Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T06:40:23.720Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Welfare implications of product choice regulation during the payout phase of funded pensions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 December 2013

VANYA HORNEFF
Affiliation:
Department of Finance, Goethe University Frankfurt, Grüneburgplatz 1 (Uni-PF H 23), 60323 Frankfurt am Main, Germany (e-mail: vhorneff@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, kaschuetzke@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, maurer@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, rogalla@finance.uni-frankfurt.de)
BARBARA KASCHÜTZKE
Affiliation:
Department of Finance, Goethe University Frankfurt, Grüneburgplatz 1 (Uni-PF H 23), 60323 Frankfurt am Main, Germany (e-mail: vhorneff@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, kaschuetzke@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, maurer@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, rogalla@finance.uni-frankfurt.de)
RAIMOND MAURER
Affiliation:
Department of Finance, Goethe University Frankfurt, Grüneburgplatz 1 (Uni-PF H 23), 60323 Frankfurt am Main, Germany (e-mail: vhorneff@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, kaschuetzke@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, maurer@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, rogalla@finance.uni-frankfurt.de)
RALPH ROGALLA
Affiliation:
Department of Finance, Goethe University Frankfurt, Grüneburgplatz 1 (Uni-PF H 23), 60323 Frankfurt am Main, Germany (e-mail: vhorneff@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, kaschuetzke@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, maurer@finance.uni-frankfurt.de, rogalla@finance.uni-frankfurt.de)
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In many countries, governmental support for funded old-age programmes comes at the cost of at least partial mandatory annuitisation of accumulated assets in retirement. We survey regulatory frameworks for the payout phase of funded pension systems in seven European countries and the US and study the influence of mandatory annuitisation on the welfare of both rational and behaviourally influenced individuals using a dynamic life-cycle model. We show that mandatory immediate full annuitisation of retirement assets will reduce rational individuals’ certainty equivalent pension wealth by up to 54%. Softening the strict immediate annuitisation requirements along the line of regulatory realities in some of the surveyed countries reduces utility losses considerably. Behaviourally restricted individuals can benefit from full annuitisation at retirement, but generally they will also prefer more flexible regulation.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

1 Introduction

In most industrialised countries, statutory pension systems are under pressure due to demographic changes, and policymakers around the world recognise the need to supplement the pay-as-you-go systems with funded employment-based or personal schemes. In most countries, incentives to save for retirement take the form of tax reliefs for contributions to eligible old-age programmes. In return for support during the accumulation phase, most programmes impose restrictions on how to draw down accrued funds in retirement. These restrictions typically take the form of compulsory annuitisation, enforced either by legislative or regulatory means, or by tax disadvantages, and usually they are independent of the total amount of retirement capital available or the level of pre-existing pension income from other sources.

There are three main arguments for requiring retirees to annuitise funds from tax-sheltered retirement accounts. First, paternalistic states, especially those in continental Europe, aim at preventing old-age poverty resulting from moral hazard in social security systems or from retirees’ myopia. Moral hazard arises when retirees deliberately exhaust their savings too early, expecting the government to bail them out at advanced ages. Consequently, governments impose regulation that prevents individuals from double dipping statutory support, first through deferred taxation during the saving phase and later through tax-financed social security payments. In case of myopia, individuals underestimate their life expectancy and their financial needs in retirement due to a lack of information or financial literacy, and again spend too much too early. Mandatory annuitisation is a potent instrument to prevent both moral hazard and myopia.

Second, governments also worry that individuals spend too little for too long. Old-age saving schemes are regularly supported by means of deferred taxation, where contributions and investment returns are tax exempt while withdrawals in retirement are taxed. Delaying withdrawals will delay tax payments. Moreover, allowing for discretionary withdrawals from retirement accounts results in an unpredictable stream of income taxes. Mandating the purchase of annuities, however, guarantees a timely and predictable tax flow.

Third, governmental support for funded pension schemes aims at helping individuals build up supplemental retirement income. By contrast, it is not intended to sponsor bequests. Annuities provide lifelong income for the retiree and typically prevent wealth from being transferred to the next generation.

While retiree protection is one of the central arguments put forward by those who favour tight restrictions with respect to admissible withdrawal patterns, little is known about the impact of those restrictions on retired individuals’ utility. Among the few papers that explicitly analyse the implications of regulatory restrictions on rational individuals are Mitchell et al. (Reference Mitchell, Poterba, Warshawsky and Brown1999) as well as Horneff et al. (Reference Horneff, Maurer and Stamos2008b). This study aims at shedding more light on this issue.

Our work extends prior literature in several ways. We present an extensive survey of regulatory environments for private and occupational pension systems in several European countries, including those with a high share of second pillar savings, as well as in the USA. We develop a classification system for restrictions imposed on product choice during the payout phase. Based on this system, we derive stylised payout regulations that we integrate into a dynamic life-cycle model along the lines of Horneff et al. (Reference Horneff, Maurer, Mitchell and Stamos2010). Using this model, we study the welfare implications of alternative levels of mandatory annuitisation for both fully rational individuals as well as retirees that exclude annuities from their investment menu for behavioural reasons.

In line with prior studies, we find that for fully rational individuals it is optimal to annuitise gradually, even in the absence of bequest motives. Hence, stipulating full annuitisation at retirement substantially reduces individuals’ wellbeing, while other forms of mandatory annuitisation result in considerably smaller utility losses. By contrast, behaviourally restricted individuals can benefit from being required to fully annuitise retirement wealth. Yet, even those individuals will generally prefer more flexible regulation.

The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 provides a brief overview of the related literature. Section 3 describes tax-supported funded pension schemes in seven European countries as well as the USA and presents and classifies the regulatory restrictions imposed during the payout phase. Section 4 derives optimal investment and consumption strategies in absence of any regulatory restrictions on payout product choice and examines welfare losses from enforced immediate, partial, and deferred annuitisation. Section 5 concludes.

