Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-g4j75 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T16:44:23.213Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Latin American Politics and the Subnational Comparative Method: Vertical and Horizontal Challenges

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 June 2020

Kent Eaton*
Affiliation:
Kent Eaton is a professor in the Department of Politics, University of California, Santa Cruz.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Decentralization has triggered widespread use of the subnational comparative method in the study of Latin American politics. Simultaneously, it has created challenges for this method that deserve careful attention. While subnational governments after decentralization can often be treated as potentially autonomous policy jurisdictions, their autonomy is also subject to new constraints and incursions, which may limit scholars’ ability to treat them as relatively independent units. By taking stock of the vibrant literature that has emerged in recent years, this article explores three major challenges that complicate the use of the subnational comparative method. Two are vertical in nature: how to theorize national causes of subnational variation, and how the varied linkages between subnational governments and transnational actors can be conceptualized in work that compares subnational units. The third challenge is horizontal, referring to interactions between governments at the same subnational level that can either enhance or subvert autonomy.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© University of Miami 2020

Decentralization has simultaneously facilitated and complicated the use of the subnational comparative method in Latin America. In a wave of reform that began in the 1970s and gained in speed and extension across the 1980s and 1990s, decentralization brought into being “potentially autonomous policy jurisdictions at the subnational level” (Snyder Reference Snyder2001a, 15). It was decentralization that set the stage for the much greater adoption of the subnational comparative method, not just because it touched so many countries but because it affected such a wide array of policy fields within those countries.Footnote 1 In addition, because policy decentralization was typically adopted alongside political decentralization (i.e., subnational elections), it became easier to credibly claim that directly elected subnational governments could now be treated as relatively independent units, no longer controlled from above by national governments that would previously appoint and remove subnational officials at will.

While decentralization generated a sizable literature on what caused it and how it changed intergovernmental relations (Arretche Reference Arretche2000; Falleti Reference Falleti2010; Fenwick Reference Fenwick2016; Souza Reference Souza1997; Tendler Reference Tendler1997; Ward et al. Reference Ward, Rodríguez and Mendoza1999), the phenomenon also meant that scholars who were not particularly interested in decentralization or its causes—or even in territorial politics more generally defined—could nevertheless take advantage of it as an event that enabled the controlled comparison of subnational units within the same country. In this sense, decentralization increased the number of observations for the generation and testing of theories that had little to do with subnational governments per se, but that advanced our understanding of the major issues that have dominated comparative politics as a subfield, including regime type and regime change (Abrucio Reference Abrucio1998; Basset et al. Reference Basset, Cerón and Pérez2017; Behrend and Whitehead 2016; Gervasoni Reference Gervasoni2010, 2018; Gibson Reference Gibson2013; Giraudy Reference Giraudy2015), clientelism (Montam- beault 2011; Szwarcberg Reference Szwarcberg2013; Weitz-Shapiro Reference Weitz-Shapiro2014), participatory institutions (Avritzer 2002; Baiocchi Reference Baiocchi2005; Faguet Reference Faguet2013; Goldfrank Reference Goldfrank2011; McNulty Reference McNulty2011; Wampler Reference Wampler2007), parties and party systems (Batlle Reference Batlle2009; Freidenberg and SuárezCao 2014; Luna Reference Luna2014; Montero 2012), state capacity (Harbers Reference Harbers2015; Ponce and McClintock 2014; Pribble Reference Pribble2015; Soifer Reference Soifer2016), and indigenous representation (Paredes and Došek this issue; Van Cott Reference Van Cott2008).

Inspired by the emergence of “potentially autonomous policy jurisdictions,” one important strand of the literature that uses the subnational comparative method has been designed to explain policy outcomes as the chief dependent variable—even as other scholarship focused on decentralization or intergovernmental relations as the main outcomes of interest (Abrucio Reference Abrucio1998; Falleti Reference Falleti2010; Restrepo Reference Restrepo2015; Souza Reference Souza1997). The striking feature of this policy-centered work is the substantive range of policy issues examined, along with the tremendous subnational variation that it has uncovered and explained. Much of the early work was conducted in the aftermath of economic adjustment and focused on economic policy, asking why subnational governments varied in terms of their industrial policy choices (Montero Reference Montero2001), regulatory behavior (Snyder Reference Snyder2001a), and fiscal profligacy (Wibbels Reference Wibbels2005).

As insecurity displaced economic woes at the top of the list of citizen concerns in Latin America, scholars expanded the focus to include security policy in research that explained why, for example, Mexican and Colombian cities responded so differently to common security threats (Moncada Reference Moncada2016; Durán-Martínez Reference Durán-Martínez2018), why police reform played out so differently across Argentine provinces (Binder Reference Binder2004; Fohrig and Pomares Reference Fohrig, Pomares, Frühling and Candina2004; Flom Reference Flom2016), and why local responses to smuggling operations varied in lowland and highland Bolivia (Alberti Reference Alberti2017).Footnote 2

Perhaps the most consistent focus of scholarly attention has been social policy, beginning with Marta Arretche’s influential study of variation across four different social policy sectors in six Brazilian states (2000). More recently, scholars of social policy have sought to explain territorial unevenness in the adoption or implementation of conditional cash transfers (Fenwick Reference Fenwick2016; Sugiyama Reference Sugiyama2013; Niedzwiecki Reference Niedzwiecki2018), variation in the quality of health care (Alves Reference Alves2015, Bonvecchi Reference Bonvecchi2008, Lima and Viana Reference Lima and Viana2011), and inequality in the access to social services across subnational units (Giraudy and Pribble Reference Giraudy and Pribble2019 and this issue; Otero-Bahamón Reference Otero-Bahamón2019 and this issue).

The decentralization of policy and political authority, more than any other governance trend, has made possible the subnational comparative method, but it has also created challenges for the use of this method that deserve further consideration, discussion, and analysis. Now is a good time to conceptualize and consider these challenges, given the spate of important work over the past decade that has deployed the subnational comparative method to explain variation across subnational units in the content of policy outcomes. My goal in this article is to explore the tension that exists between considering subnational jurisdictions as potentially autonomous units in which the analyst can make largely independent observations, on the one hand, and the messy reality that decentralization has also enmeshed subnational governments in a series of new vertical and horizontal relationships that impose additional constraints on their ability to act autonomously. While decentralization undoubtedly transferred policy authority to subnational units that had simultaneously become much more politically independent, it was also designed in ways that often maintained or increased within those units the influence of the national government (Falleti Reference Falleti2010), of other subnational governments, and of actors and forces outside the country altogether.Footnote 3

As the articles in this special issue demonstrate, widespread attempts by the national government to enforce uniformity across subnational districts—which sometimes succeed and sometimes fail—should be understood as a major threat to the policy autonomy of those districts (Harbers and Steele this issue). Uniformity can be thought of as the flipside of autonomy, and it can result either from a concentrated policy push on the part of the national government (e.g., Otero-Bahamón this issue; Giraudy and Pribble this issue), or as a reform’s unintended consequences (e.g., Cleary this issue).

Simply put, what this article does is explore the significance of one particularly critical word in the quote from Richard Snyder above: the subnational comparative method requires “potentially autonomous policy jurisdictions at the subnational level” (italics mine). There is very good reason to consider subnational governments in post-decentralization Latin America as potentially autonomous policy jurisdictions, at the same time that we have to remain mindful of how that autonomy is constantly threatened, defended, or subverted in the course of political life. According to the central argument that I develop in this article, scholars who use the subnational comparative method confront three main challenges that are conceptualized here, for purposes of tractability, as fundamentally either vertical or horizontal in nature.

With respect to the first vertical challenge, the beauty of the subnational comparative method for many scholars is that it enables them to control for the national government in ways that bring into relief the causal force of purely subnational variables. Holding constant the national government is appealing but problematic if it continues to impinge unevenly on the potential autonomy of subnational units, with autonomy understood as the ability of subnational elected officials to pursue policy preferences that do not align with the center.

Based on my survey of the literature that uses the subnational comparative method, I note that theorists have differed widely in their response to this problem. Whereas some scholars have bracketed the national government theoretically, others have endowed it with exclusive causal power in regard to subnational outcomes. Still others have articulated hybrid theories that assign causal power to both national and subnational drivers of subnational outcomes. Hybrid theories are especially appealing in terms of those (likely numerous) cases in which the autonomy of subnational units is neither absolute nor altogether absent.

