professor Vandevelde interestingly noted that ‘BITs typically assert in their preambles that their purpose is to facilitate international investment flows and thereby promote economic prosperity’ referring, as an example, to the 1993 UK-Armenia BIT, which actually, only referred to (an unqualified) ‘prosperity’.Footnote 41
2.2 Sustainable development as investment treaties’ long-term purpose for the twenty-first century?
Despite the original focus of investment treaties on ‘economic’ prosperity, there are several reasons supporting the argument that the underlying, long-term purpose of investment policies today is best captured by the more complex concept of sustainable development understood, for the time being, as involving the simultaneous pursuit of economic prosperity, environmental quality and social equity.Footnote 42
First, one of the (macro-)economic assumptions underlying investment treaties, that increasing foreign investment will result in economic growth, has been proven at best an over-optimistic assumption. Studies looking at the link between foreign investment and economic development have found that the nature of the relationship between foreign investment and economic growth depends on a variety of situation-specific factors that vary from one country to the next.Footnote 43 Equally, the empirical evidence of the impact of investment treaties on attracting foreign investment is mixed at best.Footnote 44
Second, while economic growth and stability do still matter, development theory and practice has shown that development is multifaceted and includes policies aimed at poverty reduction, protection of the environment, strengthening institutions and improving the human condition.Footnote 45 As noted in a World Bank publication:
[I]t is important to remember that development is far more complex than simply economic growth . . . Development is also the qualitative transformation of a whole society, a shift to new ways of thinking, and, correspondingly, to new relations and new methods of production. Moreover, . . . transformation qualifies as development only if it benefits most people—improves their quality of life and gives them more control over their destinies.Footnote 46
Accordingly, since development should be seen as a broader process involving economic, social, political and legal considerations, economic growth without social equity or economic re-distribution without effective political participation could hardly be regarded as making a meaningful contribution to development.Footnote 47
Third, sustainable development is a widely accepted policy objective of the global community.Footnote 48 From the 1972 Stockholm Declaration, to the 1987 report of World Commission on Environment and Development (the Brundtland Report), the 1992 Rio Declaration, and the 2002 Johannesburg Declaration, the global community has affirmed time after time its commitment to sustainable development. Many international organizations including the United Nations (particularly with the establishment of the Commission on Sustainable Development), the World Bank, the World Trade Organization (WTO), the OECD, the European Union and the African Union, have endorsed the concept of sustainable development.Footnote 49 In his famous separate opinion in Gabčíkovo-Nagymaros Project (Hungary/Slovakia), Vice-President Weeramantry concluded that the principle of sustainable development is a part of modern international law in part because ‘of its wide and general acceptance by the global community’.Footnote 50
It is thus not surprising that the concept of sustainable development has more recently become relevant in the context of international investment law and policy. In a recent survey exploring how investment treaties include language aimed at integrating the goals of investment protection and the promotion of sustainable development (including responsible business conduct), the OECD has found that, more than 75 per cent of treaties signed between 2008 and 2013 refer to at least one of four concerns: environment, labour, anti-corruption and human rights.Footnote 51 Environmental concerns were the first issue to be mentioned in a treaty, appearing in the 1985 China-Singapore BIT, followed by labour issues appearing in the preamble of the 1990 Poland-United States BIT. Anti-corruption appeared in the 2000 Austria-Uzbekistan BIT and human rights concerns were first mentioned in the 2002 Austria-Malta BIT.Footnote 52 References occur most frequently in the investment treaty's preamble.Footnote 53 The preamble of the 2012 Canada-China BIT provides an interesting example as it refers expressly (and exclusively) to ‘sustainable development’, as follows:
THE GOVERNMENT OF CANADA AND THE GOVERNMENT OF THE PEOPLE'S REPUBLIC OF CHINA (the “Contracting Parties”),
RECOGNIZING the need to promote investment based on the principles of sustainable development;
DESIRING to intensify the economic cooperation of both States, based on equality and mutual benefit;
HAVE AGREED as follows.Footnote 54
In 2012, recognizing that a new generation of investment polices was emerging placing inclusive growth and sustainable development at the heart of efforts to attract, and benefit from, investment, UNCTAD formulated a comprehensive Investment Policy Framework for Sustainable Development (IPFSD) to serve as a point of reference for policymakers in formulating national investment policies and in negotiating or reviewing international investment treaties.Footnote 55
2.3 Investment treaties, sustainable development and evolutionary interpretation
While the majority of recently signed investment treaties seem to make express reference in the preamble or in the substantive provisions to sustainable development or to environmental, labour or human rights,Footnote 56 the inclusion of such language is still relatively rare if one considers the overall stock of investment treaties. On the basis of a sample comprising 70 per cent of all investment treaties, the OECD has recently estimated that only 12 per cent of all investment treaties contain a sustainable development-related reference.Footnote 57 However, despite the lack of any express reference to sustainable development in most investment treaties, it is here argued that, based on an evolutionary interpretation of their preambles, the long-term purpose of most (3,000 plus) investment treaties is in fact sustainable development.