2 Related literature

Previous literature on funded pensions within the rational decision-making framework can broadly be divided into four main strands. The first concentrates on the properties, advantages, and disadvantages of particular retirement products and their modifications, e.g., annuities or withdrawal plans. Yaari (Reference Yaari1965), for example, shows that under restrictive assumptions, such as actuarially fair pricing of annuities, rational retirees lacking bequest motives should fully annuitise available wealth. Davidoff et al. (Reference Davidoff, Brown and Diamond2005) relax some of Yaari's restrictive assumptions. They conclude that, while partial annuitisation will be optimal for those wanting to bequeath wealth to their heirs, full annuitisation is still advantageous in absence of any bequest motive if the net return on annuities is greater than that on a reference asset. James and Song (Reference James and Song2001) provide an international comparison of money's worth ratios, a measure of actuarial fairness in annuity pricing introduced by Mitchell et al. (Reference Mitchell, Poterba, Warshawsky and Brown1999). Dus et al. (Reference Dus, Maurer and Mitchell2005) analyse shortfall risks of phased withdrawal plans with respect to benefits provided by life annuities, while Milevsky (Reference Milevsky2002) compares the risk/return characteristics of variable annuities with their fixed and escalating counterparts.

A second group of papers focuses on retirement strategies with one or more payout products and studies the optimal timing for purchasing those products. Milevsky and Young (Reference Milevsky and Young2007) analyse the optimal timing of annuitisation within a dominance framework. Horneff et al. (Reference Horneff, Maurer and Stamos2008b) derive optimal consumption and saving strategies with fixed life annuities, stocks, and bonds in a realistically calibrated life-cycle model, allowing for gradual annuitisation, and later – in Maurer et al. (Reference Maurer, Mitchell, Rogalla and Kartashov2013) – expand their work to variable annuities.

The third strand of literature examines regulation and supervision of retirement products, particularly focusing on product quality. This area of research includes, among others, papers by the OECD (2009) on principles for the regulation of private occupational pension schemes, by Dus and Maurer (Reference Dus and Maurer2009) on capital requirements for the payout phase of funded pensions in Germany, as well as descriptive country studies on available pension programmes and their regulation (e.g., Palme and Svensson, Reference Palme, Svensson, Gruber and Wise1999; Queisser and Vittas, Reference Queisser and Vittas2000; Hülsmann et al., Reference Hülsmann, Schmid and Schöll2001; Bateman and Thorp, Reference Bateman and Thorp2008).

Finally, a substantial literature has developed around the so-called annuity puzzle, i.e., the phenomenon that the empirically observable voluntary annuity take-up is lowFootnote 1, despite the theoretical appeal of annuitisation. Rational arguments put forward to explain the reluctance to annuitise include actuarially unfair annuities (Mitchell et al., Reference Mitchell, Poterba, Warshawsky and Brown1999; Finkelstein and Poterba, Reference Finkelstein and Poterba2004), incomplete annuity markets (Horneff et al., Reference Horneff, Maurer, Mitchell and Dus2008a; Peijnenburg et al., Reference Peijnenburg, Nijman and Werker2010a), crowding out by Social Security (Dushi and Webb, Reference Dushi and Webb2004), bequest motives (Friedman and Warshawsky, Reference Friedman and Warshawsky1990; Bernheim, Reference Bernheim1991; Lockwood, Reference Lockwood2012), intra-family hedging (Kotlikoff and Spivak, Reference Kotlikoff and Spivak1981; Brown and Poterba, Reference Brown and Poterba2000; Hubener et al., Reference Hubener, Maurer and Rogalla2013), as well as health shocks and the resulting medical expenses (Peijnenburg et al., Reference Peijnenburg, Nijman and Werker2010b; Ameriks et al., Reference Ameriks, Caplin, Laufer and Van Nieuwerburgh2011). These arguments, however, fail to fully solve the annuity puzzle.

Other studies analyse the annuity puzzle from a behavioural perspective. Benartzi et al. (Reference Benartzi, Previtero and Thaler2011), for example, point out that the same behavioural factors that explain saving behaviour, such as self-control problems, inertia, and lack of financial sophistication, help to understand how individuals approach the task of asset decumulation. At the same time, several studies find evidence that framing has substantial impact on the annuitisation decision, e.g., among others, Hu and Scott (Reference Hu and Scott2007), Agnew et al. (Reference Agnew, Anderson, Gerlach and Szykman2008), Behaghel and Blau (Reference Behaghel and Blau2012), and Brown et al. (Reference Brown, Kling, Mullainathan and Wrobel2008, Reference Brown, Kapteyn and Mitchell2013). Further behavioural explanations for the reluctance to annuitise include choice bracketing (Read et al., Reference Read, Löwenstein and Rabin1999), the persistence of default options during the payout phase (Bütler and Teppa, Reference Bütler and Teppa2007), the complexity of the annuitisation decision (Brown et al., Reference Brown, Kapteyn, Luttmer and Mitchell2011), and time-inconsistent preferences (Schreiber and Weber, Reference Schreiber and Weber2013).

3 Regulating payout product choice in funded pensions

3.1 Countries surveyed and their funded pension schemes

Our study of product choice regulation in the payout phase of funded pensions draws on a survey of seven representative European countries: Austria, France, Germany, Italy, Sweden, Switzerland, and the UK. For comparison, we also look at the USA. In all surveyed countries, the vast majority of the population is covered by some form of statutory pensionFootnote 2. In Austria, France, Germany, and Italy, statutory pension programmes still provide rather high replacements rates and represent the main source of retirement income. At the same time, participation in occupational or personal pension schemes is either voluntary or individuals have the possibility to opt out. Consequently, the amount of assets accumulated within funded pension schemes is still small compared to the countries’ GDP and gross debt.

By contrast, statutory pension systems in Switzerland, the UK, and the USA provide relatively low benefits, resulting in high individual responsibility for generating retirement income from other sourcesFootnote 3. Switzerland and Sweden mandate participation in employment-linked old-age programmes, either through legislation, in the case of Switzerland, or through collective agreements between trade unions and employers, in the case of Sweden. In both countries, employees do not have the chance to opt out of the system. Consequently, second pillar savings in these two countries are significant, and the resulting payouts are high enough to substantially contribute to financing the cost of living in retirement. On top of the second pillar, Sweden is the only country in which the statutory pensions system is partially funded (so-called premium pension scheme).

In the UK and the US, despite the lack of mandatory participation, funded pension schemes have also accumulated a substantial amount of assets.

For each country surveyed, Table 1 provides an overview of the funded pension programmes currently open to new members, including information on the amount of assets accumulated. To put these numbers into perspective, we also relate them to the country's GDP and general government gross debt.