To be clear, my argument is not that the national government’s continuing causal influence in post-decentralization Latin America invalidates the use of the subnational comparative method; even in low-autonomy environments, subnational officials may still enjoy some amount of discretion, despite constraints on their autonomy. My argument instead is that theory building in these cases should explicitly address and accommodate these constraints rather than bracket them, whatever their (vertical or horizontal) source.

In addition to the more visible vertical challenge posed by the continuing but uneven influence of the national government, scholars who use the subnational comparative method also face a second, less visible vertical challenge in the form of international and transnational actors above the nation-state. These external actors have highly disparate preferences regarding the autonomy of subnational governments. With less literature to draw on here, I argue that these external actors can take a number of different forms and that their behaviors may either constrain or facilitate subnational autonomy.

Besides these two vertical challenges, a different kind of possible challenge comes laterally, from other subnational governments at the same level of analysis. Scholars can safely treat the relationship between a subnational unit and the center as fundamentally bilateral when that unit is highly insulated from other subnational units, but otherwise they will need to explicitly theorize the role of horizontal dynamics. While we think of decentralization as a fundamentally vertical phenomenon, it also reshaped relations between subnational units in ways that I conceptualize as taking three main forms: cooperation, conflict, and contagion.

This article is organized into four main sections. The following section makes the case for the special importance of autonomy in invoking the subnational comparative method and briefly discusses the factors that especially recommend the use of this method in Latin America. Subsequent sections examine each of the three different types of challenges that nonetheless beset the subnational comparative method.

Using the Subnational Comparative Method to Study Latin American Politics

As Giovanni Sartori (Reference Sartori1970, 1035) reminded us long ago, to compare is to control. Herein lies the chief appeal of the subnational comparative method. By definition, subnational jurisdictions in the same country have in common their shared status as subnational jurisdictions; no subnational unit is more or less a constituent unit in the country of which it forms a part. This means that analysts can control for many factors that vary from country to country but that do not vary within a country, including such variables as whether the national government uses presidential or parliamentary forms, whether legal institutions reflect civil or common law traditions, and whether or not the country belongs to any given international organization.Footnote 4

According to Snyder (Reference Snyder2001b, 96), “subnational units within a single country can often be more easily matched on cultural, historical, ecological, and socioeconomic dimensions than can national units,” though he is careful to emphasize that “withinnation comparisons do not necessarily improve our ability to hold these dimensions constant” (italics in original). Because subnational regions in country X can be less similar to other subnational regions in country X than they are to subnational regions just across an international border in country Y, Snyder’s central recommendation is that scholars analyze contiguous subnational units across national borders. Surprisingly few scholars have heeded this call to simultaneously conduct within-nation and between-nation comparisons of contiguous units, even though Snyder’s article on the subnational comparative method is by far the most influential and widely cited for those who have adopted it in their research. Far more common are studies that explicitly compare subnational units within the same country while controlling for the national government, as discussed in the following section.

Why is the potential autonomy of subnational jurisdictions so important for the subnational comparative method? After all, there are good reasons to suspect that subnational governments are rarely fully autonomous, or entirely able to disregard the preferences of powerful national actors. Unlike the nation-state, which often enjoys significant autonomy relative to supranational actors, thanks to the sovereignty norms that govern the international system, subnational governments face multiple limitations on their autonomy; the relationship between subnational and national governments is simply not analogous to the relationship between states and supranational actors (Gibson Reference Gibson2013). In the context of Latin America’s “centralist traditions” (Veliz Reference Veliz1980), the “potential autonomy of subnational governments” can be understood to refer to their ability to adopt and implement policies that diverge from the preferences of the national government in a relevant policy area. In other words, can elected subnational officials ignore or evade the various inducements and constraints coming from national governments in the attempt to dictate subnational outcomes?

Here it is important to clarify that my argument is not that constraints on autonomy invalidate the use of the subnational comparative method, but instead that the degree to which subnational governments are constrained and the source of these constraints should inform theory building in general and the plausibility of holding constant the role of the national government in particular. As I will argue below, the less the autonomy of subnational governments, the greater the need to fold the national government into theory building, as opposed to discounting it theoretically. More generally, the source of the threat to autonomy—whether it is coming vertically from national or transnational actors or horizontally from other subnational governments—should be incorporated into theories that try to account for variation in outcomes across subnational units.

While the subnational comparative method is by no means limited to Latin America, one can argue that it is especially indicated there for a number of reasons, some of which have to do with how decentralization was designed in the region and some of which have to do with broader political dynamics. First is the predominance of symmetrical rather than asymmetrical approaches to administrative decentralization. When Latin American countries decided to devolve responsibilities for expenditures like education, health care, or infrastructure, they rarely excluded individual subnational units de jure from receiving these responsibilities (regardless of concerns about de facto unevenness in capacity), just as they rarely gave individual units special responsibilities not enjoyed by other units at their same level. Even as asymmetrical reforms have become more prominent elsewhere, often in response to geographically concentrated ethnic groups (Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2016), the Latin American approach (outside of Bolivia, where the 2009 Constitution enables the formation of indigenous municipalities) has been decidedly symmetrical, which probably aids in the use of the subnational comparative method by presumably making it safer to assume that subnational units have been endowed with similar prerogatives by the national government.

Second is the significant extent of fiscal decentralization in the region (Escobar Lemmon Reference Escobar-Lemmon2001; Fukasaku and Hausmann Reference Fukasaku and Hausmann1999; Wibbels Reference Wibbels2005). In general, national governments transferred not just policy responsibilities but the resources necessary to make these responsibilities actionable and therefore meaningful (Garman et al. Reference Garman, Haggard and Willis2001). Fiscal decentralization thus increased the possibility of comparing whether and how units responded differently to their new formal responsibilities. Furthermore, to increase the fiscal resources under the control of subnational governments, those who designed decentralization relied heavily on automatic revenue sharing via transfers from the national government and largely eschewed the devolution of new tax bases to subnational units.Footnote 5 Given pronounced unevenness in the ability of subnational governments to collect their own taxes in most countries, this design feature further increased the applicability of the subnational comparative method by making it possible to compare how different subnational units used resources delivered from above.

Third, despite important differences in sequencing decisions (Falleti Reference Falleti2010), administrative and fiscal decentralization often came coupled with political decentralization. The introduction of elections to select subnational chief executives has made it more plausible to treat the units these individuals govern as substantially more independent than they were when their leaders were appointed by national governments, whether democratic or authoritarian. Meanwhile, other developments probably reinforced the ability of newly elected subnational governors and mayors to act much more independently than they had in the past. For example, the concomitant collapse of party systems that many Latin American countries experienced removed some of the partisan controls through which national party leaders formerly kept in line the subnational party leaders who governed in subnational spaces (Cyr Reference Cyr2017; Willis et al. Reference Willis, Garman and Haggard1999). At the same time, persistent deficiencies in the capacity of the central state, especially in the form of national governments that were unable to enforce legislative and policy controls across the national territory, can be thought of as a permissive condition that probably enhanced the de facto political autonomy of subnational governments.

Vertical Challenge 1: Accommodating the “National” in the Subnational Comparative Method

The first vertical challenge facing scholars who use the subnational comparative method has to do with how they should account for the role of the national government at the theoretical level. As the literature on decentralization has shown, the national government does not just go away after decentralization is adopted, but instead typically continues to alternately engage, favor, and punish different subnational governments in ways that can be difficult to measure and document.

The continued but uneven salience of the national government in most policy realms creates an important challenge for the subnational comparative method. Here I distinguish between three main responses to this challenge by scholars; while most omit national causes of subnational variation, others have taken a very different approach by exclusively positing national causes of subnational variation.Footnote 6 Still others have articulated hybrid theories that blend attention to national and subnational causes of subnational outcomes. Each approach to theory building has distinctive strengths, but the hybrid approach holds special appeal for those policy fields in which decentralization has resulted in shared authority rather than its neat reassignment from top to bottom. In other words, the content of the policy field itself will hold clues for the form that theory building should take. According to the articles in this special issue, it may be more difficult for subnational units to defend their status as autonomous units and make policy choices that deviate from what the national government prefers in some policy areas, like property rights (SánchezTalanquer this issue), than in others, like health care (Otero-Bahamón this issue).