There is general support for an evolutionary interpretation in case of general treaty terms or terms that are ‘by definition evolutionary’. The International Court of Justice (ICJ), in its Namibia Opinion, has given terms such as ‘the strenuous conditions of the modern world’ or ‘the well-being and development of such peoples’ an evolving meaning by referring to the evolution of the right of peoples to self-determination after the Second World War.Footnote 58 The Appellate Body of the World Trade Organization (WTO) held that ‘the generic term “natural resources” in Article XX(g) is not “static” in its content or reference but is rather “by definition, evolutionary”’.Footnote 59 The basis for such decisions is the intention of the parties: ‘the idea is that the parties chose particular expressions with the knowledge and intention that these expressions would be capable of evolving over time’.Footnote 60 Since evolutionary intention is rarely expressed in the treaty, courts and tribunals have presumed such intention particularly from the ‘general’ character of the terms to be interpreted. In its judgement in Dispute regarding Navigational and Related Rights (Costa Rica v. Nicaragua), having found that the term ‘comercio’ was a generic term, the ICJ noted that the parties must necessarily have been aware that its meaning was likely to evolve over time, or in other words, ‘the parties must be presumed . . . to have intended those terms to have an evolving meaning’.Footnote 61 The Court strengthened the presumption by adding that ‘the treaty has been entered into for a very long period’.Footnote 62 When it comes to the evidence necessary to establish the substance of the term's new meaning, the interpreter will be able to rely on changing legal or factual circumstances,Footnote 63 meaning developments in international law as well as in social or economic concepts.
While evolutionary interpretation has mostly been applied with regard to terms found in treaties’ substantive provisions, the same doctrine should be applicable when it comes to the interpretation of terms found in the treaty preamble in order to ascertain the treaty's long-term purpose. Accordingly, an evolutionary interpretation appears possible when it comes to attribute meaning to generic terms such as ‘prosperity’, ‘development’, ‘benefits’, particularly when they are unqualified. I should, once again, emphasize that these are the terms that are crucial in order to identify the long-term purpose of an investment treaty. As noted above, in the preamble of their 1959 BIT, Germany and Pakistan recognized that their agreement ‘is likely to promote investment, encourage private industrial and financial enterprise and to increase the prosperity of both the States’.
Dictionary definitions of ‘prosperity’ are ambiguous. While they encompass in principle a wide set of circumstances (‘a situation in which people enjoy wealth, success, or good fortune’; from Latin pro spere, ‘according to expectations’; from pro, ‘for’ + spes, ‘hope’), they also appear to have an economic or financial slant, in particular (‘an economic state of growth with rising profits and full employment’;Footnote 64 ‘the state of being prosperous’ that is ‘successful or flourishing, especially financially’Footnote 65 ). Something similar could be said for the term ‘development’: contrast, for example, ‘the process or fact of developing; the concrete result of this process’ or ‘gradual advancement through progressive stages, growth from within’, on the one hand, with ‘the economic advancement of a region or people, esp. one currently under-developed’, on the other.Footnote 66
It is here argued that, given their generic nature and the potentially long life of the underlying treaties, terms such as ‘prosperity’ and ‘development’ can today be interpreted on the basis of certain evolving factual circumstances. As noted in the previous section, economic and development theories have evolved away from economic growth-centred policies, and the last 30–40 years have witnessed the progressive rise of the concept of sustainable development as a central policy objective of the international community.
The argument based on evolutionary interpretation has, however, certain limits. How about those investment treaties, which refer expressly to ‘economic’ prosperity or ‘economic’ development? The answer here may depend on the strength of at least two sets of arguments. A first argument in favour of an evolutionary interpretation of terms such as ‘economic prosperity’ or ‘economic development’ may depend on the ‘age’ of the applicable investment treaty. Accordingly, an evolutionary interpretation in the direction suggested above would seem possible even with regard to an investment treaty that expressly refers in the preamble to ‘economic development’ as its long-term objective, at least where such treaty was signed before the mid-1990s. The rationale here is that only from the late 1990s it can be said that the concept of sustainable development has taken centre stage and thus an express reference to ‘economic’ prosperity or development as the long-term objective of an investment treaty cannot be read, on the basis of an evolutionary interpretation, to mean ‘sustainable’ development.
