Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-f46jp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T06:11:39.429Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Exchange Systems in Late Postclassic Mesoamerica: Comparing Open and Restricted Markets at Tlaxcallan, Mexico, and Santa Rita Corozal, Belize

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 December 2020

Marc D. Marino
Affiliation:
Department of Anthropology, 330 Old Main, University of Arkansas, Fayetteville, AR72704, USA
Lane F. Fargher*
Affiliation:
Departamento de Ecologı́a Humana, Centro de Investigación y de Estudios Avanzados del IPN–Unidad Mérida, km 6 antigua carretera a Progreso, Col. Cordemex, Mérida, YUC, C.P. 97310, Mexico
Nathan J. Meissner
Affiliation:
Centre College, Crounse Hall 470, 600 West Walnut St., Danville, KY40422, USA
Lucas R. Martindale Johnson
Affiliation:
Far Western Archaeological Research Group Inc., 1180 Center Point Drive, Suite 100, Henderson, NE89074, USA
Richard E. Blanton
Affiliation:
Department of Anthropology, Purdue University, Stone Hall, 700 W. State Street, W. Lafayette, IN47907, USA
Verenice Y. Heredia Espinoza
Affiliation:
Centro de Estudios Arqueológicos, El Colegio de Michoacán, A.C., Cerro de Nahuatzen, 85, Frac. Jardines del Cerro Grande, 59379, La Piedad, Michoacán, Mexico
*
(frederick.fargher@cinvestav.mx, corresponding author)
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In premodern economic systems where the social embedding of exchange provided actors with the ability to control or monopolize trade, including the goods that enter and leave a marketplace, “restricted markets” formed. These markets produced external revenues that could be used to achieve political goals. Conversely, commercialized systems required investment in public goods that incentivize the development of market cooperation and “open markets,” where buyers and sellers from across social sectors and diverse communities could engage in exchange as economic equals within marketplaces. In this article, we compare market development at the Late Postclassic sites of Chetumal, Belize, and Tlaxcallan, Mexico. We identified a restricted market at Chetumal, using the distribution of exotic goods, particularly militarily and ritually charged obsidian projectile points; in contrast, an open market was built at Tlaxcallan. Collective action theory provides a useful framework to understand these differences in market development. We argue that Tlaxcaltecan political architects adopted more collective strategies, in which open markets figured, to encourage cooperation among an ethnically diverse population.

En los sistemas económicos premodernos donde la inserción social del intercambio proporcionó a los agentes la capacidad de controlar o monopolizar el intercambio, incluyendo los bienes que entraron y salieron del mercado, se desarrollaron “mercados restringidos”. Estos mercados produjeron ingresos externos que fueron utilizados para alcanzar metas políticas. En contraste, los sistemas comercializados requirieron de la inversión en bienes públicos que incentivaron el desarrollo de la cooperación mercantil y “mercados abiertos”, donde los vendedores y compradores de diversas comunidades y sectores sociales participaron en el intercambio como pares dentro del mercado. En este artículo, se compara el desarrollo del mercado en dos sitios del posclásico tardío: Chetumal en Belice y Tlaxcallan en el altiplano central de México. En Chetumal, se identificó un mercado restringido, basado en la distribución de bienes exóticos, particularmente puntas de obsidiana que simbolizan una carga militar y ritual; mientras que en Tlaxcallan se construyó un mercado abierto. La teoría de acción colectiva proporciona el marco para entender las diferencias en el desarrollo de estos dos mercados. Se plantea que los arquitectos políticos tlaxcaltecas implementaron estrategias más colectivas, en las cuales los mercados abiertos fueron importantes para enfatizar la cooperación de una población étnicamente diversa.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2020 by the Society for American Archaeology

In urban landscapes, market exchange has typically been viewed as a key provisioning strategy for households and institutions (Berdan Reference Berdan1975; Blanton Reference Blanton, Berdan, Blanton, Boone, Hodge, Smith and Umberger1996; Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2008; Fargher Reference Fargher2009; Hirth Reference Hirth1998). In this regard, the organization of market economies at differing scales of interaction, such as at the household or state level, is stimulated by different motivations, with some initiated by political interests and others that originate in household decision making concerning agricultural and crafting strategies (e.g., intensification, extensification, specialization, and diversification; Fargher Reference Fargher2009; Hirth Reference Hirth and Hirth2010; Morrison Reference Morrison1994).

The large complex market systems of Late Postclassic period (LPC) Mesoamerica (AD 1350–1521) served both political and domestic needs, requiring market builders to overcome difficulties associated with self-interested, rationally motivated individuals, including local merchants, long-distance traders, elites, and commoners who supplied and consumed the goods and services offered in marketplaces (Blanton Reference Blanton, Hirth and Pillsbury2013). How did these various actors effectively navigate potentially harmful behaviors associated with rational motivations and competitive behavior involving the control and exchange of private goods? Collective action theory provides an important framework to explore this question (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2008, Reference Blanton and Fargher2009).

Accordingly, we compare access to projectile points, a formal tool that often figures in discussions of wealth and status variation (Andrieu Reference Andrieu2013; Carballo Reference Carballo2007; Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992; Hirth Reference Hirth, Santley and Hirth1993:136; Meissner Reference Meissner2017, Reference Meissner, Rice and Rice2018; Scholes and Roys Reference Scholes and Roys1948:344), from two LPC sites with differing governing structures. Tlaxcallan, located in Central Mexico, used a highly collective governing strategy directed toward incorporating commoners and elites in a unified political structure in which power was shared (Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010; Fargher, Blanton, et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton, Heredia Espinoza, Millhauser, Xiuhtecutli and Overholtzer2011; Fargher, Heredia, and Blanton Reference Fargher, Blanton, Heredia Espinoza, Millhauser, Xiuhtecutli and Overholtzer2011). In contrast, the coastal Maya capital of Chetumal (Figure 1), in northern Belize, used a comparatively exclusionary strategy (Chase Reference Chase1982, Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992; Masson Reference Masson2000; Oland Reference Oland and Walker2016).

Figure 1. Contemporary Santa Rita Corozal, the capital city of the Chetumal polity, with sites and sectors mentioned in text (after Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase1988:Figures 41–52).

Both polities featured different political-economic strategies, and differences in the provisioning of these two cities are tested archaeologically. Collective strategies are expected to provide “open” markets that enhance market access across social sectors while providing tax revenues to the state (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016:69–98; Carballo et al. Reference Carballo, Roscoe and Feinman2014). “Restricted markets” occur where political institutions do not develop regulations that protect buyers and sellers, and the production and distribution of commodities, especially exotic and foreign goods, are manipulated by elites as part of exclusionary political strategies, resulting in a multitiered market system (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016:69–98; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016).

Collective Action Theory

Collective action theory focuses on revenues (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2008; Lindkvisk Reference Lindkvist and Samson1991) and how they are allocated by governments, institutions, or elites. Internal revenues are drawn from free taxpayers, such as harvest taxes, market taxes, or corvée labor (Levi Reference Levi1988). When governments rely on joint production of these revenues, more requirements will be in place to distribute those revenues back to the state's constituents (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2008). Where taxpayers (farmers, merchants, artisans) have direct control over their production and the government relies on them for revenue, they will have more say in the use of public funds (Carballo and Feinman Reference Carballo and Feinman2016). Specifically, revenues are reallocated to the populace in the form of public goods, which include infrastructure and services available to all members of society (Acheson Reference Acheson2011; Ostrom Reference Ostrom and Sabatier1999:497). Examples include roads, fortifications, plazas, ceremonies, markets, security, and redistribution (Carballo et al. Reference Carballo, Roscoe and Feinman2014).

If principals fail to provide such goods and services by (1) diverting public revenues to personal consumption, (2) failing to provide fair and just taxation procedures, (3) failing to control free riders, (4) or failing to distribute public goods across the state's geographic territory, then their constituents may withhold tax payments (Levi Reference Levi1988) and interrupt revenue flows into state coffers, impeding the ability of principals to achieve their political goals. Collective action theory predicts that principals, relying on internal revenues, will strive to ensure fair taxation and a wide distribution of public goods, control free riders, and monitor political agents (Fargher and Blanton Reference Fargher and Blanton2007).

Personalization of Power

External revenues are drawn from sources other than free taxpayers, including conquest, taxes on imperial territories, slaves, monopolization of international exchange, mines, and patrimonial estates (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2008). Because external revenues are not drawn from a state's constituents, principals face fewer constraints on revenue allocation; they tend to use revenues for self-interested aggrandizement and to recruit clients needed to achieve their political goals. These co-optive strategies focus on the construction of elite-centered identities and patron-client networks through gifting, feasting, and bride exchanges (Blanton et al. Reference Blanton, Feinman, Kowalewski and Peregrine1996).

Such finance strategies focus on private goods that can easily be restricted. Examples of finance strategies are control of craft production, exchange networks, ritual, and ideology, as well as the manipulation/control of market locations, items entering markets, or the sale of select goods (sumptuary items). In terms of collective action, restricted or attached production of items intended for limited distribution, as well as control of exchange networks, generates income from sources other than taxpayers, which frees principals from limits imposed on them by taxpayers (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2009:137; Carballo and Feinman Reference Carballo and Feinman2016:292).