Among work that theoretically brackets the national government, the most common approach to case selection has been to use the Most Similar Systems Design (MSSD) rather than the Most Different Systems Design (MDSD). This preference is possibly due to the very structure of the subnational comparative method, which encourages us to see subnational units as similar rather than different, and despite the fact that it can be productive to explore why subnational units that are different from one another in most relevant respects nevertheless share a common outcome of interest.Footnote 7

A pioneering MSSD study is Snyder’s book on reregulation in four coffee-producing Mexican states (2001a), where gubernatorial decisions are explained as the result of their interactions with state-specific societal groups (in both their oligarchic and grassroots forms), and where governors are conceptualized as equally upwardly accountable and equally bound by the dual imperative of securing votes for the governing party (PRI) and maintaining stability (2001a, 27). Snyder illuminates an intriguing paradox, whereby an avowedly neoliberal president (Carlos Salinas) sanctioned illiberal behaviors by governors in order to produce PRI majorities. As Snyder goes on to note, Salinas “did not merely tolerate subnational deviations from the neoliberal line, he selectively promoted them” (2001a, 28, italics mine), and promotion by Salinas seems especially important in the case of one of Snyder’s four states (Oaxaca), whose governor enjoyed a close personal relationship with the president. But if Salinas encouraged reregulation in some states more than others, perhaps in response to variation across states in the nature or depth of the electoral threat facing the PRI, this uneven behavior on the part of the president could have shaped variation in cross-state regulatory outcomes in ways that are not specified in the theory.

Another classic example of work that holds the national government constant theoretically, although by combining MSSD with MDSD, is Alfred Montero’s Reference Montero2001 study of industrial policymaking. Montero argues that subnational governments will successfully implement industrial policy only when delegative government and horizontal embeddedness are present at the subnational level; both conditions are necessary and cumulatively sufficient. Minas Gerais and Rio de Janeiro are compared as similar secondary industrial states in Brazil that produced different outcomes (industrial policy only in the former case), and the positive outcome in Minas is then compared with a similarly positive outcome in a very different case in another country, that of Asturias in Spain.

Like Snyder’s, Montero’s theoretical framework stands out for the richness of the combined attention it pays to state and societal actors at the subnational level, and also for the theoretical absence of the national government. Brasília is absent from the theory, but it does tend to shape outcomes in various ways in the cases, as in the argument that “intergovernmental conflicts with other states and the federal government encouraged Minas’s leaders to construct an elaborate economic technocracy designed to attract new investments to the state” (2001, 26). Not only does the center appear to play a motivating role as a trigger of what happened in Minas, but the vertical circulation of elites between Minas and the national government during military rule (65) could have shaped the logics of horizontal embeddedness among Minas elites in the 1990s that Montero emphasizes.

To be fair, Montero does begin to theorize the role of the national government when he discusses how decentralized cases like Brazil and Spain, where the national government is hypothesized to play no causal role, might differ from more centralized cases like Mexico, where democratization in the 1990s (a national-level event) explains the emergence of new industrial policy practices in the Mexican states (2001, 12–15).

A powerful, more recent example of the decision to treat the role of the national government as a theoretical constant can be seen in the study of policy diffusion across Brazilian municipalities by Natasha Borges Sugiyama (Reference Sugiyama2013), who explicitly (and laudably) clarifies that she wants to go beyond “a simple tale of vertical diffusion” (2013, 126).Footnote 8 For Sugiyama, municipal policy diffusion takes place in a fashion rather isolated from national-level dynamics; municipal officials are very aware of what’s going on in other municipalities, but national officials are mostly absent from their decisions about whether to emulate those municipalities or not. Perhaps because of her focus on larger cities, Sugiyama’s interviews with mayors suggest that federal transfers were too insignificant to shape municipal decisionmaking.Footnote 9 One could argue, however, that the role of the federal government in municipal policy adoption is undertheorized here, important in the empirical material but missing from the theory, which exclusively emphasizes municipal-level variables. The data show that Brazil experienced a dramatic increase in the adoption of its Programa Saúde da Familia (PSF) after 1998, which is the year that the federal government introduced greater funding to incentivize its adoption by municipalities (2013, 70, 73).

While the temptation to hold constant the role of the national government, and to privilege only subnational causes of subnational variation, is understandable, this treatment of the national government can also be questioned.Footnote 10 Decentralization helped to create “potentially autonomous policy jurisdictions” in Latin America, but not unambiguously. This is because, although the design elements mentioned above, such as administrative symmetry, automatic revenue sharing, and political decentralization, all helped justify the use of the subnational comparative method, other features of decentralization and its aftermath have worked in the opposite direction. For example, in the rapid push to decentralize, often the relevant legislation either failed to articulate a precise division of labor between levels of government in different policy fields, or specifically opted for a system of shared rather than exclusive competencies.

It is also the case that the same national politicians who signed off on the decentralization of authority then often doubled down on deconcentration, deploying (and funding) agents of the national government to compete with decentralized authorities in (some) subnational territories. Not only did these duplicative efforts undermine the rationality of public budgeting, but they also served to puncture “autonomous policy jurisdictions” at the subnational level. In other cases, national officials, or what Jessica Rich (Reference Rich2013) calls “activist bureaucrats,” have sought to mobilize civil society actors against subnational politicians in ways that may advance national reform objectives, but by eroding the autonomy of subnational governments.

Furthermore, decentralization often triggered attempts to recentralize authority and resources, sometimes across the board and sometimes in ways that targeted particular subnational units, but all of which have made the bracketing of the national government in “post-decentralization” Latin America a lot riskier as a research strategy (Dickovick and Eaton Reference Dickovick and Eaton2013; González Reference González2016). This is especially so in the context of judicial systems that are often too weak to punish national governments for unconstitutional breaches of subnational autonomy.

If the dominant approach has been to exclude the national government from causal explanations of subnational variation, some more recent work using the subnational comparative method has moved far in the opposite direction, not only theorizing the role of national-level variables but emphasizing them exclusively over more purely subnational variables. Consider the explanations of subnational regime type by Carlos Gervasoni (Reference Gervasoni2010, 2018) and André Borges (Reference Borges2016). In Gervasoni’s work, Argentina’s national-level revenue-sharing system, which the federal government uses to automatically transfer the taxes it collects to provincial governments, is the sole causal variable that explains the uneven democratic performance of provinces. The greater the share of these transfers in total provincial revenues, the lower the level of democracy in the province. While the causal mechanisms Gervasoni considers play out within the provinces, the theory itself only has space for national institutional rules and cannot explain subnational regime change in the absence of any change in the content of the rules.Footnote 11

With respect to the same dependent variable, Borges looks to the party system rather than to the fiscal system (and to Brazil rather than Argentina) but develops an argument that similarly emphasizes national-level dynamics. Borges explains subnational democratization as a response to the nationalization of the party system: states with more nationalized legislative elections are more democratic, and “national party dynamics have gradually undermined subnational incumbents’ power over state institutions” (Reference Borges2016, 171).

Between the extremes of these two options, which have led scholars either to control entirely for national causes or to endow them exclusively with explanatory power, scholars have successfully deployed a third, “hybrid” option. In this line of work, scholars develop theoretical explanations for subnational-level variation that identify both subnational-level and national-level causal variables. Hybrid theories are appealing because they avoid the dangers of overstating the autonomy of subnational units, which exclusively subnational theories tend to do, while also avoiding the opposite tendency, in exclusively national theories, to underestimate the potential autonomy of these units.

Two representative examples of hybrid approaches, representing the earlier wave of work on economic policy and the more recent wave of work on regime type, are those of Erik Wibbels (Reference Wibbels2005) and Agustina Giraudy (Reference Giraudy2015). Wibbels, for example, explains variation in the policy preferences of subnational officials (and the associated implications for national-level macroeconomic performance) as a function of four independent variables: one that is subnational (the level of political competition within the province), two that are national (the rules that govern the federal fiscal system and the representation of provinces in national legislatures), and one that straddles the two levels (the relationship between national and provincial leaders within parties). Turning to the persistence of subnational undemocratic regimes, Giraudy’s explanation similarly combines national-level variables like the president’s fiscal and partisan powers with subnational variables, such as the degree to which governors can depend on elite cohesion or mass support within their provinces.