Table 1. Overview of representative funded pensions programmes

Notes: Programmes open to new participants (excl. government employees). Programme size based on the latest information available (ranging from 2009 to 2013). For non-Euro countries: Exchange rates as published by the Financial Times on 18th July 2013.

1 Prämienbegünstigte Zukunftsvorsorge – Sponsored Retirement Provision.

2 Mitarbeiter Vorsorgekassen – Employee Provision Funds.

3 PERP (Le Plan d’Épargne Retraite Populaire) – People's Retirement Savings Plan.

4 PERCO (Le Plan d’Épargne pour la Retraite Collectif) – Group savings plan for retirement.

5 PPM (Premiepensionsmyndigheten) – Premium Pension Agency.

6 IRA – Individual Retirement Account (ranging from 2009–2013). (see note above). Sources: OECD (2013) ; Austria: ÖNB (2013a), FMA (2012), ÖNB (2013b) ; France: FFSA (2011), AFG (2012) ; Germany: BaFin (2011), BaFin (2012), Schwind (Reference Schwind2013), GDV (2012) ; Italy: Covip (2012) ; Sweden: OECD (2012), SPA(2012), Statistics Sweden (2013) ; Switzerland: BFS (2011), SVV (2009), Schweizerische Nationalbank (2013) ; UK: ONS (2013) ; USA: DOL (2012), ICI (2013) .

3.2 Overview and classification of product choice restrictions

Having presented the alternative funded pension schemes in the previous section, we now turn to discussing the main features of the associated restrictions with respect to product choice in the payout phase. Table 2 summarises our findings.

Table 2. Funded pension programmes restricting payout product choice

Source: Austria: FP (2013), VVÖ (2013), BMSVG (2010), Uniqua (2013); France: CGI (2013), FFSA (2013); Germany: FRG (2013); Italy: Pensplan (2012); Sweden: SPA (2012); Switzerland: SE (2013); UK: TPR (2013), TPAS (2013), HMRC (2013).

In the European countries surveyed, funded pension programmes predominantly require at least some form of annuitisation. The bulk of existing funded programmes, in terms of accumulated assets, are of the defined benefit variety, which implies a pooled payout solution at retirement. At the same time, most European defined contribution programmes are still at the beginning of the saving phase, and they have not yet accumulated as much assets as the older defined benefit programmes. Moreover, some defined contribution programmes also require pooled payout solutions at retirement, such as PERP in France, Riester plans in Germany, or the Pensionskasse in Austria. Thus, traditional pooled products, particularly fixed nominal annuities, remain the predominant payout solution, depriving retirees of financial flexibility but giving them guaranteed lifelong retirement income. Among the few programmes that allow unrestricted use of alternative payout solutions are PERCO in France, individual pension accounts in Sweden, and pillar 3a restricted accounts in Switzerland, all of which are still relatively small.

We also find that regulation for old-age saving programmes in Europe is quite complex. Even within a single country, regulations regarding the use of accumulated assets in retirement typically vary between different schemes. The only exceptions are the UK and occupational schemes in Italy, where one set of regulations applies to all tax-supported funded pension payout schemes, independent of the origin of funds. In both countries, however, this simplified regulation only applies to new pension schemes. To date, the US is the only country among those surveyed that does not impose restrictions on the choice of payout instruments, leaving retirees with a lot of freedom and flexibility regarding the use retirement funds. Recently, however, a political debate emerged over mandating at least partial annuitisation, driven by the low voluntary annuity take-up.

Restrictions on the use of capital in retirement can be imposed in two ways. Either regulators rely on outright restrictions, directly prescribing the use of funds at retirement, or they employ implicit restrictions, e.g., tax penalties as well as legal or regulatory uncertainties, as a means to channel the demand for payout products into the desired direction. The majority of countries surveyed use outright restrictions, mostly mandating the purchase of traditional pooled products (annuitisation) in retirement. Restrictions employed in the surveyed countries can be classified as outlined in Figure 1Footnote 4.

Source: Authors’ compilation based on the sources referred to in Table 2.

Figure 1. Classification of payout product choice restrictions.

Several pension schemes mandate full annuitisation of accumulated funds directly at retirement (Box 1 in Row 1). Among those programmes are the Austrian Pensionskasse, several French programmes (Article 83, Article 39, Madelin-Law, and PERP), as well as German Rürup plans. Some countries impose less strict annuitisation requirements (Boxes 2 and 3 in Row 1): Immediate partial annuitisation is mandated in Swiss occupational saving plans as well as under the new regulations for funded pension programmes in Italy. Partial annuitisation of funds may not be required immediately, but may be tied to reaching a certain age, such as age 85 in case of the German Riester programme. Annuity-tied alternative payout solutions are available in Sweden for the funded part of the statutory pension system and in the UK for all tax-supported funded pension plans (Box 1 in Row 2). Here, the maximum periodic payout for a non-pooled solution is determined by the amount the retiree would have received, had he converted the savings into annuity.

An alternative approach to restricting payout product choice in retirement is to explicitly and deliberately discourage using non-pooled solutions through taxation (Box 2 in Row 2). The Austrian Prämienbegünstigte Zukunftsvorsorge and Mitarbeitervorsorgekasse are good examples for this approach. Alternative payout solutions, particularly lump sum payments, are not prohibited per se, but they are subject to taxation, while annuity payments are largely tax-free. Only very high annuity payments from the abovementioned programmes are subject to partial taxation. Additionally, when alternative payout solutions are chosen for Prämienbegünstigte Zukunftsvorsorge, 50% of direct state subsidies received during the saving phase must be returned to the state.

A final approach to restricting product choice is more subtle (Box 3 in Row 2). While not explicitly prohibiting non-pooled solutions, several countries do not explicitly allow them either. The lack of regulatory information on the status of non-pooled products prevents potential retirees from demanding them and, as a result, they are not offered. The German Pensionskasse is a good example. Current legislation does not require complete and outright annuitisation of funds saved within the Pensionskasse. Yet, almost all of the nearly 160 Pensionskassen require outright annuitisation, and only a small number allow partial lump sum payments at retirement. Only recently, some Pensionskassen have begun to offer Riester plans, which by law allow a one-time lump sum payment of up to 30% of accumulated funds. Similarly, there is no official definition of permissible withdrawal products in Austria and Switzerland. In the absence of explicit restrictions or permissions, traditional thinking seems to limit product choice at least in the saving phase. While savers are free to choose between insurance and bank products in the tax-supported third pillar of the Swiss old-age saving system (pillar 3a savings), insurance assets are four times larger than those in the non-pooled, restricted old-age accountsFootnote 5. The latter, however, do not offer standardised drawdown products and are mostly paid out as a lump sum.