Open and Restricted Markets

Markets are often necessary for household and political provisioning, but they require costly investments from all societal members (joint production). An organized system of infrastructure (roads, plazas, platforms, stalls, judicial structures) is necessary to support functional marketplaces (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016:69–98). If taxes drawn from the broader population are used to help produce a system from which the state and its constituents benefit, then a collective scenario occurs. Markets serve an important public service if transactions are fair and effectively regulated, allowing for the impartial settlement of grievances; protection of market participants from theft, misrepresentation, and price manipulations; and the provision of security outside of markets (Blanton Reference Blanton, Hirth and Pillsbury2013). Open markets flourish under such conditions; low-status individuals will have confidence in fair market conditions and will likely travel to markets outside their local communities. These collective behaviors require trust among governing officials, merchants, producers, and consumers. They also require a market mentality where social and class distinctions do not factor into transactions (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016), producing what Carrasco (Reference Carrasco and Ortiz1983:69) called “status-free acts of exchange.” In an open market, supply and demand determine distribution and price (Braswell Reference Braswell, Garraty and Stark2010:130–132; Carrasco Reference Carrasco and Ortiz1983:74), and staples, exotics, and nonlocal goods are exchanged as commodities among individuals from diverse social, ethnic, and economic statuses, because market cooperation is provided by institutional strategies (LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016:172).

Open markets fail when governing officials engage in price-fixing, influence exchange networks, or establish status-based segregation of market locations (Blanton Reference Blanton, Hirth and Pillsbury2013; Carrasco Reference Carrasco and Ortiz1983:74; Smith Reference Smith and Smith1976). Restricted markets emerge where elites use bottlenecks to manipulate supply and demand, prices, and access (DeMarrais and Earle Reference DeMarrais and Earle2017; Earle and Spriggs Reference Earle and Spriggs2015). This scenario is consistent with Smith's (Reference Smith and Smith1976:314) partially commercialized or controlled market system (Braswell Reference Braswell, Garraty and Stark2010:132). Restricted markets result in stratification of exchanges among different social or political groups, where foreign or exotic goods exchanges are monopolized by high-status individuals who are linked through social networks to governing principals (LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016:172). Accordingly, the exchange of ordinary goods is limited to local markets where trust is based on familiarity and reputation because institutional strategies promoting cooperation are absent.

Mesoamerican Markets

Commercialization intensified throughout Mesoamerica during the LPC (Blanton Reference Blanton, Berdan, Blanton, Boone, Hodge, Smith and Umberger1996; Chase and Rice Reference Chase and Rice1985; Hassig Reference Hassig1985; Hirth Reference Hirth1998, Reference Hirth2016; Masson and Freidel Reference Masson and Freidel2012; Sabloff and Rathje Reference Sabloff and Rathje1975; Smith and Berdan Reference Smith and Berdan2000). Marketplaces and commercialized exchanges (see Feinman and Garraty Reference Feinman and Garraty2010) are reported from many Yucatecan cities (Piña Chan Reference Piña Chan, Lee and Navarette1978) and have been identified archaeologically at Mayapan (Masson and Freidel Reference Masson and Freidel2012), Tulum (Oland Reference Oland and Walker2016), Cozumel (Freidel and Sabloff Reference Freidel and Sabloff1984), Caye Coco (Masson Reference Masson2000), Laguna de On (Masson Reference Masson, Masson and Freidel2002), and Chetumal (Marino et al. Reference Marino, Martindale Johnson, Meissner and Walker2016; Seidita et al. Reference Seidita, Chase and Chase2018). The dual role of the market system for the LPC Maya was to provision households with subsistence goods and to promote the long-distance exchange of items by governing officials to affirm status distinctions (Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992; Hirth Reference Hirth, Chase and Chase1992; McAnany Reference McAnany, Hirth and Pillsbury2013; McKillop Reference McKillop2005).

In LPC Central Mexico, marketplaces served as a node at the intersection of the domestic and political economy (Berdan Reference Berdan1975; Blanton Reference Blanton, Berdan, Blanton, Boone, Hodge, Smith and Umberger1996; Charlton Reference Charlton, Hodge and Smith1994; Nichols et al. Reference Nichols, Brumfiel, Neff, Hodge and Charlton2002). Ethnohistorically, the largest market described in Central Mexico was at Tenochtitlan-Tlatelolco; it hosted as many as 60,000 visitors on principal market days (Cortés Reference Cortés2007 [1522]). Such markets played key roles in provisioning governing institutions with taxes (Berdan Reference Berdan1975; Berdan and Anawalt Reference Berdan and Anawalt1997; Blanton Reference Blanton, Berdan, Blanton, Boone, Hodge, Smith and Umberger1996; Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016:69–98; Carrasco Reference Carrasco and Ortiz1983). Principals benefited from market integration and commercialization, especially the flow of goods into urban settlements destined to provision households. The revenue received from Aztec market taxes was likely substantial, nearly 20% on all commercial transactions (Blanton Reference Blanton, Berdan, Blanton, Boone, Hodge, Smith and Umberger1996; Berdan Reference Berdan1975; Brumfiel Reference Brumfiel, Brumfiel and Earle1987). Archaeological and ethnohistoric research suggest that market systems were highly organized (Blanton et al. Reference Blanton, Fargher, Heredia-Espinoza and Blanton2005; Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase2014; Dahlin et al. 2007; Hirth Reference Hirth2016; Levine Reference Levine2011; Masson and Freidel Reference Masson and Freidel2012; Smith Reference Smith, Garraty and Stark2010; Stark and Ossa Reference Stark, Ossa, Garraty and Stark2010).

Importantly, the Aztecs developed institutions to increase market participation and cooperation among producers and consumers. They monitored local marketplaces to curb the degree to which local authorities (e.g., tlatoque) could manipulate them (Brumfiel Reference Brumfiel, Brumfiel and Earle1987:103; Hassig Reference Hassig1985:113). Market transactions were restricted to official marketplaces, where participants could be provided with security and taxed (Blanton Reference Blanton, Hirth and Pillsbury2013; Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2008; Carrasco Reference Carrasco and Ortiz1983:76; Smith Reference Smith2014). This was accomplished by ceding market management and conflict adjudication to the pochteca, a paragovernmental merchant guild (Blanton Reference Blanton, Berdan, Blanton, Boone, Hodge, Smith and Umberger1996). In the Classic period Maya Lowlands, similar systems were also noted. Market nodes were placed in strategic locations to promote administered exchange by central elites (Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase2004:122; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016). These actions directly benefited central elites through revenue collection, while reducing the income and influence of local and regional elites.

Archaeological Identification of Markets

The archaeological identification of market exchange uses distributional, configurational, spatial, and contextual approaches (Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase2014; Hirth Reference Hirth1998). The latter three are based on an evaluation of population estimates, ethnohistoric accounts, and placement of architecture. We take the distributional approach as our point of departure because it uses artifact densities to identify market exchange. It is based on the premise that market exchange provides equal access to goods. Therefore, artifact densities found in households should reflect the equitable distribution of commodities (Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase2014; Garraty Reference Garraty2009; Hirth Reference Hirth1998). However, we modify the distributional approach using the concepts of open and restricted markets.

Open Markets

Archaeological correlates for open market exchange are visible in qualitatively homogeneous consumption and production of materials across households (see Table 1), meaning that no categorical differences will be visible in artifact densities or source materials across households (Braswell Reference Braswell, Garraty and Stark2010:132; Hirth Reference Hirth1998:455; Johnson Reference Johnson2016; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016:158). In open markets, commoners feel safe engaging in exchange at broader social scales, including visiting nonlocal markets or buying from nonlocal merchants. This limits the degree to which elites can monopolize high-order exchanges. All households will have access to nonlocal goods, including ordinary goods and luxuries, circulating at the regional and macroregional scales. For example, in the LPC southern Basin of Mexico, Brumfiel (Reference Brumfiel, Claessen and van de Velde1991) found both rural and urban low-status households were well supplied with green obsidian, and those rural households directly administered by the Aztec state had slightly better access to green obsidian than those governed by local rulers. Open markets may also be identified by production and consumption practices that are exceptionally varied, meaning households are producing surplus on such a large and varied scale that one can infer market exchange based on the presence of an economic system too complex and diverse to be organized by a central institution (Feinman and Nicholas Reference Feinman, Nicholas, Manzanilla and Hirth2011; Levine Reference Levine2011; Levine et al. Reference Levine, Fargher, Cecil and Ford2015; Masson and Freidel Reference Masson and Freidel2012).

Table 1. Types of Exchanges Based on Embedded (“Non-Market”) or Commercial Relationships (Market Systems).