A third representative example, though at the municipal rather than provincial level, is Donna Lee Van Cott’s Reference Van Cott2008 study of indigenous politics in ten small and medium-sized cities in Bolivia and Ecuador. After theorizing about the impact of Ecuador’s more flexible approach to decentralization (a national-level feature), she then attributes reform outcomes to municipal-level differences.

Considering these three scholars, one can identify a critical trade-off here, in the sense that hybrid theoretical frameworks blending causal attention to national and subnational variables are likely to come at the cost of greater complexity (and less parsimony), to the extent that this is seen as a negative.

Recent research shows that theoretically hybrid approaches can also be used to accommodate the vertical relationship between intermediate-level units and the local governments within those units.Footnote 12 Scholars who are chiefly interested in using the subnational comparative method to compare intermediate-level governments have begun to factor in and theorize the various roles played by municipal governments, as seen in the “authoritarian province, plural cities” dynamic (Fenwick Reference Fenwick2016; Gibson Reference Gibson2013, 2015; Behrend and Whitehead 2016; Niedzwiecki Reference Niedzwiecki2018; Souza 2016).Footnote 13 Likewise, scholars whose main research site is municipal governments have worked in the opposite direction by considering more deeply how municipalities are affected “from above” by intermediate-level governments (Grindle Reference Grindle2007; Alves and Gibson Reference Alves and Gibson2019). Consider, for example, Veronica Herrera’s Reference Herrera2017 study of water politics in Mexican municipalities, which attributes the marketization of water policy to industrial elites and middle-class constituencies. While her focus is on municipal-level causes and outcomes, Herrera simultaneously factors in the role that intermediate-level governments played, which she conceptualizes as the level of institutional support for municipal water reform that state governments can provide or fail to provide (Reference Herrera2017, 82).

By paying theoretical attention to more than one level of government (i.e., national and provincial, or provincial and municipal), hybrid theories offer a more realistic way of theorizing the complexity inherent in multilevel political systems, along with the multiple threats to autonomy that subnational governments face.

Vertical Challenge 2: Relationships Between Subnational Governments and Transnational Actors

According to the discussion so far, scholars have paid a lot of attention to the vertical relationships between subnational and national governments, and they have differed greatly in the decisions they have made about how to treat the national government theoretically in research that seeks to explain subnational variation. But another important vertical challenge also affects the use of the subnational comparative method, though this second challenge has received far less explicit scholarly attention. Whether subnational units function as potentially autonomous policy spaces is also shaped by the vertical relationships that increasingly tie them to international or transnational actors, who can be conceptualized as operating above the national level of government.

Even though we live in an era of globalization, comparativists who study intergovernmental relations in Latin America have tended not to pay much attention to supranational dynamics. Perhaps this is because struggles between national, provincial, and municipal governments over which level gets to do what and with whose money often seem to play out as quintessentially domestic conflicts, safely protected by sovereignty norms and securely under the control of ministries of the interior and of finance. For whatever reason, and to the best of my knowledge, scholars who have used the subnational comparative method have mostly overlooked the question of how external actors might shape the autonomy of subnational jurisdictions (even though these actors did receive a fair amount of attention in the literature on why decentralization happened). But attention to these external actors is likely to be critical in order to defend the claim that subnational units represent “potentially autonomous policy jurisdictions.”

Even without much literature to draw on, it is nonetheless possible to argue that the subnational transnational challenge differs from the subnational national challenge in two key respects, which scholars who use the subnational comparative method should keep in mind. The first is that it refers to a much more heterogeneous set of actors, including bilateral aid organizations, international financial institutions, globalized NGOs, transnational advocacy networks, multinational corporations, and even individuals, in the form of transnational migrants. A second difference, related to this remarkable breadth in the identity of the external actors who might impact the degree of subnational autonomy, is the reality that this impact might be positive or negative, in the sense that disparate goals and preferences might drive these external actors either to favor or to oppose autonomy for subnational units. This variety stands in stark contrast to the first vertical challenge, in which it can more safely be assumed (and documented) that the national government mostly tries to restrict subnational autonomy, even when it has passed decentralizing legislation.

Beyond taking stock of the variety of external actors and the multiplicity of their preferences, scholars can usefully distinguish between two different kinds of relevant scenarios (“bottom up” vs. “top down”) that increasingly link subnational governments with extranational actors and forces. According to the first scenario, the leaders of subnational governments themselves have reached out and sought to activate possible allies or defenders outside their countries when their autonomy is threatened by political opponents at the national level. We know from the sizable literature on the “Europe of the Regions” (Hooghe and Marks Reference Hooghe and Marks2001) that the effect of the creation and strengthening of European Union institutions has been to bolster the position of subnational regions in regard to national governments; by the year 2000, regions had already staffed and funded more than 150 independent offices in Brussels. In Latin America, regional integration has afforded nothing of the kind to subnational governments, even though these governments have indeed been able to defend provincial interests indirectly through the lobbying of national governments over Mercosur’s Common External Tariff (Pezzola Reference Pezzola2018).

Drawing on the concept of “paradiplomacy,” scholars have begun to examine how subnational governments in Latin America directly engage in international relations, not as a way to defend their autonomy but instead as a means to encourage foreign investment in their regions or to promote regional exports (Maira 2010). For example, Jorge Schiavon (Reference Schiavon2006) finds that opposition-governed states in Mexico are not more likely to engage in international relations, and that wealth and proximity to the United States are, instead, the factors that explain their pursuit of paradiplomatic efforts abroad.

Rather than the Europe of the Regions or paradiplomacy, the deployment of external strategies by subnational governments in Latin America more closely recalls Keck and Sikkink’s “boomerang effect,” through which domestic actors partner with external allies to target national governments (Reference Keck and Sikkink1998). Subnational governments should probably be added to the long list of actors enumerated by Keck and Sikkink who may deploy the boomerang, including local social movements, foundations, and the media.

One can identify several salient examples of subnational elected officials appealing to international bodies to defend subnational autonomy in the face of what they frame as illegal intrusions by the national government. Consider the case of Gustavo Petro, a former guerrilla leader of the M-19 in Colombia, who was elected to a four-year term as mayor of Bogotá (2012–15). After pursuing a series of left-leaning reforms in service provision, including a controversial attempt to reverse the privatization of trash collection, Petro was suspended from office by Inspector General Alejandro Ordoñez (Eaton Reference Eaton2020). Arguing that his suspension was a breach of Bogotá’s 1993 autonomy statute, Petro took his case to the Inter-American Court of Human Rights, which ordered President Juan Manuel Santos to reinstate the mayor (who was able to finish his term). Another example of a mayor who pursued a similar course of action but to lesser effect was Caracas mayor Antonio Ledezma, who responded to what he considered illegal recentralizing actions by President Hugo Chávez by lobbying the Spanish Parliament and by engaging in a hunger strike on the steps of the Caracas headquarters of the Organization of American States.

If the first scenario involves subnational officials reaching out to extranational allies in the struggle to defend their autonomy from the center, the second, “topdown” scenario unfolds in the opposite direction, as external actors reach down into subnational spaces. The broader point is that when decentralization expanded subnational autonomy, some transnational actors benefited from this change while others were threatened by it. Thus, for the sake of simplicity, one could argue that external influence can take one of two forms: attempts by transnational actors to restrict the autonomy of subnational governments or to defend that autonomy.

Perhaps the most visible actors to take stock of are the same bodies—bilateral aid agencies and multilateral financial institutions—that promoted the very decision to decentralize to begin with and that, subsequent to decentralization, stayed on the scene, in the form of capacity-building programs for newly empowered subnational governments (Dickovick Reference Dickovick2014). Even here, however, one finds evidence of rival views about the merits of subnational autonomy. Although most of the prominent bilateral development organizations have continued to promote development, other actors, in the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund, voiced early support for recentralizing measures in Argentina, Brazil, and Colombia (Dillinger and Webb Reference Dillinger and Webb1999; Restrepo Reference Restrepo2015).