4 Dynamic portfolio choice in retirement under regulatory restrictions

4.1 Motivation and research design

Regulation of payout products has its merits, but it also comes at a price. Rules have to be defined, implemented, and supervised, resulting in additional fees and duties. While these costs are measurable, the bulk of regulation costs are not directly observable. This particularly includes the utility losses suffered by those prevented from purchasing the desired payout products and thereby from structuring retirement cash flows in accordance with their preferences. Hence, in order to balance advantages and costs of regulation, it is vital to develop a framework that helps quantifying the utility impacts of product choice restrictions.

To this end, we implement a dynamic portfolio choice model and derive optimal consumption and investment patterns for a risk-averse male retiree that faces uncertain lifetime and stochastic capital market returnsFootnote 6. The retiree is endowed with a certain level of savings, accumulated during the active working life (pre-existing wealth), and an exogenous pension income in form of life-long, inflation adjusted fixed annuity benefits. This pre-existing pension income may be drawn from the statutory pension system, other social security arrangements, or from occupational pension systems of the defined benefit variety. This income is assumed to be at least equal or above the subsistence level. At the beginning of every year, the retiree has to decide how much to consume and how to invest his liquid wealth into risky stocks, risk-free bonds, and new illiquid fixed-payout life annuities in order to maximise his (expected) utility.

We first derive optimal policies in an unrestricted world, in order to have a benchmark against which we can evaluate the utility implications of preventing the retiree from following the optimal strategy by mandating annuitisation. Then, we quantify the utility losses from restricting product choice in retirement by integrating the three stylised restrictions defined in the previous section, i.e., immediate full annuitisation at retirement, immediate partial annuitisation at retirement, and deferred annuitisation. Finally, we look at the impact of mandating annuitisation on individuals that, for behavioural reasons, exclude annuities from their investment menu.

4.2 The model

Following Horneff et al. (Reference Horneff, Maurer, Mitchell and Dus2008a), we assume that the retiree maximises expected utility drawn from consumption and bequest, based on a recursively defined, additively time-separable utility function of the constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) type:

(1)$$V_{t} \equals {{\lpar C_{t} \rpar ^{\setnum{1} \minus \rho } } \over {1 \minus \rho }} \plus \beta \cdot E_{t} \left[ {p_{t}^{s} \cdot V_{t \plus \setnum{1}} \plus \lpar 1 \minus p_{t}^{s} \rpar \cdot k \cdot {{\lpar B_{t \plus \setnum{1}} \rpar ^{\setnum{1} \minus \rho } } \over {1 \minus \rho }}} \right]\comma $$

with terminal utility

(2)$$V_{T} \equals {{\lpar C_{T} \rpar ^{\setnum{1} \minus \rho } } \over {1 \minus \rho }} \plus \beta \cdot E_{T} \left[ {k \cdot {{\lpar B_{T \plus \setnum{1}} \rpar ^{\setnum{1} \minus \rho } } \over {1 \minus \rho }}} \right].$$

Here, Ct denotes the consumption level at time t, subject to being alive at that point in time. Bt represents the remaining financial wealth to be bequeathed, in case the retiree dies at time t. The retiree's subjective probability of surviving from t to t+1 is represented by pts and calibrated to the German population male mortality table (2004/2006). The curtailed lifetime T is set to age 100, i.e., p 100s=0;. The parameter ρ represents the coefficient of relative risk aversion that also reflects the retiree's willingness to engage in intertemporal substitution of consumption. We set ρ to 5, a standard value in the life-cycle literature representing a retiree with moderate risk aversion (see, for example, Horneff et al., Reference Horneff, Maurer, Mitchell and Dus2008a). The parameter β, which we set to 0.96, reflects the retiree's time preference and k the strength of his bequest motive. For k>0, the retiree has a bequest motive and will always keep some liquid wealth. For our analysis of investors with bequest motive, we set k to a moderate level of 2, which is comparable with calibrations in Cocco et al. (Reference Cocco, Gomes and Maenhout2005) .

Each year, the retiree has to decide how to distribute current cash on hand Wt to consumption Ct, financial wealth St, i.e., stock and bond investments, and the purchase of additional inflation-indexed life annuities At. Hence, the budget constraint at time t is given by:

(3)$$W_{t} \equals S_{t} \plus A_{t} \plus C_{t} \comma $$

resulting in next period's cash on hand of:

(4)$$W_{t \plus \setnum{1}} \equals S_{t} \cdot \lpar R_{f} \plus \pi _{t} \cdot \lpar R_{t \plus \setnum{1}} \minus R_{f} \rpar \rpar \plus L_{t \plus \setnum{1}} \plus Y\comma $$

where πt denotes the fraction of financial wealth invested in risky stocks, Rf denotes the real bond growth rate, and Rt +1 the risky stock return. The annual income from all previously purchased annuities is Lt +1, and Yt=Y represents the constant real lifelong annual pension income. If the retiree perishes at t+1, pension and annuity payments cease, and the remaining estate is given by Bt +1=St·(Rf+πt·(Rt +1Rf)). Moreover, the retiree is prevented from borrowing against future pension income and annuity payouts, as well as from short-selling stocks, bonds, or annuities.

In our base case, we set the annual real return on the risk free asset to 2%. Furthermore, we assume that the annual real return on stocks is i.i.d. log-normally distributed with an expected return of 8% and a volatility of 25%. To study the sensitivity of our results with respect to the capital market calibration, we also use a more pessimistic parameterisation in line with Gomes et al. (Reference Gomes, Kotlikoff and Viciera2008) . Here, the real annual risk-free return is set to 1%, the expected real return on stocks is reduced to 5%, and the volatility of stock returns is set to 20.5%.