Restricted Markets

Archaeological correlates for restricted forms of exchange are visible in equal consumption of only locally produced ordinary goods across all households, with consumption of higher-quality, higher-cost, or politically charged items (exotics and nonlocal goods) limited to high-status households (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016). Thus, a stratified market develops, featuring local marketplaces with limited institutional development for cooperation, so that trust is based on familiarity and reputation, and exchanges are limited to locally produced and consumed goods. Elites monopolize exchanges at larger geographical scales, involving more exotic goods. Social embedding is key to these exchanges. Thus, elite social relationships are reinforced by the restricted exchange of prestige goods. Archaeologically, restricted markets will be materialized in the form of relatively homogeneous distributions of low-value goods over limited geographic scales (e.g., within sites or over a comparatively small territory); whereas, special, costly, nonlocal goods and raw materials should be distributed over very large areas (>100 km2) but restricted to higher-status households.

Reciprocal Exchange

Reciprocity involves low-volume, heterogeneous exchange spheres representative of households with unique social networks and procurement strategies (Braswell Reference Braswell, Garraty and Stark2010:132; Hirth Reference Hirth1998:455; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016:158). Surplus production of goods would be reduced in this system in comparison with market exchange or to centralized redistribution, since consumption is geared only toward one's own social network. Given that each household would have had its own procurement system, distinct patchworks of goods and raw materials would be visible archaeologically.

However, for low-status households, reciprocity in the absence of larger integrating mechanisms (e.g., open markets) will only provide access to local goods; whereas, high-status political agents will be connected to regional and macroregional networks. Principals and other high-level political actors develop social ties well beyond local borders, manipulating these relationships to control access to and the sale of regional or world-systems goods within settlements and their immediate hinterlands (Blanton Reference Blanton, Hirth and Pillsbury2013; Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016). In this manner, social embedding through reciprocal exchange is key to the development of restricted markets.

The merging of reciprocal exchange with restricted markets will result in three exchange spheres operating simultaneously. At the highest level, rare or singular items will be concentrated among rulers and the highest governing officials (e.g., polychrome vessels with their owners named; gold, silver, and tumbaga composite jewelry; rock-crystal chalices; and eccentrics of various materials that promote rulership, etc.). Next, a specific set of commodities, usually nonlocal goods and craft items that are difficult to produce (such as jade beads and other forms, elaborate polychromes, plumbate, codices, metal axe-monies, copper and bronze jewelry, and artifacts made using nonlocal materials, etc.) will flow through restricted markets and be most frequent in high-status contexts and taper off as these goods move down the social hierarchy. Finally, locally produced commodities made with comparatively simple techniques (e.g., low-fired monochrome jars and comales, staple foods, chipped tools made on local materials, wooden artifacts, and textiles made from locally produced fibers) will be widely distributed.

Redistribution

Redistribution will be visible in the households of governing officials having the greatest quantity of items, with comparatively fewer goods possessed by low-status households, thereby reflecting the established social hierarchy (Braswell Reference Braswell, Garraty and Stark2010:132; Hirth Reference Hirth1998:455; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016:158). The basic goods possessed by everyone would be the same, meaning access is not stratified. In this model, tools and local raw materials would be homogeneous, yet elites would have the same tools made on the same local materials, in larger volumes, with production limited to a few locations either within or near settlements. Braswell (Reference Braswell, Smith and Berdan2003:157) identifies redistribution at Postclassic Otumba, Mexico. Workshops at the site were primarily exploiting local gray Otumba obsidian, which was predominantly consumed by rural households. In contrast, urban high-status households were consuming predominantly green Pachuca obsidian alongside some local gray, and several lower-status urban households were consuming a mixture of both Otumba and Pachuca obsidian. This scenario is interpreted as controlled distribution (redistribution; Braswell Reference Braswell, Smith and Berdan2003).

Exploring Market Restriction in Postclassic Mesoamerica

Based on the preceding, we hypothesize that in Postclassic Mesoamerica, collective political-economic strategies will be associated with open markets and that exclusionary strategies will be associated with either reciprocity or a combination of restricted markets and reciprocal exchange. We selected two well-studied cities from the LPC—Chetumal and Tlaxcalla—to test these hypotheses. Both cities have extensive ethnohistoric documentation, household excavations, and well-classified assemblages.

Chetumal

Political Strategies

The political organization of Maya polities varied at the time of conquest (Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992, Reference Chase1982; Fox et. al 1996; Landa Reference Landa and Pagden1975 [1566]; Masson Reference Masson2000; Oland Reference Oland and Walker2016; Roys Reference Roys1957). The Chetumal polity was organized as a kuchkabal, under the rulership of a halach winik named Nachan Kan (Chamberlain Reference Chamberlain1948:100; Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase1988; Landa Reference Landa and Pagden1975 [1566]:33; Masson Reference Masson2000; Oland Reference Oland and Walker2016). As a kuchkabal, the Chetumal polity was organized into at least three settlement tiers. The highest tier was the noh kah (“capital”) at Chetumal, recognized archaeologically as the site of Santa Rita Corozal (SRC), Belize (Chase Reference Chase1982; Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase1988). Below it were batabil; they were governed by batabob (Oland Reference Oland and Walker2016:109), which controlled small local settlements or neighborhoods called cah (pl. cahob; e.g., Chase Reference Chase, Robertson and Fields1985:223–233).

Artifact patterns, ethnohistoric accounts, and architecture suggest that the halach winik sought to integrate and control lower-level elites through domination of ideological resources (e.g., ritual knowledge, including possible esoteric/exotic languages based on specialized linguistic puns; see Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase2008; Roys Reference Roys1933; Stross Reference Stross1983). Batabob in turn manipulated ritual at the local level to bring low-status households under their authority. As a result, Postclassic elites were unable to build larger networks, because personal power placed structural limits on the geographical scale of integration (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2008), resulting in a high degree of fragmentation and power sharing among a limited number of individuals or lineages (Fox et al. Reference Fox, Cook and Demarest1996). Thus, although Nachan Kan was the halach winik, Chase and Chase (Reference Chase and Chase1988) suggest that decision-making authority rotated among elite households or lineages.

Consequently, religious shrines, ritual caches, and paired censers used in calendric rites, as well as other religious paraphernalia, such as stingray spines, were reported to be restricted to high-status houses or nonresidential structures (Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992:128). For example, caches with iconographic links to Itzamna were placed in altars and high-status residences in accordance with Wayeb rites for the Kan years in the northeastern part of the site (Chase Reference Chase, Robertson and Fields1985:228; Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase2008). In the southwestern part, similar caching is associated with rites involving the Muluc years, warriors, the war dance, and the sun god (Kinich Ajaw). Taube (Reference Taube, Vail and Hernández2010:161) notes a severed head of Kinich Ajaw portrayed with dancing warriors on the west wall mural at Chetumal. Rites associated with the Ix and Cauac years have been tentatively identified in other sectors (Chase Reference Chase, Robertson and Fields1985:233). Importantly, projectile points appear in the plumed serpent imagery on murals, such as in Mound 1 (Taube Reference Taube, Vail and Hernández2010:177). Quetzalcoatl and Itzamna, who were often associated with royalty in Postclassic iconography (Taube Reference Taube1989; Reference Taube, Vail and Hernández2010), appear in mural iconography, signaling an emphasis on royal lineages, personalized rulership, hereditary power, and social hierarchies (Olko Reference Olko2014; Ringle et al. Reference Ringle, Negrón and Bey1998; cf., Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010).

Hence, we might expect to see specialized ritual artifacts materialize this pattern by being concentrated in the largest and wealthiest houses (those of the halach winik and high-level batabob), with smaller amounts appearing in middle-level households and few or none appearing in low-status houses. This pattern might be manifested in the form of a monopoly on raw materials, on specialized artifact forms, or on both (see Peregrine Reference Peregrine1991).

Economics and Exchange at Chetumal

Substantial evidence exists at Chetumal for high-value trade items in high-status contexts, including conspicuously crafted items like metals, textiles, ceramics, polished lapidaries, and eccentrics (Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase1988). These items served as important symbols and as social capital, irrespective of material source (see Appadurai Reference Appadurai and Appadurai1986). Specifically, evidence indicates that obsidian and fine chalcedony projectile points are concentrated in high-status houses and contexts, suggesting that some may have served as potent ritual items (Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992). Lithic materials were overwhelmingly comprised of cherts and chalcedonies, with obsidian recovered in lower frequencies. The most common siliceous tools were bifaces and small, triangular side-notched projectile points (<3 cm in length, <1 g in weight) with either short or elongated blades (Meissner Reference Meissner2014). Such points, common throughout LPC Mesoamerica, are associated with bow-and-arrow technology (Andresen Reference Andresen, Hester and Hammond1976; Meissner and Rice Reference Meissner and Rice2015; Shafer and Hester Reference Shafer and Hester1988; Thomas Reference Thomas1978). Obsidian tools were primarily prismatic blades; despite these patterns, obsidian points seem to have played a special political-economic role (Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992:123).