In addition to governmental organizations, scholars should canvas three other kinds of external actors—multinational corporations, transnational NGOs, and migrant associations—to determine whether and how their behavior might shape subnational autonomy. With respect to corporations, examples of how foreign companies can benefit from the autonomy of subnational units can be found in the literature on the fiscal wars that took place between Brazilian states in the 1990s (Rodríguez-Pose and Arbix Reference Rodríguez-Pose and Arbix2001). Governors’ ability to offer exemptions from the important tax on goods and services led to bidding wars, which probably resulted in less tax liability for automobile manufacturers.

But foreign companies may also have cause to fear subnational autonomy and to use the kinds of rules that were introduced by Chapter 11 of NAFTA, which expanded protections for foreign investors in relation to subnational governments. A case in point is the municipality of Guadalcázar, which sought to deny a land use permit to a U.S. company, Metalclad, which wanted to open a toxic waste facility in the municipality (Warner and Gerbasi Reference Warner and Gerbasi2004). In 1996, Metalclad secured a $16.7 million award from the court of international arbitration established by NAFTA to compensate for the negative financial impact of losing the permit. Warner and Gerbasi propose that cases like this have a galvanizing effect on foreign investors seeking to question almost any form of regulation by subnational officials, and a chilling effect on municipalities seeking to make use of their legal authority.Footnote 14

Like bilateral aid agencies, transnational NGOs are especially relevant as external actors that—for their own issueor policy-specific reasons—may bring to bear important assistance in the construction of subnational capacity, a critical asset, the absence of which may doom efforts by subnational governments to act autonomously. Peru is a case in point. External environmental NGOs, in partnership with national NGOs, have sponsored capacity-building activities in regional governments to enable them to effectively make use of formally devolved zoning and planning authorities (zonificación ecológica económica y ordenamiento territorial, or ZEE-OT). As Maria-Therese Gustafsson (Reference Gustafsson2016) shows in her comparison of outcomes across regions, some regional governments have been far more able than others to carry out and conclude this technical exercise in ways that impose limits on where mining can take place within the subnational territory—in direct opposition to the wishes of the national government in Lima.

In this sense, the case of resource extraction in Peru showcases a particularly interesting dynamic, whereby different kinds of transnational actors (e.g., environmental NGOs and transnational corporations) seek to bolster rival sides in the struggles that have unfolded between subnational and national governments over the scope of autonomy for the former. Transnational mining companies question the autonomy of local authorities to regulate extraction at the same time that transnational NGOs are engaged in capacity-building exercises to render their autonomy meaningful.

In addition, a vibrant literature on the impact of remittances on country-of-origin dynamics points to the importance of a relatively new kind of “external” actor: migrants and the hometown associations (HTAs) they have built to facilitate and coordinate the flow of resources back home. To date, scholars have largely asked about the impact of remittances on democracy (Meseguer and Aparicio Reference Meseguer and Aparicio2012) and development (Duquette-Rury Reference Duquette-Rury2014) rather than about how they may impact the potential autonomy of subnational units. The design of Mexico’s 3×1 program, whereby funds from municipal, state, and federal governments triple the amount of money sent by HTAs, points toward at least two possible rival hypotheses. On the one hand, remittances may increase the fiscal capacity of municipalities that otherwise simply do not enjoy sufficient resources to make use of their formal policy prerogatives. On the other hand, the required participation of higher levels of government, in the form of matching transfers, can link municipal governments to the preferences of those higher levels even more tightly, with negative consequences for their potential autonomy.

The Horizontal Challenge: Relationships Between Subnational Governments at the Same Level

In addition to challenges from actors who occupy higher rungs in vertical hierarchies, the potential autonomy of subnational jurisdictions can also be challenged horizontally. Here, too, we see significant variation in the literature in terms of how, and how much, scholars have emphasized these relationships between subnational units at the same level of government (intermediate or local).

Much of the literature tends not to focus on these relationships at all, or to privilege the vertical relationship with the national government to the exclusion of horizontal dynamics.Footnote 15 In the literature on subnational regime type, for example, interactions between provinces are unimportant for both Gervasoni and Giraudy, who both see struggles between democratic presidents and autocratic governors playing out in an almost exclusively bilateral fashion. Horizontal dynamics likewise seem to be theoretically irrelevant in the major policy-centered works discussed above, including research on regulatory, industrial, and fiscal policymaking by intermediate-level governments (Snyder Reference Snyder2001a; Montero Reference Montero2001; Wibbels Reference Wibbels2005), as well as work that explains municipal-level variation (Grindle Reference Grindle2007; Moncada Reference Moncada2016; Wampler Reference Wampler2007). Though horizontal dynamics have not featured prominently in research that deploys the subnational comparative method, I argue that relationships between subnational units can have the effect of either increasing or decreasing the autonomy of those units, and that they can be conceptualized as taking three main forms: cooperation, conflict, and contagion and diffusion.

Cooperation has received the most attention. Most generally stated, the asymmetrical power dynamics that characterize the relationship between the national government and even the most powerful of subnational units put the onus on cooperative behaviors between subnational governments to defend their collective prerogatives (Stoner-Weiss Reference Stoner-Weiss1997). In her sequential theory of decentralization, for example, Tulia Falleti considers the creation of subnational associations of provinces or municipalities as a “strong indication of the increased levels of autonomy of subnational officials” (Reference Falleti2010, 64). For Colombia, Falleti shows how the Colombian Federation of Municipalities lobbied successfully for additional fiscal resources and for the recognition of municipal autonomy in the 1991 Constitution (134).

Laura Flamand (Reference Flamand2009) and Alberto Pacheco (Reference Pacheco, Puga and Luna2008) likewise emphasize collective efforts on the part of Mexican governors, who succeeded in creating a powerful new lobbying organization (the National Conference of Governors) under the Vicente Fox administration. Cooperative horizontal relationships are also critical for Edward Gibson, who argues that the subnational hegemonic parties that sustain subnational authoritarianism and enforce “boundary control” are linked horizontally to a network of copartisan (and not necessarily authoritarian) provincial parties. As he notes in the Argentine case, “Peronist hegemonic provincial parties were … minority members of a chain of provincial parties dominated by parties from large competitive provincial party systems, [and] benefited from the reflected legitimacy of their national coalition” (2013, 156; see also Cruz Reference OlmedaOlmeda forthcoming).

I also argue (Eaton 2017) that lateral coalitions between subnational officials can serve to defend the autonomy of the units they govern, and that ideologically deviant governors and mayors are likely to lose if they confront the center on a bilateral basis. Whereas a coalition of governors in eastern Bolivia coordinated actions (e.g., work stoppages, strikes) against the national government, which was forced to accept those departments’ more liberal policies, regional presidents in Peru who tried to design policies at odds with national preferences were isolated from one another, unable to find common cause, and ultimately powerless to resist Lima’s divide-and-conquer tactics.

At first blush, conflict between subnational governments would appear to hinder the ability to act collectively in defense of their autonomy as subnational units. However, scholars have identified pathways through which conflictual rather than cooperative relations between subnational units can lead to greater autonomy. For example, Soifer (Reference Soifer2016) argues that while conflict between subnational regions in Ecuador and Colombia had the effect of depressing overall levels of public goods provisioning by the central state, it reinforced, at the same time, the ability of regional elites to pursue their distinct preferences in regard to public goods in a more autonomous fashion. In Brazil, conflict between the wealthier states of the South and the poorer states of the North and Northeast led to an institutional solution in the guise of the 1988 Constitution, which enhanced the autonomy of both through different accommodations: the devolution of important tax bases like the VAT, which pleased the former; and generous provisions for the automatic sharing of revenues from centrally collected taxes, which assuaged the concerns of the latter (Souza Reference Souza1997).