In addition to stocks and bonds, the retiree has access to real fixed payout life annuities. Based on the actuarial principle of equivalence, at age x, the price of a payout annuity with fixed lifelong payments of Lt=1 is given by:

(5)$$A_{t} \equals \mathop{\sum}\limits_{t \equals \setnum{1}}^{T} {{{_{t}\,p_{x}^{a} } \over {\lpar R_{f} \rpar ^{t} }}.} $$

Here, $_{t} p_{x}^{a} \equals \prod _{i \equals \setnum{0}}^{t \minus \setnum{1}} p_{x \plus i}^{a} $ is the cumulative conditional probability for an individual aged x to survive until age x+t, according to the mortality table used by the insurer to price the annuity. These annuitants’ survival rates may differ from the subjective survival probability pts, reflecting adverse selection in the annuity markets (see Brugiavini, Reference Brugiavini1993). In our base case, we price annuities using survival probabilities from the German DAV 2004 R male annuitants’ mortality table with base year 2008. We incorporate the DAV's first-order mortality trend to account for future mortality improvements. Moreover, we do not curtail the lifetime to age 100 for pricing the annuity but calculate with a maximum age of 121, i.e., the final age in the DAV table. Consequently, annuity prices include substantial implied cost loadings; about 37% at age 65 when compared with prices calculated using the population table. To evaluate the impact of these loadings on our findings, we also conduct our analysis under the assumption that annuities are priced using the population mortality table.

To analyse the influence of the level of pre-existing pension income on the utility implications of product choice restrictions, we study three alternative levels of retirement wealth relative to the exogenous annual pension income. We set this financial wealth-to-pension income ratio (WPR) to 2, 5, and 10. Retirees with a WPR of 2 already have a high exposure to annuities compared with their other assets, for example due to a generous pre-existing pension, whereas those with a WPR of 10 only receive a comparably small pension income. For the 17 countries of the Euro area, Eurostat (2013) reports a median equivalised net income of € 15,758 for the population age 65 and older in 2011 (the last year available). Based on this pension income, our WPR calibrations lie within the range of the lower three quintiles of the total wealth distributions of retirement-aged European households (see Börsch-Supan et al., Reference Börsch-Supan, Brugiavini, Jürges, Mackenbach, Siegrist and Weber2005, Table 4A.5).

We solve the optimisation problem by backward induction through a three-dimensional state space {W, L, t}, as analytical solutions to this type of optimisation problem do not exist. Based on the optimal consumption and investment policies derived, we conduct an extensive Monte Carlo simulation of 10,000 independent life-cycles to evaluate how the retiree's consumption, investments in liquid assets, and annuity purchases are expected to evolve over time. For further details on the numerical solution technology, we refer the reader to Horneff et al. (Reference Horneff, Maurer, Mitchell and Stamos2010).

4.3 Optimal unrestricted investment and consumption strategies in retirement

We begin our quantitative evaluation of the utility implications of restricting product choice in retirement plans by analysing the optimal consumption and investment patterns for male investors that live in an unrestricted world. Figure 2 presents the expected evolution of key parameters as well as the expected asset allocation throughout the retirement phase for a retiree with a moderate wealth-to-pension ratio (WPR=5) and without bequest motives for our baseline calibration of capital market parameters. Panel A of Figure 2 illustrates expected consumption, pension and annuity income, annuity wealth, the amount of new annuity purchases, and liquid wealth in each year, starting at retirement age 65 and ending at age 100. All parameters are normalised by pre-existing annual pension income. Panel B of Figure 2 shows the corresponding expected allocation to stocks, bonds, and annuities over time, where the investment in annuities, i.e., the annuity wealth, is measured by the actuarial present value of previously purchased life annuity claims.

Source: Authors’ calculation.

Figure 2. Expected life-cycle profiles and asset allocation – no bequest motive. Notes: Male retiree age 65. Moderate wealth/pension ratio (WPR=5). No bequest motive (k=0). Expected stock (bond) returns: 8% (2%), return volatility stocks (bonds): 25% (0%). Mortality assumptions for annuity pricing: DAV 2004 R (year 2008) plus trend.

At retirement, the investor receives a pre-existing, external pension income of 1 and holds financial wealth of 5. At this point in time, he withdraws approximately 1.5 for consumption purposes, spending the entire income from pre-existing pensions as well as about 10% of financial wealth. The largest fraction of remaining wealth, approximately 4.25, or 92%, is invested in stocks. Bonds only account for about 8% of the retiree's wealth, while voluntary annuity purchases, and hence annuity wealth, are virtually zero. In subsequent periods, consumption, although slightly falling, remains well above periodic pension income, resulting in decreasing financial wealth. While the amount invested in risky stocks is slowly reduced, the retiree starts purchasing additional annuities from age 67 and continues to do so until the mid-80s. Consequently, the retiree's periodic income increases as does annuity wealth. By the mid-70s, annuities have completely crowded out the equally risk-less bonds due to the extra return generated through the mortality credit. At this point in time, the individual holds 84% of his total wealth in stocks and 16% in annuities. Annuity wealth reaches its maximum around age 80 and declines thereafter, as diminishing annuity purchases cannot overcompensate the reduction in present value, which is due to progressing payments and increasing mortality. With liquid financial wealth being exhausted by the mid-90s, the retiree is fully invested in annuities and can no longer afford consumption in excess of periodic income. Due to the purchase of additional annuities earlier in retirement, however, this periodic income, and therefore consumption, exceeds the initial pre-existing pension income for the rest of the retiree's lifetime.

This picture changes when the investor draws utility from leaving a bequest. Figure 3 again presents the expected evolution of key parameters as well as the expected asset allocation throughout the retirement phase for a retiree with a moderate wealth-to-pension ratio (WPR=5) and our baseline calibration of capital market parameters. This time, however, the retiree is assumed to have a moderate bequest motive of k=2.

Source: Authors’ calculation.

Figure 3. Expected life-cycle profile and asset allocation – moderate bequest motive. Notes: Male retiree aged 65. Moderate wealth/pension ratio (WPR=5). Moderate bequest motive (k=2). Expected stock (bond) returns: 8% (2%), return volatility stocks (bonds): 25% (0%). Mortality assumptions for annuity pricing: DAV 2004 R (year 2008) plus trend.