The Corozal Postclassic Project excavated 43 structures, of which 35 yielded architecture or occupation surfaces dated to the LPC (Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992:123). High-status households were previously identified by their association with items referencing ritual performance, including effigy censers, paired incense burners, and other ritual paraphernalia relating to bloodletting, such as stingray spines (Chase Reference Chase, Robertson and Fields1985). They also contained complex multiroom architecture and more diverse artifact assemblages (Chase Reference Chase, Robertson and Fields1985), a pattern noted in elite households throughout Mesoamerica (Hirth Reference Hirth, Santley and Hirth1993). Households of other-status lacked these ritual items and multiroom constructions (Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992).

Of these 35 contexts, 286 projectile points were found in 30 structures, including 14 high-status houses, 10 other-status (either low or middle) households, and six ritual contexts (Meissner Reference Meissner2014; Seidita Reference Seidita2015). Yet only 33 points were made of obsidian (Figure 2), a nonlocal resource originating from Highland Guatemala (500 km away) and Highland Mexico (1,000 km away; Seidita Reference Seidita2015; Seidita et al. Reference Seidita, Chase and Chase2018). The other 253 points were made from locally available resources, including northern Belize chert associated with Colha (Shafer and Hester Reference Shafer and Hester1988), chalcedony likely from Caye Coco and the Laguna de On area (Masson Reference Masson2000), and other lower-quality cherts from unknown sources located throughout northern Belize (Oland Reference Oland1999, Reference Oland2013).

Figure 2. Typical obsidian side-notched points from Santa Rita Corozal (Meissner Reference Meissner2014:345, Figure 6.20).

Following Hirth's (Reference Hirth1998) distributional approach for identifying markets (see also Braswell Reference Braswell, Garraty and Stark2010; Garraty Reference Garraty2009; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016; Stark and Garraty Reference Stark, Ossa, Garraty and Stark2010), we tested the degree to which households had homogeneous access to projectile points. Specifically, we compared households containing obsidian points to those containing siliceous points using a contingency table analysis and Fisher's Exact Test. Results suggest that lower-quality chert points were uniformly distributed among houses, regardless of status differences (Fisher's Exact Test, p = 0.51, df = 1, n = 21), including Colha chert (Fisher's Exact Test, p = 0.58, df = 1, n = 21; see Figure 3a). Furthermore, the distribution of chert points among “civic/ritual” contexts, “high-status” contexts, and “other-status” contexts was subjected to a one-way analysis of variance test (ANOVA). We performed this test on the total number of chert points recovered per context, and the total number of points divided by each excavation surface area, to normalize differences in excavation size; the test results were not significant. We ran post hoc t-tests to assess for differences between “other-status” and “high-status”; again, there was no difference (see Table 2).

Figure 3. Projectile point distribution at Santa Rita Corozal (SRC): (a) Santa Rita Corozal number of households with chert points by status; (b) Santa Rita Corozal number of households with obsidian points by status.

Table 2. Santa Rita Corozal Chert Point Statistical Summary.

Note: S.A. = surface area.

In contrast, obsidian points show a skewed spatial distribution among households (Fisher's Exact Test, p = 0.023, df = 1, n = 21; Figure 3b). These points are concentrated in the highest-status houses, with a smaller amount appearing in intermediate-status houses and almost none in lowest-status houses. Yet, no significant difference in obsidian blade consumption was observed among these households (Seidita Reference Seidita2015). Obsidian (n = 576) recovered at Postclassic Santa Rita Corozal, including a sample analyzed with pXRF (n = 536; Seidita et al. Reference Seidita, Chase and Chase2018), indicated that all households had access to obsidian. Thus, obsidian points were restricted for social reasons and not because they were too costly for low-status households. Similarly, chalcedony points were also partially restricted to high-status houses (Fisher's Exact Test, p = 0.1, df = 1, n = 21).

Some metals were also likely exchanged in restricted markets at Chetumal. Gold (e.g., beads, foil) and silver (e.g., bells) commodities, along with rarer gold and silver artifacts that probably were gifts, were only found in high-status households—including those of the halach winik (see Chase Reference Chase, Sabloff and Wyllys Andrews1986:20; Chase and Chase Reference Chase and Chase1988:20). Comparatively, gold adornments were highly restricted in Aztec Mexico; these items identified the owner as possessing significant authority and power that lesser elites did not possess (Chase Reference Chase, Sabloff and Wyllys Andrews1986:20).

Interestingly, the likely residence of a principal and one other high-status house contained the highest number of obsidian and chert points (Chase Reference Chase, Sabloff and Wyllys Andrews1986:355). Examination of the chert debitage (n = 2,449) recovered from these high-status households determined that higher-quality cherts were not controlled at these locations (Marino et al. Reference Marino, Martindale Johnson, Meissner and Walker2016). When combined with the broader lithic dataset, it becomes clear that neither higher-quality cherts, obsidian blades, nor chert points were restricted.

Tlaxcallan

Political Strategies

Ethnohistoric and archaeological evidence indicate that Tlaxcallan encompassed 1,400 km2 and housed 250,000–300,000 people (Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010; Fargher, Blanton, et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton, Heredia Espinoza, Millhauser, Xiuhtecutli and Overholtzer2011). The largest settlement within Tlaxcallan was the densely occupied, 450 ha eponymous hilltop city (Figure 4). Spatial patterns coupled with ethnohistoric information indicate that it was organized in three districts (or sing. teccalli, pl. teccalleque) that were subdivided into neighborhoods (tlaca). Each teccalli was governed by a teuhctli (a titled noble), who probably acceded to his position based on merit, but heredity may have figured in an individual's success (Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010). The teteuctin (pl. of teuhctli) of these districts were important members of Tlaxcallan's ruling council.

Figure 4. Late Postclassic city of Tlaxcallan, with neighborhoods mentioned in text (Fargher, Blanton, et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton, Heredia Espinoza, Millhauser, Xiuhtecutli and Overholtzer2011).

Tlaxcallan's ruling council consisted of 50–250 members, all of whom gained their positions principally through merit accumulated by service to the state. Military service, commercial success, and religious service were the most important pathways to these positions (Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010). This council was the supreme governing authority, and all Tlaxcaltecans were under its jurisdiction. The council elected officials and monitored their official behavior; it also determined the state's political policies, including declaring war and trying high-level officials for crimes. It could sentence any Tlaxcaltecan citizen regardless of their social position (see Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010). Each teuhctli administered a district (teccalli), including tax and tribute collection, organization of military corvée, policing, and public goods supply (Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010).

On the basis of cross-cultural research (e.g., Blanton Reference Blanton, Hirth and Pillsbury2013; Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016; Fargher Reference Fargher2009), we hypothesize that the high degree of collectivity described in early colonial documents was materialized in open and accessible public spaces, where citizens could gather to participate in large collective rituals, attend open markets, and interact personally with governing officials; there was also a wide distribution of both nonlocal materials and elaborate artifacts with little emphasis on monopolies over luxury items. Systematic survey (Fargher, Blanton, et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton, Heredia Espinoza, Millhauser, Xiuhtecutli and Overholtzer2011) demonstrated that this collective organization was materialized in architectural styles that emphasized open, unrestrictive, public spaces coupled with a deemphasis on individual wealth as expressed in the form of elaborate palaces in central locations. Excavations in key public spaces (in and around temples) have demonstrated that elaborate burials typical of aggrandizing elites in other parts of Mesoamerica were not placed in these structures (Caso Reference Caso1927; Contreras Reference Contreras1992; Noguera Reference Noguera1929). Elaborate items and exotic materials, such as polychrome pottery and green obsidian, were widely distributed throughout the site and were not concentrated in “high-status” residences (Fargher, Blanton, et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton, Heredia Espinoza, Millhauser, Xiuhtecutli and Overholtzer2011; Fargher, Heredia, and Blanton Reference Fargher, Blanton, Heredia Espinoza, Millhauser, Xiuhtecutli and Overholtzer2011).

Iconography on both murals and codex-style polychrome pottery corresponds with architectural patterns. Specifically, the Tizatlan and Tlaxcallan (Ocotelulco) murals focus on themes associated with death, sacrifice, warfare, and the gods of night and death. At Tizatlan, the west altar depicts Tezcatlipoca, a god associated with merit and the value of persons regardless of ascribed status, and the Tlaltecuhtli-Tzitzimimeh complex, which references droughts, epidemics, war, death, and destruction (Caso Reference Caso1927; López Corral et al. Reference López Corral, Almanza, Ibarra Narváez and Cano2019:345). The east altar depicts Tlahuizcalpantecuhtli and Xiucoatl, indicating themes of sacrifice, captives (defeated warriors), and war (Caso Reference Caso1927; Jordan Reference Jordan2013:248). The Ocotelulco mural shows the birth of Tezcatlipoca surrounded by the Tlaltecuhtli-Tzitzimimeh complex (Contreras Reference Contreras1992; López Corral et al. Reference López Corral, Almanza, Ibarra Narváez and Cano2019:345).