A second argument in favour of an evolutionary interpretation may be based on the evolving definition of ‘economic development’ in economics. In his textbook on Economic Growth and Development, Professor Van den Berg has suggested a definition of the term ‘economic development’ that is broader than the one provided by orthodox, or mainstream, economists. According to Van den Berg, ‘[e]conomic development describes the full range of changes in humanity's economic, social, and natural environments that are perceived by people as making life more pleasant and satisfying’.Footnote 67
3. Sustainable development and the principle of integration
While sustainable development is an evolving and multi-faceted concept,Footnote 68 one can identify at least three, interrelated key elements of such concept: inter-generational equity (to preserve natural resources for the benefit of future generations), intra-generational equity (to ensure that all people within the current generation are able to meet their basic needs) and integrative decision-making (to integrate economic growth, environmental protection and social development at all levels of decision-making). In a recent World Bank Institute publication, Soubbotina captures these three key elements as follows:
“Sustainable” development could probably be otherwise called “equitable and balanced”, meaning that, in order for development to continue indefinitely, it should balance the interests of different groups of people, within the same generation and among generations, and do so simultaneously in three major interrelated areas—economic, social, and environmental. So sustainable development is about equity, defined as equality of opportunities for well-being, as well as about comprehensiveness of objectives.Footnote 69
These three elements also explain the popularity of sustainable development as a shared aspiration of the global community. In principle, a broad understanding of equity spanning over time and space as well as the realization of the complexity and interconnectedness of our economic, environmental and social challenges cannot but be seen as the enlightened vision for the twenty-first century. Equally, however, these three elements explain the global community's frustration with its attempt to actually achieve sustainable development. In a way, the higher the vision, the greater the difficulty in achieving it.
Despite its evolving and multifaceted nature, I share the view according to which integrative (or integrated) decision-making (or the principle of integration) is the ‘most important’ element of sustainable development.Footnote 70
Tladi highlights two dimensions of integration. At one level, he notes that under the classic definition of sustainable development given in the Brundtland Commission reportFootnote 71 ‘intergenerational equity concerns have to be balanced against immediate, intragenerational equity concerns’.Footnote 72 On another level, Tladi emphasizes that ‘[a]t the heart of the Brundtland Commission report lies a call for integration. The Report describes the various economic, social and environmental problems as “interlocking crises” requiring an integrated solution’.Footnote 73 The two dimensions are obviously interwoven as meeting the needs of the future depends crucially on how well we balance economic, environmental and social objectives or needs when making decisions today.Footnote 74 The list of relevant needs is open-ended and subject to evolution. The World Bank Institute has highlighted the following: under economic needs it includes generally ‘services’, ‘household needs’, ‘industrial growth’, ‘agricultural growth’, and ‘efficient use of labour’; under environmental needs, it includes ‘biodiversity’, ‘rational use and conservation of natural resources’, ‘carrying capacity’, ‘ecosystem integrity’, and ‘clean air and water’; and under social needs, it lists ‘equity’, ‘participation’, ‘empowerment’, ‘social mobility’ and ‘cultural preservation’.Footnote 75
Accordingly, in the context of achieving sustainable development, integration will require two kinds of decision-making exercises. First, since the various economic, environmental and social needs may be mutually supportive (for example, economic growth may lead to greater equity through the ability of governments to fund stronger welfare systems; or economic growth may lead to rational use of natural resources through the ability to afford more efficient technology), integrative decision-making will demand establishing those positive links across the various needs. Second, since these various objectives may indeed be in conflict with one another (for example, economic growth may lead to inequity or environmental degradation), integrative decision-making will require a complex and delicate balancing exercise. The 2002 Johannesburg Declaration on Sustainable Development noted states, ‘collective responsibility to advance and strengthen the interdependent and mutually reinforcing pillars of sustainable development—economic development, social development and environmental protection—at the local, national, regional and global levels’.Footnote 76
In the policy discussions, at least at the international level, one often hears the rhetoric of ‘mutual supportiveness’, only. For example, in the preamble of the Doha Declaration, WTO Members have highlighted their conviction that ‘the aims of upholding and safeguarding an open and non-discriminatory multilateral trading system, and acting for the protection of the environment and the promotion of sustainable development, can and must be mutually supportive’.Footnote 77