Early in retirement, pensioners with moderate bequest motives consume less and invest less in risky stocks than retirees that do not draw utility from leaving bequests. The initial asset allocation consists of 85% stocks and 15% bonds. Retirees with bequest motives are even more reluctant to voluntarily purchase additional annuities than their counterparts without any interest in bequests, as funds invested in annuities are irretrievably lost when the retiree dies. Annuity wealth only increases slowly and stagnates at about 10% of the retiree's remaining wealth from the mid-80s until age 100, despite the substantial mortality credits at later ages. As a result, periodic pension income only rises marginally, and the retiree primarily has to rely on bonds when investing risk-free. Even late in life, the retiree will hold a measurable fraction of his wealth in stocks. With annuities being undesirable due to a lack of bequest potential, only stocks will provide an expected return significantly above the risk-free bond return. Consequently, at age 100, the retiree will still hold 20% of wealth in stocks, 70% in bonds, and 10% in annuities.

Our results are structurally robust with respect to changes in mortality assumptions as well as transaction costs on annuities. Pricing annuities with population mortality tables, i.e., higher mortalities will result in slightly earlier and higher annuity purchases. Introducing a front-end expense load on annuities leads to slightly lower and later purchasesFootnote 7.

Summing up, we find that retirees with moderate WPRs postpone annuitisation and only gradually increase their annuity holdings. Even investors without a bequest motive will not be fully annuitised before the mid-90s. Instead, they use liquid wealth to finance both annuity purchases as well as consumption in excess of periodic income from pre-existing pensions and additionally purchased annuities.

4.4 Welfare implications of mandatory annuitisation

Using our analysis for retirees in an unrestricted world as a benchmark, we now study the utility impacts of mandating annuitisation. To this end, we evaluate three alternative regulatory frameworks that differ in the extent to which product choice in retirement is restricted. In Case A, we require the individual to fully annuitise available wealth at retirement age 65, which is in line with current regulations in, e.g., Austria, France, or Germany. For our less strict alternatives, we draw on simplified regulations from two other European countries. In Case B, we mandate immediate annuitisation of 50% of the initial wealth at age 65, imposing no further restrictions on the use of the remaining half of retirement funds. Hence, the retiree may subsequently withdraw funds for consumption purposes or for purchasing additional annuities at any time. Such a set-up is comparable with regulation in, e.g., Italy. In Case C, the retiree has to fully annuitise all remaining wealth at age 75. Prior to that, withdrawals are limited to the annual benefit of an immediate annuity purchased at the respective age. This is comparable with regulation in the UK prior to 2011 and in the spirit of German Riester programmes.

To evaluate the economic costs of these regimes, we conduct a welfare analysis similar to Mitchell et al. (Reference Mitchell, Poterba, Warshawsky and Brown1999) and Horneff et al. (Reference Horneff, Maurer, Mitchell and Stamos2009). For each of the three regulatory frameworks, we determine the expected utility for a given level of initial wealth. We then solve for the level of initial wealth in the unrestricted world that generates the same expected utility. This enables us to measure the utility loss in monetary units. Our findings are summarised in Table 3, which presents the utility impacts of alternative regulations as a percentage change in initial financial wealth relative to the unrestricted world for alternative bequest motive strengths, WPRs, and financial market parameterisations.

Table 3. Welfare implications of alternative product choice restrictions – Fully rational individual

Notes: Change in utility equivalent wealth due to product choice restrictions in per cent of the initial wealth. Case A: Full mandatory annuitisation at retirement. Case B: Mandatory annuitisation of 50% of wealth at retirement, no further restrictions of use of remaining 50%. Case C: Mandatory annuitisation of remaining retirement funds at age 75, prior to that, withdrawals limited to the annual benefit of immediate life annuity purchased at the respective age. Male retiree age 65. No bequest motive: k=0, moderate bequest motive: k=2. Base case capital market parameterisation: Expected stock (bond) return: 8% (2%), return volatility stocks (bonds): 25% (0%). Pessimistic capital market parameterisation: Expected stock (bond) return: 5% (1%), return volatility stocks (bonds): 20.5% (0%). Mortality assumptions for annuity pricing: Annuitant mortalities: DAV 2004 R (year 2008) plus trend. Population mortalities: Population mortality table for German males 2004/2006. Source: Authors’ calculation.

First, we turn our attention to Panel 1 of Table 3, which presents utility impacts of restricting product choice for our base case capital market calibration, when assuming that annuities are priced using annuitant mortality tables. Independent of the level of pre-existing pension income, all forms of mandated annuitisation result in substantial utility losses, especially for retirees with bequest motives. We find that these losses are particularly high for Case A, i.e., full immediate annuitisation. For example, a retiree with a moderate WPR of 5 and no bequest motive suffers a utility loss equivalent to 24.8% of initial wealth. Stated differently, an individual with an initial endowment of € 100,000 in the most restrictive world is equally well off as his identical twin brother in an unrestricted world who is only endowed with € 75,040 at retirement. For retirees with moderate bequest motives, this loss in wealth even increases to 54%. Retirees with lower WPR tend to suffer higher utility losses. These individuals already have a comparably high, inflexible, annuity-like pension income. Consequently, they appreciate the flexibility offered by liquid assets much more than the marginal increase in periodic pension income this small amount of liquid wealth is able to buy. Retirees with a high WPR, on the other hand, only have comparably little pre-existing pension income that can be measurably increased when the substantial endowment is used to purchase additional annuities. Hence, utility losses are slightly smaller than for those retirees with low WPR. Nonetheless, their reduction in utility equivalent wealth still amounts to almost 20% when they do not have a bequest motive and to more than 40% in case they are moderately inclined to leave a bequest.

Requiring individuals to only annuitise 50% of their wealth at retirement (Case B), considerably reduces utility losses across all WPR levels. For retirees without bequest motives, utility losses are cut by more than 60% for a WPR of 2 and by even more than 80% for a WPR of 10. In the presence of a moderate bequest motive and independent of the WPR, Case B results in the smallest utility reductions of all restricted cases, as the retiree at any point in time has the opportunity to retain some non-annuitised wealth for bequest purposes.

Now, we turn to our Case C, which mandates full annuitisation of remaining funds at age 75 and, prior to that, restricts the use of funds. While utility losses are generally lower than Case A, utility losses still exceed those of Case B, particularly for retirees with bequest motives. This comes as no surprise, since Case C imposes the same strict annuitisation requirements as Case A, just deferred by 10 years, during which the freedom of fund use is limited as well.