Iconography on polychrome pottery includes the Tlaltecuhtli-Tzitzimimeh complex, among several others. The Xochicuica-Xochilhuitl complex is associated with ceremonies, ritual acts, and Xochipilli. The Feathers and Flowers complex references cuauhxochitl (eagle-flower) and chimalxochitl (shield-flower), invoking warrior songs and battlefields. The War, Sacrifice, and Nobility complex indicates birds, jaguars, government, and warriors, as well as aztaxelli (feathered headdresses) worn by Tlaxcaltecan warriors in the Lienzo de Tlaxcala. The Teocuitlatl complex implies divinity, foodstuffs for the gods of the night (Tezcatlipoca, Mezti, Mictlantecuhtli), and sacrifice. Lastly, the Mictlan complex references Mictlantecuhtli, the underworld, and darkness (López Corral et al. Reference López Corral, Almanza, Ibarra Narváez and Cano2019:340–346). Thus, the themes on murals and polychrome pottery emphasize service, sacrifice, warfare, death, ritual, merit, and the gods of night, instead of individuals and royal lineages (Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010; López Corral et al. Reference López Corral, Almanza, Ibarra Narváez and Cano2019). Such themes are consistent with descriptions in early colonial documents concerning rituals, religion, and ideology (Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010).

Economics and Exchange

Excavations and systematic survey indicate that much of the hilltop city was terraced using tepetate, a naturally occurring sediment, which makes poor arable (Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Blanton and Heredia Espinoza2010). Thus, agriculture was displaced to the valleys that surround Tlaxcallan. Because the site is several hundred meters above zones with quality arable needed for farming, households would have engaged in craft production, including multicrafting (see Costin Reference Costin, Feinman and Douglas Price2001; Hirth Reference Hirth and Hirth2010), to provide income to purchase commodities in the city's numerous marketplaces and to pay taxes (see also López and Hirth Reference López Corral and Hirth2012). In his second letter, Cortés (Reference Cortés2007 [1522]:67) noted craft items, including pottery, feathers, lapidaries, gold, silver, precious stones, and textiles, for sale in the market at Ocotelulco, Tlaxcallan, which he estimated served many thousands of people. Cortés (Reference Cortés2007 [1522]:67) also stated that multiple marketplaces existed in Tlaxcallan. This pattern may indicate a more decentralized and open market system (see Hirth Reference Hirth2016:71). Cortés (Reference Cortés2007 [1522]; see also Zorita Reference Zorita and Keen1963 [1585]:152–154) also mentioned the presence of judges and police in the market, which would imply state investment in market security.

Archaeological data are consistent with these descriptions. The primary lithic materials recovered by the Tlaxcallan Archaeological Project were obsidian tools and debitage. PXRF analysis demonstrates that multiple sources supplied Tlaxcallan markets with obsidian nodules and prismatic cores (López Corral et al. Reference López Corral, Vera Ortiz, Cano, Hirth and Dyrdahl2015; Millhauser et al. Reference Millhauser, Fargher, Espinoza Heredia and Blanton2015). Importantly, all sources were located outside the borders of the Tlaxcaltecan polity, with most under Aztec control or in disputed regions. The most-used source by Tlaxcaltecans, El Paredón, sits roughly 70 km away in a zone nominally under Aztec supervision; whereas, green obsidian, the next most common material, originated well within the Aztec empire at a distance of approximately 100 km. Because obsidian crossed international boundaries or was purchased in enemy marketplaces, we consider it to be imported and nonlocal.

Currently, 21,000 obsidian artifacts have been analyzed, including 95 projectile points (Figure 5). However, we limited our analysis to points associated with structures (n = 50). These materials were recovered from a terrace with a public function located in the Quiahuixtlan district, three “other-status” houses in the Ocotelulco district, and two houses located in the Tepeticpac district, one of possibly “high-status” (El Fuerte Terrace [EFT.] 30) and one of “other-status.” Status determination is difficult, because extensive excavations have demonstrated that wealth inequality is highly compressed at Tlaxcallan, houses are very homogeneous, and traditional status markers are absent. We identify EFT. 30 as a possible “high-status” context because it is slightly larger than all the other excavated residences and has a slightly larger and nicer talud façade fronting one room (see Fargher et al. Reference Fargher, Antorcha-Pedemonte, Heredia Espinoza, Blanton, Corral, Cook, Millhauser, Marino, Rojo, Alcantara and Costa2020). Overall, structural contexts in each of the three districts are represented in our study; we excavated one high-status, four lower-middle status, and one public space (Figure 6a).

Figure 5. Typical obsidian side-notched projectile points from Tlaxcallan, Mexico.

Figure 6. Projectile point distribution at Tlaxcallan: (a) Tlaxcallan structures by area; (b) Tlaxcallan structures by Postclassic points; (c) Tlaxcallan structures by ratio of Postclassic points to area.

Projectile points were recovered in all of these contexts, indicating that all households had comparatively equal access to obsidian projectile points. Interestingly, a chi-square test reveals a significant difference in consumption of points among households (χ2 = 18.16, p = 0.002, df = 5, n = 50; Figure 6b,c). The house (Ocotelulco T.6, Str. 1) that contains a significantly higher amount of points (n = 18) is a comparatively humble residence with about half the surface area of the “high-status” house on EFT. 30 (Figure 6a,b). In fact, 50% of structures excavated at Tlaxcallan have equal or more points than those found in the high-status context (EFT. 30), despite all being comparatively smaller and having smaller excavation volumes. When Ocotelulco Structure 1 is removed from the sample, no pattern emerges in the consumption of Tlaxcaltecan projectile points (χ2 = 6.125, p = 0.19, df = 4, n = 32).

Discussion

The distribution of points at Chetumal suggests that lithic resources used during the LPC arrived through both local and long-distance networks. Importantly, locally available siliceous materials and the points made from them were widely available across social sectors. This is consistent with local markets and household-based provisioning for auto-consumption. The pattern of consumption for chert points is similar to that of obsidian blades, which indicates market-based distribution (Marino et al. Reference Marino, Martindale Johnson, Meissner and Walker2016; Seidita et al. Reference Seidita, Chase and Chase2018). Small, side-notched chert projectile points were produced on flakes and blades, and these resources were not controlled. Their production and consumption are visible in high-status residential contexts, ritual contexts, and in lower-status contexts (Meissner Reference Meissner2014:416–420).

Obsidian points, made using nonlocal materials, were more restricted to higher-status houses and ritual contexts (along with stingray spines, gold beads and foil, and silver bells), likely reflecting their monopolization for esoteric rituals or other activities conducted by political actors (e.g., the halach winik and batabob). It is significant that the obsidian used to make these items is not restricted, as evidenced by the equitable consumption of obsidian blades among all houses. Instead, it is the specific tool form in conjunction with foreign material that was restricted. This is suggestive of a bifurcated distribution system, which is consistent with restricted market transactions (Blanton Reference Blanton, Hirth and Pillsbury2013; Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016; LeCount Reference LeCount, Fargher and Heredia Espinoza2016).

At Tlaxcallan, it is clear that high-status individuals did not monopolize access to obsidian projectile points or other nonlocal items (e.g., gold, silver, precious stones, fancy pottery) and that lower-status houses had access to them. All of the obsidian was imported, which suggests that large numbers of individuals had access to nonlocal materials and goods across social sectors and geographic space. Such a pattern is consistent with “open” markets and market management strategies designed to resolve cooperation problems and encourage exchange among strangers, foreigners, and locals, as well as across social sectors. Thus, in contrast to Chetumal, obsidian projectile points at Tlaxcallan were not an important political currency.

Energy investments are needed to establish and maintain trade networks and distribution systems. The origin of such investments is important in identifying whether such systems were (1) manipulated for political gains and oriented toward the interests of specific individuals competing for economic and political power through exclusionary strategies, or (2) oriented toward promoting cooperation across social sectors to increase market revenues as part of collective political-economic strategies. At Chetumal, the primary form of social and economic investment came from high-status political actors, as indicated by both ethnohistoric and archaeological data. Consistent with theory (Blanton et al. Reference Blanton, Feinman, Kowalewski and Peregrine1996; D'Altroy and Earle Reference D'Altroy and Earle1985), elite-centered networks were materialized in the patterned consumption of many high-status goods, including obsidian projectile points. Paradigms also predict that open markets and open exchange networks are provided to constituents as a public good in societies where the interests of many are considered (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016; Carballo and Feinman Reference Carballo and Feinman2016). In the case of Tlaxcallan, ethnohistoric accounts indicate that collective strategies were used. Theoretical patterns associated with such political strategies are supported by our economic data, which indicate that formal tools made from exotic materials (like obsidian projectile points) were accessible through open market systems and distributed across social sectors. Thus, governing officials did not monopolize them for use in exclusionary rituals.