However, a large part of the attractiveness of the concept of sustainable development rests on an understanding of integration as balancing different, and often conflicting needs, without any hierarchy between the three pillars (economic growth, environmental protection and social development). The crucial aspect here is that the balancing between the various needs or objectives has no a priori correct outcome that is inherent in the very concept of sustainable development. The actual outcome of a given balancing exercise will crucially depend on the relevance given, by the decision-maker, to the various economic, environmental and social needs at issue in the specific case. In this sense, the principle of integration focuses on establishing an appropriate process capable of achieving sustainable development rather than providing the result of that balance.Footnote 78 In other words, the pursuit of sustainable development according to the integration principle will entail the need to take all three dimensions into account in development decision-making.Footnote 79 This process-based approach will include the creation of ‘interlocking mechanisms’, such as environmental or social units in development-related departments at the national and international levels, the use of sustainability or ‘integrated’ impact assessments, as well as information exchanges and co-operative strategies at and across all levels of government, whether national or international.Footnote 80 Practices, standards and rules will of course develop over time with regard to addressing and resolving specific issues and specific balancing conundrums. However, the point I want to stress here is that, at a primordial level, the concept of sustainable development leaves a lot of freedom to the decision-maker in the determination of the appropriate balance between economic growth, environmental protection and social development.
For example, a decision to privatize the provision of waste services by a local municipality may provide the opportunity to appreciate integrative decision-making for purposes of pursuing sustainable development. Privatization will potentially allow foreign investors to bid for the relative waste service licenses or concessions. That in turn may lead to an injection of hard capital and new technology that may be mutually beneficial in terms of economic growth (more jobs, higher corporate tax), environmental protection (less pollution) and social development (better paid jobs). These positive spill-overs may depend on many factors including the content of regulation underlying the specific license or concession, as well as any other general legislation addressing performance requirements applicable to foreign investors, environmental laws as well as corporate practice including social responsibility ones.
However, there will also be balancing decisions to be made. For example, the local municipality will need to identify a waste disposal site within its territory. That decision may have a negative impact on the local environment (at least with regard to the specific area where the site is located) as well as on the profitability of the business (for example, if the site is located in a remote area) and the social development of the municipality (for example, if the site is located in an already deprived area within the municipality). Alternatively, the municipality may decide to transfer and dispose of the waste outside its territory maximizing the benefits to its environment, which will, however, put a greater burden on its finances. Similarly, the municipality may also decide to grant a tax incentive in order to attract a waste disposal provider that can guarantee a more environmentally-friendly technology or in order to require the waste disposal provider to expand and improve waste collection to more deprived parts of the municipality. All of these decisions will entail balancing costs and benefits across the three pillars of sustainable development. Crucially, having fully considered the facts at issues and the various relevant implications, it will be for the municipality to strike the appropriate balance between economic growth, environmental protection and social development on the basis of its policy priorities and choices as the concept of sustainable development is not by itself capable of providing for such balancing.
Accordingly, the principle of integration, as the key component of sustainable development, emphasizes the need to take into account economic growth, environmental protection and social development. In certain circumstances, this will lead to a maximization of all three policy values (a triple win situation). In other cases, this will require a balancing exercise, which will entail the determination of winners and losers. Crucially, the determination of the appropriate balance between economic growth, environmental protection and social development is not found in the concept of sustainable development but is left to the relevant decision maker.
4. Integrative decision-making and reasonableness standards: What kind of review for investment tribunals?
As noted in the introduction, investment treaty tribunals are called to review the conduct of host states on the basis of a variety of norms principally found in investment treaties. Some of these norms include substantive reasonableness requirements embodied for example in the fair and equitable treatment standard and the prohibition of uncompensated indirect expropriation.