Next, we are interested in the sensitivity of our results with respect to the underlying assumptions concerning the parameterisation of capital and annuity markets. Panel 2 of Table 3 presents utility implications of restrictive regulations under the assumption that annuities are priced based on population mortalities instead of annuitant mortalities. Mandating annuitisation reduces adverse selection in the annuity market and enables providers to price annuities using less conservative mortality assumptions, resulting in higher annuity payments. This considerably reduces the welfare losses of mandatory annuitisation, usually by more than half for all analysed restriction types if the individual does not have a bequest motive. Yet, even in this environment, welfare losses from full immediate annuitisation as well as full annuitisation at age 75 are substantial in the presence of moderate bequest motives, ranging from 23% for high-wealth individuals in Case C to 47% for low-wealth retirees in Case A. Panel 3 of Table 3 presents the results for our more pessimistic capital market parameterisation and for annuity prices based on population mortality rates. Reducing expected returns on stocks and bonds makes holding liquid financial wealth less appealing. This increases the relative attractiveness of annuities, and utility losses of mandated early annuitisation are lower under pessimistic capital market assumptions than under the baseline calibration. Variations in capital market parameters, however, have substantially less impact on utility than changes in mortality assumptions.

So far, our analysis has solely focused on fully rational individuals, which were shown to suffer substantial welfare losses from mandatory annuitisation. Yet, the discussion in Section 2 showed that real-world individuals may refrain from voluntarily purchasing annuities for behavioural reasons, despite the well-understood benefits of annuitisation. This raises the question as to whether mandated annuitisation can actually be utility-increasing for those individuals and as to how the alternative regulatory regimes perform in such an environment. In what follows, we seek to tackle this question within our rational decision making framework. To this end, we repeat our welfare analysis positing that the individual excludes annuities from the investment menu for behavioural reasons, but is fully rational otherwise. Consequently, in all cases A–C, annuities are only purchased to the extent required by our stylised regulation, and welfare is then benchmarked against an unrestricted world without annuitisation. Results are summarised in Table 4.

Table 4. Welfare implications of alternative product choice restrictions – behaviourally restricted individual

Notes: Change in utility equivalent wealth due to product choice restrictions in per cent of the initial wealth. Case A: Full mandatory annuitisation at retirement. Case B: Mandatory annuitisation of 50% of wealth at retirement, no further restrictions of use of remaining 50%. Case C: Mandatory annuitisation of remaining retirement funds at age 75, prior to that, withdrawals limited to the annual benefit of immediate life annuity purchased at the respective age. Male retiree age 65. No bequest motive: k=0, moderate bequest motive: k=2. Base case capital market parameterisation: Expected stock (bond) return: 8% (2%), return volatility stocks (bonds): 25% (0%). Pessimistic capital market parameterisation: Expected stock (bond) return: 5% (1%), return volatility stocks (bonds): 20.5% (0%). Mortality assumptions for annuity pricing: Annuitant mortalities: DAV 2004 R (year 2008) plus trend. Population mortalities: Population mortality table for German males 2004/2006. Source: Authors’ calculation.

In Panel 1 of Table 4, annuities are again priced using annuitant mortality tables. In this scenario, welfare losses are almost equal to those presented in Table 3 for individuals that include annuities in their investment menu. The differences only range between 0 and 2 percentage points. The reason for this can be seen when again looking at Figures 2 and 3. Due to high annuity prices, even fully rational investors will purchase only a small amount of annuities and only later in life. Hence, there is little difference to an individual that does not purchase any annuities.

This picture changes when assuming that annuities are priced using population mortality tables (Panels 2 and 3 of Table 4). Welfare losses for behaviourally restricted individuals with low wealth (WPR=2) are still comparable with those of their fully rational counterparts. With increasing WPRs, however, the utility impact of mandated annuitisation strongly depends on the type of restriction and on whether the individual is willing to leave a bequest. Those with a bequest motive and with higher WPRs still suffer substantial welfare losses ranging between 14 and 37% under full immediate and deferred annuitisation (Cases A and C). With mandated immediate annuitisation of only 50% (Case B), however, individuals in fact benefit from regulation, with welfare gains reaching 10% for a WPR of 10. Wealthier individuals without a bequest motive enjoy welfare gains under all regulatory regimes. Yet, Case B again generates the highest benefits for most scenarios. Here, welfare gains range from 5% for the baseline parameterisation to around 14% in the more pessimistic capital market scenario. Full immediate mandatory annuitisation (Case A) will only be preferred if individuals are very wealthy (WPR=10) and returns in the capital market are low.

Overall, we can conclude that mandated annuitisation may be beneficial for those that exclude annuities from their investment menu. Yet, as in the case of fully rational individuals, utility implications strongly depend on the type of regulation. Here, our results suggest that, in most cases, fully rational as well as behaviourally restricted individuals have similar preferences regarding the extent to which annuitisation is mandated.

5 Conclusions

In Europe, the majority of funded old-age provision schemes that enjoy statutory support during the saving phase include restrictions on the use of accumulated monies in retirement. Typically, these restrictions take the form of mandatory annuitisation of retirement funds. Looking at seven European countries and the USA, this paper surveys and classifies the types of regulatory rules that limit product choice in the payout phase of funded private and occupational pension programmes.

Subsequently, we integrate stylised payout regulations into a dynamic life-cycle consumption and portfolio choice model and study their impact on the welfare of fully rational individuals as well as of individuals that exclude annuities from their investment universe for behavioural reasons. In line with prior studies, we find that fully rational individuals will only gradually annuitise retirement funds, even in the absence of bequest motives. Liquid wealth will be held at least until around age 90 and mostly in equities. Consequently, mandating investors to fully annuitise at retirement substantially reduces individuals’ wellbeing. Wealth-poor individuals without bequest motives may lose up to 25% in utility-equivalent wealth when being required to fully annuitise at retirement. Softening strict annuitisation requirements, however, results in considerable reductions in utility losses. Behaviourally restricted individuals, on the other hand, may actually benefit from being required to annuitise their retirement funds. Wealth-rich individuals may gain up to 15% in utility-equivalent wealth when being required to buy cheap annuities. But even those individuals will generally prefer less-strict annuitisation requirements.