Conclusion

Comparing LPC Tlaxcallan with LPC Chetumal demonstrates major differences in production and exchange. At Chetumal, a multitiered economy existed, in which obsidian points and other politically charged artifacts were likely used as one of several high-status items to promote monopolies over ideological resources. Such data suggest limits on access to ritual knowledge, socially embedded exchange networks, and stratified consumption (Chase Reference Chase, Chase and Chase1992; Hirth Reference Hirth, Chase and Chase1992; McAnany Reference McAnany, Hirth and Pillsbury2013), all of which are important characteristics of restricted markets (Blanton and Fargher Reference Blanton and Fargher2016:69–98). In contrast, such controls may not have played a role in the legitimization strategies employed by governing officials at Tlaxcallan. Data from Tlaxcallan demonstrate that the state did not monopolize or manipulate the distribution of nonlocal or elaborated artifacts. All terraces and households had access in comparable amounts, which indicates that exclusionary control by high-status households was minimal. Thus, we suggest that Tlaxcaltecan officials promoted market services, which facilitated the development of open markets, and a more homogeneous distribution of goods as compared with Chetumal. In his description of the Ocotelulco market in Tlaxcallan, Cortés noted that commercial transactions occurred both within the Ocotelulco market and in various other plazas dispersed throughout the city. It is clear from these descriptions that public goods/services were provided to market attendees in the form of market infrastructure, including market security (e.g., judges and police [topiles]), marketplaces (plazas), and temples. These patterns indicate that diverse political strategies, such as elite-centered personalization of power versus collective action, differentially affect market development and the distribution of luxury or ritually charged goods.

Acknowledgments

We thank Drs. Diane and Arlen Chase for use of SRC datasets in several theses, papers, and dissertations. We thank Belize's Institute of Archaeology and the Instituto Nacional de Antrología e Historia (INAH) for permits. We thank Aurelio López for continually providing lab space and assistance. The Tlaxcalan Mapping Project and the Tlaxcallan Archaeological Project were funded by Conacyt (Grant CB-2014-236004), the National Science Foundation (Grants 0809643-BCS, 1450630-BCS), the National Geographic Society (Grant # 8008–06), and the Foundation for the Advancement of Mesoamerican Studies, Inc. The SRC data were collected by the Corozal Postclassic Project directed by D. Z. Chase and A. F. Chase with funding from the National Science Foundation (Grant 8509304-BNS, Grant 8318531-BNS) to D. Z. Chase and A. F. Chase. No financial or institutional conflicts of interest exist.

Data Availability Statement

All data are available in the published sources cited within. Project reports, compiled by the Tlaxcallan Archaeological Project, are available through INAH.