Reasonableness, particularly in its substantive connotation, is a notoriously ubiquitous and imprecise concept. It is employed in a variety of different contexts, for example, as a ground of judicial review of administrative conductFootnote 81 or as a parameter for the constitutionality review of laws.Footnote 82 More fundamentally, reasonableness includes a variety of different normative standards or tests: from the more generic (or tautological) ones like the famous Wednesbury formulation in English law – ‘so unreasonable that no reasonable authority could ever come to it’,Footnote 83 to the more structured ones such as the three-pronged proportionality test (suitability, necessity and proportionality stricto sensu) in German and EU law.Footnote 84
As noted above, despite the different origin and terminology, the overlap between reasonableness and proportionality is extensive.Footnote 85 Both concepts entail first of all, a review of whether the public decision is effective in, or materially contributes to, achieving its purported objective (or the ‘means’ employed by the public authority are rationally related to the ‘ends’ pursued).Footnote 86 Second, they include an inquiry on whether the public decision under review is necessary to achieve its purported aim (or no other less costly means capable of pursuing that same aim exists). Finally, both reasonableness and proportionality may entail a review of whether the public decision has an excessive impact on the applicant's interests compared to the benefits to the chosen public policy.
The appeal (and success) of the proportionality principle, as a global judicial review mechanism,Footnote 87 lies in part on the clarity with which its various (reasonableness) components are laid out.Footnote 88 Scholars have repeatedly noted that the three prongs of proportionality (suitability, necessity and proportionality stricto sensu) constitute an ascending series in terms of the intrusiveness of the review of public decisions.Footnote 89 Crucially, unless the law-maker expressly provides which of the various components (e.g., suitability, necessity, proportionality stricto sensu) are applicable, the choice of which test to apply is left to the adjudicator.
The central point for purposes of this article is that the difference in the level of intrusiveness is linked to the different nature of the various tests or tenets falling under reasonableness or proportionality. Particularly, ‘suitability’ and ‘necessity’ differ from ‘proportionality stricto sensu’ since the former take as given the policy objective(s) pursued by the public authority (say environmental protection) including the specific level(s) of protection chosen by that public authority (say zero pollution). Going back to our waste disposal scenario, a review based on suitability and necessity would involve the following inquiries: first, does the decision to (re)locate the waste disposal facility outside the territory of the municipality contribute to achieve the zero environmental pollution aim chosen by the municipality? Second, are there alternative options to the decision to (re)locate the facility outside the territory, which would be capable of achieving the same zero environmental pollution aim at a lesser cost? In principle, while implying two different level of intrusiveness in the decision-making of the municipality, the two tests never put into question the chosen level of environmental protection.
When it comes to proportionality in the strict sense, the adjudicator will zoom in on those very choices and balance the costs and benefits of the public decision: is the adverse economic impact (including on the foreign investment) of the decision to (re)locate disproportionate vis-à-vis the environmental benefits of a zero pollution policy? It is for this reason that courts and tribunals, particularly at the international level, appear to exercise caution when it comes to this type of balancing. For example, the Appellate Body (AB) of the WTO has so far stayed away from a cost/benefit balancing expressly noting that WTO Members have the right to determine for themselves the desired level of protection.Footnote 90 The AB example is noteworthy as it shows how sometimes the term ‘balancing’ is used loosely in the context of a determination of suitability or necessity to emphasize that the court or tribunal needs to consider different aspects.Footnote 91 However, it is only within the third prong (of proportionality in the strict sense) that a court or tribunal is called upon to balance between different values or interests.
Accordingly, in light of the fact that sustainable development is the underlying long-term purpose of the investment treaty (as argued above), an investment tribunal should interpret, say, the FET standard or the provision on expropriation or the prohibition of arbitrary, unjustifiable or unreasonable measures to exclude a review that entails a balancing between the various values or interests at issue. As noted above, the crucial aspect of the concept of sustainable development understood as the integration of economic growth, environmental protection and social development, is that the balancing between the various needs or objectives has no a priori correct outcome that is inherent in the concept of sustainable development. The actual outcome of a given balancing exercise will crucially depend on the relevance given, by the decision-maker, to the various economic, environmental and social needs at issue in the specific case. Accordingly, in the context of a (substantive) reasonableness review carried out by an arbitral tribunal under an investment treaty, where the treaty itself does not specify the type of review,Footnote 92 cost-benefit balancing should be excluded.
In other words, the recognition that the (narrow) ‘object’ of an investment treaty is an instrument to achieve the (broader) ‘purpose’ of sustainable development has two implications. First, the investment treaty recognizes the existence of values (economic growth, environmental protection, social development) that are greater than affording protection to foreign investors. Second, the reasonableness-type standards imposed on host states for the protection of foreign investment do not impose any restraints on states’ balancing among those values. Accordingly, an interpretation of investment treaty provisions requiring reasonableness in light of the object and purpose of the investment treaty will exclude a review based on the measure's proportionality in the strict sense.