Moreover, while subnational units may clash or coalesce in quite visible patterns, they also influence each other horizontally through subtler and more indirect mechanisms of contagion and diffusion. While most of the diffusion literature focuses on the nation-state as the unit of analysis, recent scholarship suggests that subnational units are powerfully shaped by what happens in neighboring jurisdictions. Consider Sugiyama’s research on social policy diffusion across Brazilian municipalities. She found that social networks and shared professional norms between health bureaucrats in different municipalities facilitated the spread of common policy approaches. Thus, while her first causal variable (the ideological orientation of the mayor) is one that can be thought of as mostly independent from other districts, the second variable taps into the importance of professional relationships that transcend jurisdictional boundaries. Municipal bureaucrats network in professional forums, the effect of which is, de facto, to limit the autonomy of municipalities as separate policy jurisdictions. In other policy-centered research, Catalina Smulovitz (Reference Smulovitz2015) has shown that factors like the strength of civil society explain cross-provincial variation in the adoption of domestic violence laws, but that more protective laws have diffused across provinces over time.Footnote 16

Conclusions

For more than a decade now, political scientists working in Latin America have increasingly engaged the subnational comparative method to study a great number of empirical phenomena. While decentralization is the governance trend that facilitated this dynamic by creating “potentially autonomous subnational jurisdictions,” the viability of the method requires careful attention to this very status of jurisdictions as potential spaces of autonomy, and as units that can be considered sufficiently separate to generate independent observations. Even after political, fiscal, and administrative decentralization, the autonomy of subnational governments to make their own choices is impinged on by a number of relationships with actors above, below, and alongside those units. These vertical and horizontal relationships with actors outside subnational units continue to powerfully—and unevenly— shape what happens within them, which creates a number of challenges for the subnational comparative method.

As demonstrated in this article, scholars using the subnational comparative method in recent years have dealt with these challenges in a number of different ways. Just as scholars have adopted the method to study a remarkably broad set of substantive issues (e.g., democracy, security, social welfare, development), so have they differed in how explicitly they have sought to accommodate these challenges. In analyzing responses to the first vertical challenge, I have argued that it is possible to group work into three main categories: work that largely brackets the role of the national government, work that locates causal impacts entirely at the national level, and hybrid approaches that theorize how both subnationaland national-level variables shape the outcomes of interest. While any of these approaches might be appropriate, depending on the context of the policy or institutional issues under study, my analysis points to an important indirect relationship: the less the potential autonomy of subnational units, the greater the need to theorize rather than bracket national-level causes of subnational variation. More generally, the key point is that explicit attention should always be paid to the potential ways the national government can (de facto and de jure) undermine the autonomy of subnational units, even after decentralization.

Despite the perhaps well-founded tendency to think of the national government as the chief menace when it comes to the autonomy of subnational units, decentralization has also had the effect of increasing the influence within those units of other actors from other jurisdictions, both horizontally and vertically defined. With respect to the newly complicated horizontal relationships that have emerged between subnational governments in the aftermath of decentralization, and drawing on the limited research that has begun to theorize these horizontal ties, I have argued that these relationships might have a positive or negative impact on autonomy and that they come in three main forms: cooperation, conflict, and contagion or diffusion. Ironically, while horizontal cooperation between subnational governments may help them to defend their autonomy in relation to the center, greater contact of this sort is likely to facilitate diffusion in ways that challenge our ability to consider units as independent observations.

Even less than this horizontal challenge, the second vertical challenge conceptualized in this article is by far the one that has received the least attention from scholars who use the subnational comparative method. One the one hand, there may be good reason to privilege the other “domestic” challenges arising from the complex relationships between national and subnational governments. The politically sensitive nature of territorial struggles within countries may discourage the involvement of external actors who have a stake in the outcome of these struggles but whose incursions may trigger hostile responses from national governments bent on defending sovereignty. On the other hand, the sovereignty of Latin American countries is routinely breached in all sorts of ways, and it would be naive to suppose that external actors like transnational corporations and globalized NGOs are not directly and indirectly participating in these high-stakes territorial struggles. Drawing on very little literature here, I argue that scholars who deploy the subnational comparative method should take stock of a wider range of external actors, ask who initiates the formation of subnational-transnational alliances (subnational officials “from below” or transnational actors “from above”), and determine whether the involvement of external actors is meant either to bolster or to erode the autonomy of subnational governments.

Footnotes

Conflict of interest: author declares none.

I am grateful to Carla Alberti and Juan Pablo Luna for the invitation to present the original version of this paper at a workshop on subnational politics in Latin America that took place at the Catholic University in Santiago in November 2017, as well as to the participants in that workshop for their constructive feedback: Diego Díaz-Rioseco, Tomáš Došek, Lucas González, Maritza Paredes, Fernando Rosenblatt, Richard Snyder, Hillel Soifer, Abbey Steele, and Jorge Vargas. I would also like to thank the four anonymous reviewers of this paper and the LAPS editorial team for their very helpful comments.

1. For the argument that it was not decentralization but rather a growing methodological pluralism that opened the door to subnational comparisons, see Suárez-Cao et al. Reference Suárez-Cao, Batlle and Wills-Otero2017.

2. For other work that uses this method to study violence, see Brinks 2003; Snyder and Durán-Martínez Reference Snyder and Durán-Martínez2009; Trejo and Ley Reference Trejo and Ley2018.

3. Here my focus is on what happens within subnational units, considering only work that treats subnational outcomes as the dependent variable. For a broader approach that includes how subnational units influence national outcomes, see Giraudy et al. Reference Giraudy, Moncada and Snyder2019a.

4. This approach is distinct from work that compares a subnational region in one country with a subnational region in another country (Burbano de Lara Reference Felipe2014; Eaton Reference Eaton2011; Goldfrank and Schrank 2009; Heller Reference Heller2001).

5. In the 1980s and 1990s, decentralizing reforms produced major increases in the relative size and absolute levels of automatic fiscal transfers in Argentina (1988), Bolivia (1994), Ecuador (1997), Brazil (1988), Colombia (1986 and 1991), Mexico (1991 and 2000), and Venezuela (1993). Even in countries that eschewed automatic sharing for more discretionary approaches (e.g., Chile, Peru, Uruguay), decentralizing measures also significantly increased subnational fiscal resources.

6. Giraudy et al. (Reference Giraudy, Moncada and Snyder2019a) call these “top-down theories” (i.e., theories in which “causes at higher scales have effects at lower scales”).

7. For an example of the potential theoretical payoff of MDSD, see Wampler Reference Wampler2007.

8. See Baiocchi Reference Baiocchi2005; Moncada Reference Moncada2016; and Pribble Reference Pribble2015 for other examples of work that applies the subnational comparative method to the municipal level and that largely brackets the role of the national government.

9. Rather than use MSSD or MDSD to select a small-n set of individual cases, Sugiyama focuses on the universe of cities with more than one hundred thousand inhabitants. For other work that analyzes data on the universe of local or intermediate-level jurisdictions in a country, see Arce Reference Arce2014; Díaz-Cayeros Reference Díaz-Cayeros2006; Gervasoni 2018; Giraudy Reference Giraudy2015; Niedzwiecki Reference Niedzwiecki2018; Weitz-Shapiro Reference Weitz-Shapiro2014.

10. In this kind of work, in the words of Otero-Bahamón (this issue), “The national arena practically disappears because, according to the methodological parlance of the subnational method, it is constant across subnational units and does not explain variations.”

11. Fenwick’s important study of social policy outcomes (Reference Fenwick2016) likewise emphasizes national causes (e.g., party system and electoral rules) to explain why CCTs in Argentina experienced greater territorial unevenness than in Brazil. See also Trejo and Ley 2019 for an argument that explains subnational patterns of violence as the result of national-level decisions, including militarization and federal protections for local politicians from the governing party.

12. Relations between subnational levels of government can be critical in unitary and not just federal systems, especially those that have moved recently to strengthen intermediate-level governments (Došek Reference Došek and Tuesta2016; Encinas et al. Reference Encinas2016; Pino Reference Pino2017).

13. Díaz-Rioseco (Reference Díaz-Rioseco2016) shows that the impact of natural resource wealth on political competition at the provincial level depends on whether provinces automatically share revenues with municipalities.

14. See Post Reference Post2014 for the argument that Argentine provincial governments generally enjoyed less autonomy relative to domestic firms than they did relative to MNCs in terms of the (re)negotiation of infrastructure contracts.

15. See Harbers and Ingram 2019 for a critique of this tendency.

16. For recent work that applies diffusion theories to subnational regime type and democratization in Mexico and Russia, see Lucardi Reference Lucardi2016; Lankina et. al. Reference Lankina, Libman and Obydenkova2016. Behrend and Whitehead (2016, 308) also consider contagion one of three major pathways toward subnational democratization.