References

References Cited

Acheson, James M. 2011 Ostrom for Anthropologists. International Journal of the Commons 5:319339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andresen, John 1976 Notes on the Pre-Colombian Chert Industry of Northern Belize. In Maya Lithic Studies: Papers from the 1976 Belize Field Symposium, edited by Hester, Thomas R. and Hammond, Norman, pp. 151176. Special Report No. 4. Center for Archaeological Research. University of Texas, San Antonio.Google Scholar
Andrieu, Chloé 2013 Late Classic Maya Lithic Production and Exchange at Rio Bec and Calakmul, Mexico. Journal of Field Archaeology 38:2137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Appadurai, Arjun 1986 Introduction: Commodities and the Politics of Value. In The Social Life of Things: Commodities in Cultural Perspective, edited by Appadurai, Arjun, pp. 363. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berdan, Frances F. 1975 Trade, Tribute, and Market in the Aztec Empire. PhD dissertation, Department of Anthropology, University of Texas, Austin. University Microfilms, Ann Arbor.Google Scholar
Berdan, Frances F., and Anawalt, Patricia R. 1997 The Essential Codex Mendoza. University of California Press, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Blanton, Richard E. 1996 The Basin of Mexico Market System and the Growth of Empire. In Aztec Imperial Strategies, by Berdan, Frances F., Blanton, Richard E., Boone, Elizabeth Hill, Hodge, Mary G., Smith, Michael E., and Umberger, Emily, pp. 4784. Dumbarton Oaks, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Blanton, Richard E. 2013 Cooperation and the Moral Economy of the Marketplace. In Merchants, Markets, and Exchange in the Pre-Columbian World, edited by Hirth, Kenneth G. and Pillsbury, Joanne, pp. 2345. Dumbarton Oaks, Washington DC.Google Scholar
Blanton, Richard E., and Fargher, Lane F. 2008 Collective Action in the Formation of Pre-Modern States. Springer, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Richard E., and Fargher, Lane F. 2009 Collective Action in the Evolution of Pre-Modern States. Social and Evolutionary History 8:133166.Google Scholar
Blanton, Richard E., and Fargher, Lane F. 2016 How Humans Cooperate: Confronting the Challenges of Collective Action. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanton, Richard E., Fargher, Lane F., and Heredia-Espinoza, Verenice 2005 The Mesoamerican World of Goods and Its Transformations. In Settlement, Subsistence, and Social Complexity: Essays Honoring the Legacy of Jeffrey R. Parsons, edited by Blanton, Richard E., pp. 260294. Cotsen Institute of Archaeology Press, University of California, Los Angeles.Google Scholar
Blanton, Richard E., Feinman, Gary M., Kowalewski, Stephen A., and Peregrine, Peter N. 1996 A Dual-Processual Theory for the Evolution of Mesoamerican Civilization. Current Anthropology 37:114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braswell, Geoffrey E. 2003 Obsidian Exchange Spheres. In The Postclassic Mesoamerican World, edited by Smith, Michael E. and Berdan, Francis F., pp. 131158. University of Utah Press, Salt Lake City.Google Scholar
Braswell, Geoffrey E. 2010 The Rise and Fall of Market Exchange: A Dynamic Approach to Ancient Maya Economy. In Archaeological Approaches to Market Exchange in Ancient Societies, edited by Garraty, Christopher P. and Stark, Barbara L., pp. 127140. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.Google Scholar
Brumfiel, Elizabeth M. 1987 Elite and Utilitarian Crafts in the Aztec State. In Specialization, Exchange, and Complex Societies, edited by Brumfiel, Elizabeth M. and Earle, Timothy K., pp. 102118. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Brumfiel, Elizabeth M. 1991 Tribute and Commerce in Imperial Cities: The Case of Xaltocan, Mexico. In Early State Economics, edited by Claessen, Henri J. M. and van de Velde, Pieter, pp. 177198. Political and Legal Anthropology Vol. 8. Transaction, New Brunswick, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Carballo, David M. 2007 Implements of State Power: Weaponry and Martially Themed Obsidian Production Near the Moon Pyramid, Teotihuacan. Ancient Mesoamerica 18:173190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carballo, David M., and Feinman, Gary M. 2016 Cooperation, Collective Action, and the Archaeology of Large-Scale Societies. Evolutionary Anthropology 25:288296.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Carballo, David M., Roscoe, Paul, and Feinman, Gary M. 2014 Cooperation and Collective Action in the Cultural Evolution of Complex Societies. Journal of Archaeological Method and Theory 21:98133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carrasco, Pedro 1983 Some Theoretical Considerations about the Role of the Market in Ancient Mexico. In Economic Anthropology: Topics and Theory, edited by Ortiz, Sutti, pp. 6782. University Press of America, Lanham, Maryland.Google Scholar
Caso, Alfonso 1927 Las ruinas de Tizatlán, Tlaxcala. Revista Mexicana de Estudios Antropológicos 1:139–172.Google Scholar
Chamberlain, Robert S. 1948 The Conquest and Colonization of the Yucatan. Publication 582. Carnegie Institute of Washington, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Charlton, Cynthia Otis 1994 Plebians and Patricians: Contrasting Patterns of Craft Production and Distribution in the Aztec Figuring and Lapidary Industries. In Economies and Polities in the Aztec Realm, edited by Hodge, Mary and Smith, Michael E., pp. 192213. University of Texas Press, Austin.Google Scholar
Chase, Arlen F., and Chase, Diane Z. 2004 Exploring Ancient Economic Relationships at Caracol, Belize. Research Reports in Belizean Archaeology 1:115227.Google Scholar
Chase, Arlen F., and Rice, Prudence M. (editors) 1985 The Lowland Maya Postclassic. University of Texas Press, Austin.Google Scholar
Chase, Diane Z. 1982 Spatial and Temporal Variability in Postclassic Northern Belize. PhD dissertation, Department of Anthropology, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia.Google Scholar
Chase, Diane Z. 1985 Between Earth and Sky: Idols, Images, and Postclassic Cosmology. In Fifth Palenque Roundtable, edited by Robertson, Merle G. and Fields, Virginia M., Vol. VII, pp. 223233. Pre-Columbian Art Research Institute, San Francisco.Google Scholar
Chase, Diane Z. 1986 Social and Political Organization in the Land of Cacao and Honey: Correlating the Archaeology and Ethnohistory of the Postclassic Lowland Maya. In Late Lowland Maya Civilization: Classic to Postclassic, edited by Sabloff, Jerome A. and Wyllys Andrews, E.. Vol. V, pp. 347377. University of New Mexico Press, Albuquerque.Google Scholar
Chase, Diane Z. 1992 Postclassic Maya Elites: Ethnohistory and Archaeology. In Mesoamerican Elites: An Archaeological Assessment, edited by Chase, Diane Z. and Chase, Arlen F., pp. 118134. University of Oklahoma Press, Norman.Google Scholar
Chase, Diane Z., and Chase, Arlen F. 1988 A Postclassic Perspective: Excavations at the Maya Site of Santa Rita Corozal, Belize. Monograph 4. Pre-Columbian Art Research Institute, San Francisco.Google Scholar
Chase, Diane Z., and Chase, Arlen F. 2008 Late Postclassic Ritual at Santa Rita Corozal, Belize: Understanding the Archaeology of a Maya Capital City. Research Reports in Belizean Archaeology 5:7992.Google Scholar
Chase, Diane Z., and Chase, Arlen F. 2014 Ancient Maya Markets and the Economic Integration of Caracol, Belize. Ancient Mesoamerica 25:239250.Google Scholar
Contreras, José 1992 Los hallazgos arqueológicos de Ocotelulco, Tlaxcala. Arqueología 7:113118.Google Scholar
Cortés, Hernan 2007 [1522] Cartas de relacíon. Grupo Editorial Exodo, Mexico City.Google Scholar
Costin, Cathy L. 2001 Craft Production Systems. In Archaeology at the Millennium: A Sourcebook, edited by Feinman, Gary M. and Douglas Price, T., pp. 273327. Springer, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D'Altroy, Terrence N., and Earle, Timothy K. 1985 Staple Finance, Wealth Finance, and Storage in the Inka Political Economy. Current Anthropology 26:187206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeMarrais, Elizabeth, and Earle, Timothy K. 2017 Collective Action Theory and the Dynamics of Complex Societies. Annual Review of Anthropology 46:183201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Earle, Timothy K., and Spriggs, Matthew 2015 Political Economy in Prehistory: A Marxist Approach to Pacific Sequences. Current Anthropology 56:515544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fargher, Lane F. 2009 A Comparison of the Spatial Distribution of Agriculture and Craft Specialization in Five State-Level Societies. Journal of Anthropological Research 65:353387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fargher, Lane F., Antorcha-Pedemonte, Ricardo R., Heredia Espinoza, Verenice Y., Blanton, Richard E., Corral, Aurelio López, Cook, Robert A., Millhauser, John K., Marino, Marc D., Rojo, Iziar Martínez, Alcantara, Ivonne Pérez, and Costa, Angelica 2020 Wealth Inequality, Social Stratification, and the Built Environment in Late Prehispanic Highland Mexico: A Comparative Analysis with Special Emphasis on Tlaxcallan. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology. DOI:10.1016/j.jaa.2020.101176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fargher, Lane F., and Blanton, Richard E. 2007 Revenue, Voice, and Public Goods in Three Pre-Modern States. Comparative Studies of Society and History 49:848882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fargher, Lane F., Blanton, Richard E., and Heredia Espinoza, Verenice Y. 2010 Egalitarian Ideology and Political Power in Prehispanic Central Mexico: The Case of Tlaxcallan. Latin American Antiquity 21:227251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fargher, Lane F., Blanton, Richard E., Heredia Espinoza, Verenice Y., Millhauser, John, Xiuhtecutli, Nezahualcoyotl, and Overholtzer, Lisa G. 2011 Tlaxcallan, the Archaeology of an Ancient Republic in the New World. Antiquity 85:172186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feinman, Gary M., and Garraty, Christopher P. 2010 Preindustrial Markets and Marketing: Archaeological Perspectives. Annual Review of Anthropology 39:167191.Google Scholar
Feinman, Gary M., and Nicholas, Linda M. 2011 Domestic Craft Production and the Classic Period Economy of Oaxaca. In Producción artesanal y especializada en Mesoamérica: Áreas de actividad y procesos productivos, edited by Manzanilla, Linda R. and Hirth, Kenneth G., pp. 2958. INAH and Universidad Nacional Autónoma de México, Mexico City.Google Scholar
Fox, John W., Cook, Garrett W., and Demarest, Arthur A. 1996 Constructing Maya Communities: Ethnography for Archaeology. Current Anthropology 37:811830.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freidel, David A., and Sabloff, Jeremy A. 1984 Cozumel: Late Maya Settlement Patterns. Academic Press, Orlando, Florida.Google Scholar
Garraty, Christopher L. 2009 Evaluating the Distributional Approach to Inferring Marketplace Exchange: A Test Case from the Mexican Gulf Lowlands. Latin American Antiquity 20:157174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hassig, Ross 1985 Trade, Tribute, and Transportation: The Sixteenth Century Political Economy of the Valley of Mexico. University of Oklahoma Press, Norman.Google Scholar
Hirth, Kenneth G. 1992 Interregional Exchange as Elite Behavior: An Evolutionary Perspective. In Mesoamerican Elites: An Archaeological Assessment, edited by Chase, Diane Z. and Chase, Arlen F., pp. 1829. University of Oklahoma Press, Norman.Google Scholar
Hirth, Kenneth G. 1993 Identifying Rank and Socioeconomic Status in Domestic Contexts: An Example from Central Mexico. In Prehispanic Domestic Units in Western Mesoamerica: Studies of the Household, Compound, and Residence, edited by Santley, Robert S. and Hirth, Kenneth G., pp. 121146. CRC Press, Boca Raton, Florida.Google Scholar
Hirth, Kenneth G. 1998 The Distributional Approach: A New Way to Identify Marketplace Exchange in the Archaeological Record. Current Anthropology 39:451476.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirth, Kenneth G. 2010 Craft Production, Household Diversification, and Domestic Economy in Prehispanic Mesoamerica. In Housework: Craft Production and Domestic Economy in Ancient Mesoamerica, edited by Hirth, Kenneth G., pp. 1332. Archaeological Papers Vol. 19. American Anthropological Association, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Hirth, Kenneth G. 2016 The Aztec Economic World: Merchants and Markets in Ancient Mesoamerica. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Johnson, Lucas R. Martindale 2016 Toward an Itinerary of Stone: Investigating the Movement, Crafting, and Use of Obsidian from Caracol, Belize. PhD dissertation, Department of Anthropology, University of Florida, Gainesville.Google Scholar