Two additional clarifications should be made here. First, our argument against strict balancing does not per se undermine investment protection (as the relevant ‘object’ of investment treaties). An interpretation of reasonableness-type standards in light of sustainable development does not prevent an investment tribunal's application of ‘suitability’ and ‘necessity’. As noted above, rather than simply procedural, the nature of the review based on these tests is substantive, including, for example, whether there are sufficient grounds for the public action under review or whether the action taken is the most effective or efficient measure available. Accordingly, a review based on ‘suitability’ and ‘necessity’ will involve a meaningful, substantive review of host state conduct, albeit a more limited type of review, one that does not include reviewing the attribution of values or the setting of policy priorities by the host state.
Second, it should also be emphasized that investment tribunals operating such limited type of review (based on suitability and necessity) will still be facing some difficult and sensitive decisions such as determining (a) the extent of the means-end relationship between the host state measure and the public policy objective being pursued with that measure; (b) the level of protection aimed at by the host state; (c) the existence of less restrictive alternatives that are reasonably available to the host state; and (d) the standard of review (i.e., the intensity of the review) carried out under suitability and necessity. The experience of international adjudicative bodies, in particular those in similarly monothematic institutions (such as the WTO), will certainly offer very useful insights on these various challenges.Footnote 93
5. Concluding Remarks
The number of critics of the investment treaty system has grown in the past few years. Many of the criticism are legitimate and need to be addressed. This article attempts to deal with one critical question: how far should investment tribunal go in reviewing host state conduct on the basis of investment treaties? The article's answer is that, when reviewing host state conduct on the basis of reasonableness-type standards, investment tribunals should avoid a review based on strict balancing or proportionality in the strict sense (also known as cost-benefit balancing).
The argument advanced in the article is, first of all, addressed to, and can be taken up by, the treaty interpreter. Called upon to exercise their adjudicative functions, investment treaty tribunals need to appreciate the complex nature of the treaty's ‘object and purpose’. While investment treaties focus on investment protection, they are fundamentally aimed at achieving broader objectives, such as prosperity, development and in particular today, sustainable development. In light of the complexity of investment treaties’ object and purpose, investment protection standards that focus on the reasonableness of the host state conduct should be read to exclude any strict balancing or proportionality requirements. Given the fact that investment treaty protection are ultimately aimed at enabling states’ pursuit of a variety of (at times conflicting) policy interests, investment tribunals should leave the balancing of such interests to the states. While this is no revolutionary suggestion, it is important to clearly lay the outer boundaries of the function of an international investment tribunal.Footnote 94
The case against strict balancing is also very much relevant for the policy (or treaty) maker. There is a very lively debate among policy makers about the scope and content of future international investment disciplines. Policy makers are well aware of the key challenges that they are facing.Footnote 95 International investment policies (including treaties) are not simply about encouraging foreign investment but they are about ensuring economic growth, environmental protection and social equity. Investment treaties should not simply afford a ‘strong protection to investors and investments’ but they should also preserve ‘the authority to adopt and maintain measures necessary to regulate in the public interest to pursue certain public policies’.Footnote 96 Accordingly, future international investment disciplines should expressly clarify that investment protection standards do not involve any strict balancing. Current proposals on the negotiating table for a Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) between the European Union and the United States show mixed signals: the general provision guaranteeing the right of the Parties to regulate through measures necessary to achieve legitimate policy objectivesFootnote 97 is accompanied by a definition of ‘indirect expropriation’ that entails forms of strict balancing.Footnote 98
In addition, in order to bring about greater clarity, excluding strict balancing from the realm of international investment disciplines would fundamentally strengthen the legitimacy of the entire investment system. As long as the system remains limited in its subject-matter (such as the name of the TTIP clearly indicates), any attempt to include disciplines that encompass balancing between investors’ interests and broader public policy values will lead to controversy, resistance and ultimately failure. This is not so much because of the alleged inability of international tribunals to perform such balancing exercise when an actual dispute arises. It is the very monothematic nature of the investment treaty system (as it principally focuses on affording protection to foreign investments) that does not allow for an accurate and thus legitimate balancing of a variety of different interests, policies and values to take place. This is one of the consequences of the multiplication (and success) of specialized regimes and thus fragmentation of international law. Obviously strict balancing by an international court or tribunal is in principle technically and politically possible but only in broader and more integrated systems (such as within the European Convention of Human Rights or the European Union). Short of that, excluding any such balancing represents one of the techniques for the ‘peaceful’ cohabitation of specialized regimes in international law.