References

Abrucio, Fernando. 1998. Os barões da federação. São Paulo: Universidade de São Paulo.Google Scholar
Alberti, Carla. 2017. Communities of Smugglers: Controlling Transnational Violence in the Andes. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, August 31–September 3.Google Scholar
Alves, Jorge. 2015. (Un?)Healthy Politics: The Political Determinants of Subnational Health Systems in Brazil. Latin American Politics and Society 57, 4: 119–42.Google Scholar
Alves, Jorge, and Gibson, Christopher. 2019. States and Capitals of Health: Multilevel Health Governance in Brazil, Latin American Politics and Society 61, 1: 5477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arce, Moisés. 2014. Resource Extraction and Protest in Peru. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arretche, Marta. 2000. Estado federativo e políticas sociais. São Paulo: Revan. Avritzer, Leonardo. 2002. A participação em São Paulo. São Paulo: Editora Unesp.Google Scholar
Baiocchi, Gianpaolo. 2005. Militants and Citizens: The Politics of Participatory Democracy in Porto Alegre. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Basset, Yann, Juan Carlos Guerrero, Cerón, Karen, and Pérez, Andrés. 2017. La política local en Riosucio (Chocó): ¿un caso de autoritarismo subnacional? Colombia Internacional 91: 4583.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Batlle, Margarita. 2009. Distribución territorial de los apoyos territoriales en América Latina. Análisis Político 67: 320.Google Scholar
Behrend, Jacqueline, and Whitehead, Laurence, eds. 2016. Illiberal Practices: Territorial Variance Within Large Federal Democracies. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Binder, Alberto. 2004. Policías y ladrones: la inseguridad en cuestión. Buenos Aires: Capital Intelectual.Google Scholar
Bonvecchi, Alejandro. 2008. Políticas sociales subnacionales en países federales: Argentina en perspectiva comparada. Desarrollo Económico 48, 190–91: 307–39.Google Scholar
Borges, André. 2016. Subnational Hybrid Regimes and Democratization in Brazil: Why Party Nationalization Matters. In Behrend and Whitehead 2016. 162–96.Google Scholar
Felipe, Burbano de Lara. 2014. La revuelta de las periferias: movimientos regionals y autonomías políticas en Bolivia y Ecuador. Quito: FLACSO Ecuador.Google Scholar
Olmeda, Cruz, Juan. Forthcoming. La unión hace la fuerza: la política de la (in)acción colectiva de los gobernadores en Argentina, Brasil y México. Mexico City: El Colégio de Mexico.Google Scholar
Cyr, Jennifer. 2017. The Fates of Political Parties: Institutional Crisis, Continuity, and Change in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Díaz-Cayeros, Alberto. 2006. Federalism, Fiscal Authority, and Centralization in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Díaz-Rioseco, Diego. 2016. Blessing and Curse: Oil and Subnational Politics in the Argentine Provinces. Comparative Political Studies 49, 14: 1930–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickovick, Tyler. 2014. Foreign Aid and Decentralization: Limitations on Impact in Autonomy and Responsiveness. Public Administration and Development 34, 3: 194206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickovick, Tyler, and Eaton, Kent. 2013. Latin America’s Resurgent Centre: National Government Strategies After Decentralisation. Journal of Development Studies 49, 11: 1453–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dillinger, William, and Webb, Steven. 1999. Fiscal Management in Federal Democracies. Policy Research Working Paper 2121. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Došek, Tomáš. 2016. Los caminos divergentes a nivel subnacional de los sistemas de partidos más institucionalizados. In Partidos políticos y elecciones: representación política en América Latina, ed. Tuesta, Fernando. Lima: Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú. 231–52.Google Scholar
Duquette-Rury, Lauren. 2014. Collective Remittances and Transnational Coproduction: The 3x1 Program for Migrants and Household Access to Public Goods in Mexico. Studies in Comparative International Development 49: 112–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durán-Martínez, Angélica. 2018. The Politics of Drug Violence: Criminals, Cops, and Politicians in Colombia and Mexico. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eaton, Kent. 2011. Conservative Autonomy Movements. Comparative Politics 43, 3: 291310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, Kent. 2017. Territory and Ideology in Latin America: Policy Conflicts Between National and Subnational Governments. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, Kent. 2020. Bogotá’s Left Turn: Counter-neoliberalization in Colombia. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 44, 1: 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Encinas, Daniel, et. al. 2016. Democracia y territorio en países unitarios: una agenda de investigación pendiente. Lima: Jurado Nacional de Elecciones.Google Scholar
Escobar-Lemmon, Maria. 2001. Fiscal Decentralization and Federalism in Latin America. Publius 31, 4: 2341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faguet, Jean-Paul. 2013. Decentralization and Popular Democracy: Governance from Below in Bolivia. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Falleti, Tulia. 2010. Decentralization and Subnational Politics in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenwick, Tracy. 2016. Avoiding Governors: Federalism, Democracy, and Poverty Alleviation in Brazil and Argentina. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Flamand, Laura. 2009. La Conferencia Nacional de Gobernadores en México. ¿Cómo resolver un problema de acción colectiva? In Nuevas tendencias en la teoría y en la práctica de la administración y de las políticas públicas, ed. María del Carmen Pardo. Mexico City: El Colegio de México. 1–35.Google Scholar
Flom, Hernán. 2016. Police, Politicians, and the Regulation of Drug Trafficking in Latin America. Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Fohrig, Alberto, and Pomares, Julia. 2004. La reforma policial desde las teorías del cambio institucional. In Participación ciudadana y reformas a la policía en América del Sur, ed. Frühling, Hugo and Candina, Azun. Santiago: Centro de Estudios para el Desarrollo. 230–58.Google Scholar
Freidenberg, Flavia, and Suárez-Cao, Julieta, eds. 2014. Territorio y poder: nuevos actores y competencia política en los sistemas de partidos multinivel en América Latina. Salamanca: Ediciones Universidad de Salamanca.Google Scholar
Fukasaku, Kiichiro, and Hausmann, Ricardo. 1999. Democracia, descentralización y déficit presupuestarios en América Latina. Washington, DC: Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo.Google Scholar
Garman, Christopher, Haggard, Stephen, and Willis, Eliza. 2001. Fiscal Decentralization: A Political Theory with Latin American Cases. World Politics 53, 2: 205–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gervasoni, Carlos. 2010. A Rentier Theory of Subnational Regimes: Fiscal Federalism, Democracy, and Authoritarianism in the Argentine Provinces. World Politics 62, 2: 302–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
———. 2018. Subnational Democracy and Fiscal Federalism Rents: Argentina’s Provincial Hybrid Regimes in Comparative Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gibson, Edward L. 2013. Boundary Control: Subnational Authoritarianism in Federal Democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Giraudy, Agustina. 2015. Democrats and Autocrats: Pathways of Subnational Undemocratic Regime Continuity Within Democratic Countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giraudy, Agustina, and Pribble, Jennifer. 2019. Rethinking Measures of Democracy and Welfare State Universalism. Regional and Federal Studies 29, 2: 135–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giraudy, Agustina, Moncada, Eduardo, and Snyder, Richard. 2019a. Subnational Research in Comparative Politics: Substantive, Theoretical, and Methodological Contributions. In Giraudy et al. 2019b. 3–54.Google Scholar
Giraudy, Agustina, Moncada, Eduardo, and Snyder, Richard, eds. 2019b. Inside Countries: Subnational Research in Comparative Politics. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldfrank, Benjamin. 2011. Deepening Local Democracy: Participation, Decentralization, and the Left. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Goldfrank, Benjamin, and Schrank, Andrew. 2009. Municipal Neoliberalism and Municipal Socialism. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 33, 2: 443–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
González, Lucas. 2016. Presidents, Governors, and the Politics of Distribution in Federal Democracies: Primus Contra Pares in Argentina and Brazil. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grindle, Merillee. 2007. Going Local: Decentralization, Democratization, and the Promise of Good Governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gustafsson, Maria-Therese. 2016. Private Conflict Regulation and the Influence of Peasant Communities over Natural Resources. Latin American Research Review 51, 2: 86106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbers, Imke. 2015. Taxation and the Unequal Reach of the State: Mapping State Capacity in Ecuador. Governance 28, 3: 373–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbers, Imke, and Matthew, C. Ingram. 2019. Politics in Space: Methodological Considerations for Taking Space Seriously in Subnational Research. In Giraudy et al. 2019b. 57–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heller, Patrick. 2001. Moving the State: The Politics of Democratic Decentralization in Kerala, South Africa, and Porto Alegre. Politics & Society 29, 1: 131–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrera, Verónica. 2017. Water and Politics: Clentelism and Reform in Mexico. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooghe, Liesbet, and Marks, Gary. 2001. Multi-level Governance and European Integration. New York: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