Jordan, Keith 2013 Serpents, Skeletons, and Ancestors? The Tula Coatepantli Revisited. Ancient Mesoamerica 24:243274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landa, Diego de 1975 [1566] The Maya (Diego de Landa's Account of the Affairs of the Yucatan). Translated and edited by Pagden, Anthony R.. O'Hare, Chicago.Google Scholar
LeCount, Lisa J. 2016 Classic Maya Marketplaces and Exchanges: Examining Market Competition as a Factor for Understanding Commodity Distributions. In Alternative Pathways to Complexity: A Collection of Essays on Architecture, Economics, Power, and Cross-Cultural Analysis, edited by Fargher, Lane F. and Heredia Espinoza, Verenice Y., pp. 155173. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret 1988 Of Rule and Revenue. University of California Press, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Levine, Marc N. 2011 Negotiating Political Economy at Late Postclassic Tututepec (Yucu Dzaa), Oaxaca, Mexico. American Anthropologist 113:2239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levine, Marc N., Fargher, Lane F., Cecil, Leslie G., and Ford, Jaime E. 2015 Polychrome Pottery Economics and Ritual Life in Postclassic Oaxaca, Mexico. Latin American Antiquity 26:319340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindkvist, Thomas 1991 Social and Political Power in Sweden, 1000–1300: Predatory Incursions, Royal Taxation, and the Formation of a Feudal State. In Social Approaches to Viking Studies, edited by Samson, Ross, pp. 137–45. Boydell & Brewer, Rochester, New York.Google Scholar
López Corral, Aurelio, Almanza, Ivonne Velasco, Ibarra Narváez, Thania E., and Cano, Ramón Santacruz 2019 Iconografía y gobierno colectivo durante el posclásico tardío en Tepeticpac y Tlaxcallan, México. Latin American Antiquity 30: 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López Corral, Aurelio, and Hirth, Kenneth G. 2012 Terrazguero Smallholders and the Function of Agricultural Tribute in Sixteenth-Century Tepeaca, Mexico. Journal of Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos 28:7393.Google Scholar
López Corral, Aurelio, Vera Ortiz, Manuel Ángel, Cano, Ramón Santacruz, Hirth, Kenneth G., and Dyrdahl, Eric 2015 ¿Química o color?: Comparación entre el uso de fluorescencia de rayos-X portátil y las técnicas visuales de clasificación de obsidiana de Tepeticpac. Arqueología 50:157174.Google Scholar
Marino, Marc D., Martindale Johnson, Lucas R., and Meissner, Nathan J. 2016 Postclassic Tool Production at Santa Rita Corozal, Implications for Domestic Craft Production and Regional Exchange in Flaked Stone. In Perspectives on the Ancient Maya of Chetumal Bay, edited by Walker, Debra S., pp. 251263. University of Florida Press, Gainesville.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masson, Marilyn A. 2000 In the Realm of Nachan Kan: Postclassic Maya Archaeology at Laguna de On, Belize. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.Google Scholar
Masson, Marilyn A. 2002 Community Economy and the Mercantile Transformation in Postclassic Northeastern Belize. In Ancient Maya Political Economies, edited by Masson, Marilyn A. and Freidel, David A., pp. 335364. AltaMira Press, Lanham, Maryland.Google Scholar
Masson, Marilyn A., and Freidel, David A. 2012 An Argument for Classic Era Maya Market Exchange. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 31:455484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAnany, Patricia A. 2013 Artisans, Ikatz, and Statecraft: Provisioning Classic Maya Royal Courts. In Merchants, Markets, and Exchange in the Pre-Columbian World, edited by Hirth, Kenneth G. and Pillsbury, Joanne, pp. 229253. Dumbarton Oaks, Washington DC.Google Scholar
McKillop, Heather 2005 Finds in Belize Document Late Classic Maya Salt Making and Canoe Transport. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 102:56305634.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Meissner, Nathan J. 2014 Technological Systems of Small Point Weaponry of the Postclassic Lowland Maya (A.D. 1250–1697). PhD dissertation, Department of Anthropology, Southern Illinois University, Carbondale.Google Scholar
Meissner, Nathan J. 2017 A Social Network Analysis of the Postclassic Lowland Maya Obsidian Projectile Industry. Ancient Mesoamerica 28:137156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meissner, Nathan J. 2018 Small Projectile Points of Petén: Resources, Production, and Interpolity Variability. In Historical and Archaeological Perspectives on the Itzas of Petén, Guatemala, edited by Rice, Prudence M. and Rice, Don S., pp. 252272. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meissner, Nathan J., and Rice, Prudence M. 2015 Postclassic Petén Maya Bow-and-Arrow Use as Revealed by Immunological Analysis. Journal of Archaeological Science 64:6776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millhauser, John K., Fargher, Lane F., Espinoza Heredia, Verenice Y., and Blanton, Richard E. 2015 The Geopolitics of Obsidian Supply in Postclassic Tlaxcallan: A Portable X-Ray Fluorescence Study. Journal of Archaeological Science 58:133146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrison, Kathleen D. 1994 The Intensification of Production: Archaeological Approaches. Journal of Archaeological Method and Theory 1:111159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nichols, Deborah L., Brumfiel, Elizabeth M., Neff, Hector, Hodge, Mary, and Charlton, Thomas H. 2002 Neutrons, Markets, Cities, and Empires: A 1000-Year Perspective on Ceramic Production and Distribution in the Postclassic Basin of Mexico. Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 21:2882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noguera, Eduardo 1929 Ruinas de Tizatlan, Tlaxcala: Los altares de sacrificio de Tizatlan, Tlaxcala. Publicaciones de la Secretaria de Educación Pública 20:2465.Google Scholar
Oland, Maxine 1999 Lithic Raw Material Sources at the Southern End of the Freshwater Creek Drainage: A View from Laguna de On, Belize. Lithic Technology 24:91110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oland, Maxine 2013 The Fifteenth-Seventeenth Century Lithic Economy at Progresso Lagoon, Belize. Lithic Technology 38:8196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oland, Maxine 2016 Chetumal Bay in the Fifteenth to Seventeenth Centuries. In Perspectives on the Ancient Maya of Chetumal Bay, edited by Walker, Debra S., pp. 108122. University Press of Florida, Gainesville.Google Scholar
Olko, Justyna 2014 Insignia of Rank in the Nahua World. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1999 Institutional Rational Choice. In Theories of the Policy Process, edited by Sabatier, Paul A., pp. 3572. Westview Press, Boulder, Colorado.Google Scholar
Peregrine, Peter N. 1991 Some Political Aspects of Craft Specialization. World Archaeology 23:111.Google Scholar
Piña Chan, Roman 1978 Commerce in the Yucatan Peninsula: The Conquest and Colonial Period. In Mesoamerican Communication Routes and Cultural Contacts, edited by Lee, Thomas A. and Navarette, Carlos, pp. 3748. Papers of the New World Archaeological Foundation Vol. 40. Brigham Young University, Provo, Utah.Google Scholar
Ringle, William M., Negrón, Tomás G., and Bey, George J. III 1998 The Return of Quetzalcoatl: Evidence for the Spread of a World Religion during the Epiclassic Period. Ancient Mesoamerica 9:183232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roys, Ralph L. 1933 The Book of Chilam Bilam of Chumayel. Publication No. 438. Carnegie Institute of Washington, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Roys, Ralph L. 1957 The Political Geography of the Yucatan Maya. Publication No. 613. Carnegie Institution of Washington, Washington DC.Google Scholar
Sabloff, Jeremy A., and Rathje, William L. 1975 The Rise of a Maya Merchant Class. Scientific American 233:7382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scholes, Frances V., and Roys, Ralph L. 1948 The Maya Chontal Indians of Acalan-Tixchel: A Contribution to the History and Ethnography of the Yucatán Peninsula. University of Oklahoma Press, Norman.Google Scholar
Seidita, Max 2015 Chetumal's Dragonglass: Postclassic Obsidian Production and Exchange at Santa Rita Corozal, Belize. Master's thesis, Department of Anthropology, University of Central Florida, Orlando.Google Scholar
Seidita, Max, Chase, Diane Z., and Chase, Arlen F. 2018 Postclassic Obsidian Production and Exchange at Santa Rita Corozal, Belize. Research Reports in Belizean Archaeology 15:169178.Google Scholar
Shafer, Harry J., and Hester, Thomas R. 1988 Preliminary Analysis of Postclassic Lithics from Santa Rita Corozal, Belize. Monograph 4. Pre-Columbian Art Research Institute, San Francisco.Google Scholar
Smith, Carol A. 1976 Exchange Systems and the Spatial Distribution of Elites: The Organization of Stratification in Agrarian Societies. In Regional Analysis, Vol. 2, edited by Smith, Carol A., pp. 309374. Academic Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Michael E. 2010 Regional and Local Market Systems in Aztec-Period Morelos. In Archaeological Approaches to Market Exchange in Ancient Societies, edited by Garraty, Christopher P. and Stark, Barbara L., pp. 161182. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.Google Scholar
Smith, Michael E. 2014 The Aztecs Paid Taxes, Not Tribute. Mexicon 36:1922.Google Scholar
Smith, Michael E., and Berdan, Frances F. 2000 The Postclassic Mesoamerican World System. Current Anthropology 41:283286.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stark, Barbara L., and Garraty, Christopher P. (editors) 2010 Archaeological Approaches to Market Exchange in Ancient Societies. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.Google Scholar
Stark, Barbara, and Ossa, Alanna 2010 Origins and Development of Marketplaces: Evidence from South-Central Veracruz, Mexico. In Archaeological Approaches to Market Exchange in Ancient Societies, edited by Garraty, Christopher P. and Stark, Barbara L., pp. 99126. University Press of Colorado, Boulder.Google Scholar
Stross, Brian 1983 The Language of Zuyua. American Ethnologist 10:150164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taube, Karl A. 1989 Itzam Cab Ain: Caimans, Cosmology, and Calendrics in Postclassic Yucatán. Research Reports on Ancient Maya Writing Vol. 26. Center for Maya Research, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Taube, Karl A. 2010 At Dawn's Edge: Tulúm, Santa Rita, and Floral Symbolism in the International Style of Late Postclassic Mesoamerica. In Astronomers, Scribes, and Priests: Intellectual Interchange between the Northern Maya Lowlands and Highland Mexico in the Late Postclassic Period, edited by Vail, Gabrielle and Hernández, Christine, pp. 145191. Dumbarton Oaks, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Thomas, David H. 1978 Arrowheads and Atlatl Darts: How the Stones Got the Shaft. American Antiquity 43:461472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zorita, Alonso de 1963 [1585] Life and Labor in Ancient Mexico: The Brief and Summary Relations of the Lords of New Spain. Translated by Keen, Benjamin. Rutgers University Press, New Brunswick, New Jersey.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Contemporary Santa Rita Corozal, the capital city of the Chetumal polity, with sites and sectors mentioned in text (after Chase and Chase 1988:Figures 41–52).

Figure 1

Table 1. Types of Exchanges Based on Embedded (“Non-Market”) or Commercial Relationships (Market Systems).

Figure 2

Figure 2. Typical obsidian side-notched points from Santa Rita Corozal (Meissner 2014:345, Figure 6.20).

Figure 3

Figure 3. Projectile point distribution at Santa Rita Corozal (SRC): (a) Santa Rita Corozal number of households with chert points by status; (b) Santa Rita Corozal number of households with obsidian points by status.

Figure 4

Table 2. Santa Rita Corozal Chert Point Statistical Summary.

Figure 5

Figure 4. Late Postclassic city of Tlaxcallan, with neighborhoods mentioned in text (Fargher, Blanton, et al. 2011).

Figure 6

Figure 5. Typical obsidian side-notched projectile points from Tlaxcallan, Mexico.

Figure 7

Figure 6. Projectile point distribution at Tlaxcallan: (a) Tlaxcallan structures by area; (b) Tlaxcallan structures by Postclassic points; (c) Tlaxcallan structures by ratio of Postclassic points to area.