Hooghe, Liesbet, and Marks, Gary. 2016. Community, Scale, and Regional Governance: A Postfunctionalist Theory of Governance. Volume 2. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keck, Margaret, and Sikkink, Kathryn. 1998. Activists Beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Lankina, Tomila, Libman, Alexander, and Obydenkova, Anastassia. 2016. Authoritarian and Democratic Diffusion in Post-Communist Regions. Comparative Political Studies 49, 12: 15991629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lima, Luciana, and Viana, Ana. 2011. Descentralização, regionalização e instâncias intergovernmentais no Sistema Único da Saúde. In Regionalização e relações federativas na política de saúde no Brasil, ed. Viana. Rio de Janeiro: Contra Capa. 1–30.Google Scholar
Lucardi, Adrián. 2016. Building Support from Below? Subnational Elections, Diffusion Effects, and the Growth of the Opposition in Mexico. Comparative Political Studies 49, 14: 1855–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luna, Juan Pablo. 2014. Segmented Representation: Political Party Strategies in Unequal Democracies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maira, Luís, ed. 2010. La política internacional subnacional en América Latina. Buenos Aires: Libros del Zorzal.Google Scholar
McNulty, Stephanie. 2011. Voice and Vote: Decentralization and Participation in Post-Fujimori Peru. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Meseguer, Covadonga, and Aparicio, Francisco. 2012. Migration and Distributive Politics: The Political Economy of Mexico’s 3x1 Program. Latin American Politics and Society 54, 4: 147–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moncada, Eduardo. 2016. Cities, Business, and the Politics of Urban Violence in Latin America. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Montambeault, Francoise. 2011. Overcoming Clientelism Through Local Participatory Institutions in Mexico. Latin American Politics and Society 53, 1: 91124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montero, Alfred. 2001. Shifting States in Global Markets: Subnational Industrial Policy in Contemporary Brazil and Spain. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Montero, Alfred. 2012. A Reversal of Political Fortune: The Transitional Dynamics of Conservative Rule in the Brazilian Northeast. Latin American Politics and Society 54, 1: 136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niedzwiecki, Sara. 2018. Uneven Social Policies: The Politics of Subnational Variation in Latin America. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otero-Bahamón, Silvia. 2019. Subnational Inequality in Latin America: Empirical and Theoretical Implications of Moving Beyond Interpersonal Inequality. Studies in Comparative International Development 54, 2: 185209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pacheco, Alberto. 2008. El desempeño de la Conferencia Nacional de Gobernadores: una instancia de concertación institucional en vías de institucionalización. In Estudios sobre desempeño asociativo, ed. Puga, Cristina and Luna, Matilde. Mexico City: Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México. 80–98.Google Scholar
Pezzola, Anthony. 2018. The Deep Roots of Protectionism in the Southern Cone: Constituent Interests and Mercosur’s Common External Tariff. Latin American Politics and Society 60, 4: 6992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pino, Juan Federico. 2017. Entre democracias y autoritarismos: una mirada crítica al studio de la democracia en Colombia y Latinoamérica. Colombia Internacional 91: 215–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ponce, Aldo, and McClintock, Cynthia. 2014. The Explosive Combination of Inefficient Local Bureaucracies and Mining Production: Evidence from Localized Societal Protests in Peru. Latin American Politics and Society 56, 3: 118–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Post, Alison. 2014. Foreign and Domestic Investment in Argentina: The Politics of Privatized Infrastructure. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pribble, Jennifer. 2015. The Politics of Building Municipal Effectiveness in Chile. Latin American Politics and Society 57, 3: 100–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Restrepo, Darío. 2015. Procesos de descentralización en Bolivia y Colombia. Bogotá: Universidad Nacional de Colombia.Google Scholar
Rich, Jessica. 2013. Grassroots Bureaucracy: Intergovernmental Relations and Popular Mobilization in Brazil’s AIDS Policy Sector. Latin American Politics and Society 55, 2: 125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodríguez-Pose, Andrés, and Arbix, Glauco. 2001. Strategies of Waste: Bidding Wars in the Brazilian Automobile Sector. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 25, 1: 134–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, Giovanni. 1970. Concept Misinformation in Comparative Politics. American Political Science Review 64, 4: 1033–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schiavon, Jorge. 2006. La proyección internacional de las entidades federativas: México ante el mundo. Mexico City: Instituto Matías Romero.Google Scholar
Smulovitz, Catalina. 2015. Legal Inequaltiy and Federalism: Domestic Violence Laws in the Argentine Provinces. Latin American Politics and Society 57, 3: 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Richard. 2001a. Politics After Neoliberalism: Reregulation in Mexico. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Richard. 2001b. Scaling Down: The Subnational Comparative Method. Studies in Comparative International Development 36, 1: 93110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Richard, and Durán-Martínez, Angélica. 2009. Does Illegality Breed Violence? Drug Trafficking and State-sponsored Protection Rackets. Crime, Law and Social Change 52, 3: 253–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soifer, Hillel. 2016. Regionalism, Ethnic Diversity, and Variation in Public Good Provision by National States. Comparative Political Studies 49, 10: 1341–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Souza, Celina. 1997. Constitutional Engineering in Brazil. New York: St. Martin’s Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Souza, Celina. 2016. The Rise and Fall of Illiberal Politics in the Brazilian State of Bahia. In Behrend and Whitehead 2016. 197–229.Google Scholar
Stoner-Weiss, Kathryn. 1997. Local Heroes: The Political Economy of Russian Regional Governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Suárez-Cao, Julieta, Batlle, Margarita, and Wills-Otero, Laura. 2017. El auge de los estudios sobre la política subnacional latinoamericana. Colombia Internacional 90: 1534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugiyama, Natasha Borges. 2013. Diffusion of Good Government: Social Sector Reforms in Brazil. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Szwarcberg, Mariela. 2013. Building a Following: Local Candidates’ Political Careers and Clientelism in Argentine Municipalities. Latin American Politics and Society 55, 3: 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tendler, Judith. 1997. Good Government in the Tropics. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Trejo, Guillermo, and Ley, Sandra. 2018. Why Did Drug Cartels Go to War in Mexico? Subnational Party Alternation, the Breakdown of Criminal Protection, and the Onset of Large-Scale Violence. Comparative Political Studies 51, 7: 900937.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trejo, Guillermo, and Ley, Sandra. 2019. Multilevel Partisan Conflict and Drug Violence in Mexico: When Do Criminal Organizations Attack Subnational Elected Officials? In Giraudy et al. 2019b. 181–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Cott, Donna Lee. 2008. Radical Democracy in the Andes. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veliz, Claudio. 1980. The Centralist Tradition of Latin America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wampler, Brian. 2007. Participatory Budgeting in Brazil: Contestation, Cooperation, Accountability. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Ward, Peter, Rodríguez, Victoria, and Mendoza, Enrique, eds. 1999. New Federalism and State Government in Mexico: Bringing the States Back In. Austin: University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
Warner, Mildred, and Gerbasi, Jennifer. 2004. Rescaling and Reforming the State Under NAFTA: Implications for Subnational Authority. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 28, 4: 858–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weitz-Shapiro, Rebecca. 2014. Curbing Clientelism in Argentina. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wibbels, Erik. 2005. Federalism and the Market: Intergovernmental Conflict and Economic Reform in the Developing World. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willis, Eliza, Garman, Christopher, and Haggard, Stephan. 1999. Decentralization in Latin America. Latin American Research Review 34, 1: 756.Google Scholar