Central parameters driving the welfare implications of mandated annuitisation are the level of accumulated retirement wealth in relation to pre-existing retirement income as well as the annuity prices. The lower the individual's accumulated retirement wealth the higher the utility losses that result from strict annuitisation rules. This is particularly pronounced in the case of behaviourally restricted individuals, where those with high wealth enjoy substantial welfare increases while those with little wealth in fact suffer measurable welfare losses. This highlights the necessity for regulation to account for the individual's economic circumstances instead of imposing undifferentiated rules for all retirees. With respect to the second factor influencing welfare outcomes, mandated annuitisation has to be discussed in light of the actuarial assumptions underlying the annuity prices. If these are based on highly conservative annuitant mortality tables, welfare losses will be substantial. Yet, if mandated annuitisation reduces adverse selection in the annuity markets and if insurers are able and willing to pass the resulting gains on to the annuitants, welfare outcomes of mandated annuitisation will be much more favourable.

Our findings have implications for both policymakers as well as suppliers of retirement payout products. Policymakers should be aware of the potentially substantial burden they impose on investors and, therefore, should strive to achieve their legitimate regulatory goals at the lowest possible utility cost. On the other hand, it is more than unlikely that average individuals will be able to self-reliantly derive and implement optimal annuitisation and withdrawal policies. Consequently, financial institutions are called on to develop cost-efficient, standardised retirement products, which provide dynamic access to both annuities and liquid investments, while accounting for central characteristics of the targeted retiree group.

Footnotes

1 See Johnson et al. (Reference Johnson, Burman and Kobes2004) for evidence from the HRS, Schaus (Reference Schaus2005) for a survey of annuity intake in 450 large 401(k) plans, Boardman (Reference Boardman2006) for a comparison between the UK and US annuity markets, and Inkmann et al. (Reference Inkman, Lopes and Michaelides2011) for the voluntary annuity market in the UK.

2 Following the classification developed by the OECD (2005), we refer to private pension programmes as those administered by an institution other than the government; these may be personal or employment-linked. In contrast to employment-linked (occupational) programmes, access to personal pension programmes does not have to be linked to an employment relationship.

3 OECD (2005).

4 Maurer and Somova (Reference Maurer and Somova2009).

5 Schweizerische Nationalbank (2007, pp. 31, 73); Schweizerischer Versicherungsverband (2007, pp. 12–14).

6 We do not account for consumption shocks, e.g., resulting from uncertain medical or nursing expenses. This can be justified by the relatively high level of medical insurance coverage, especially in continental Europe. In addition, we do not analyse the interaction between the accumulation and decumulation phase.

7 Detailed results are available from the authors on request.

References

Agnew, J. R., Anderson, L. R., Gerlach, J. R. and Szykman, L. R. (2008) Who chooses annuities? An experimental investigation of the role of gender, framing, and defaults. American Economic Review, 98(2): 418422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ameriks, J., Caplin, A., Laufer, S. and Van Nieuwerburgh, S. (2011) The joy of giving or assisted living? Using strategic surveys to separate bequest and precautionary motives. Journal of Finance, 66(2): 519561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
BaFin (Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht) (2011) Jahresbericht 2011, Statistischer Teil. Table 700. Available online at http://www.bafin.de/SharedDocs/Standardartikel/DE/st_va_erstvu.html, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
BaFin (Bundesanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht) (2012) Jahresbericht 2012, p. 97. Table 6. Available online at http://www.bafin.de/SharedDocs/Downloads/DE/Jahresbericht/dl_jb_2012.html, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Bateman, H. and Thorp, S. (2008) Choices and constraints over retirement income streams: comparing rules and regulations. Economic Record, 84 (Special Issue September): 1731.Google Scholar
Behaghel, L. and Blau, D. M. (2012) Framing social security reform: behavioral responses to changes in the full retirement age. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4(4): 4167.Google Scholar
Benartzi, S., Previtero, A. and Thaler, R. H. (2011) Annuitization puzzles. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(4): 143164.Google Scholar
Bernheim, D. B. (1991) How strong are bequest motives? Evidence based on estimates of the demand for life insurance and annuities. Journal of Political Economy, 99(5): 899927.Google Scholar
BFS (Bundesamt für Statistik Schweiz) (2011) Überblick über die berufliche Vosorge 2004–2011, Table 2011 A 01 1 Z. Available online at http://www.bfs.admin.ch/bfs/portal/de/index/themen/13/02/03/data/01.html#parsys_29182, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
BMSVG (Betriebliches Mitarbeiter- und Selbständigenvorsorgegesetz) (2010) Available online at http://www.ris.bka.gv.at, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Boardman, T. (2006) Annuitization lessons from the UK: money-back annuities and other developments. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 73(4): 633646.Google Scholar
Börsch-Supan, A., Brugiavini, A., Jürges, H., Mackenbach, J., Siegrist, J. and Weber, G. (eds) ( 2005) Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe – First Results from the Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe. Mannheim: Mannheim Research Institute for the Economics of Aging (MEA).Google Scholar
Brown, J., Kling, J., Mullainathan, S. and Wrobel, M. (2008) Why don't people insure Late-Life consumption? A framing explanation of the Under-Annuitization puzzle. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 98(2): 304309.Google Scholar
Brown, J., Kapteyn, A., Luttmer, E.F.P. and Mitchell, O. S. (2011) Do consumers know how to value annuities? Complexity as a Barrier to Annuitization. Financial Literacy Center Working Paper, WR-924-SSA, September 2011.Google Scholar
Brown, J., Kapteyn, A. and Mitchell, O. S. (2013) Framing and claiming: how information-framing affects expected social security claiming behavior. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 9999: 124.Google Scholar
Brown, J. R. and Poterba, J. M. (2000) Joint life annuities and annuity demand by married couples. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 67(4): 527553.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brugiavini, A. (1993) Uncertainty resolution and the timing of annuity purchases. Journal of Public Economics, 50(1): 3162.Google Scholar
Bütler, M. and Teppa, F. (2007) The choice between an annuity and a lump sum: results from Swiss pension funds. Journal of Public Economics, 91(10): 19441966.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cocco, J., Gomes, F. and Maenhout, P. (2005) Consumption and portfolio choice over the life-cycle. Review of Financial Studies, 18(2): 491533.Google Scholar
Covip (Commissione di Vigilanza sui Fondi Pensione) (2012) RELAZIONE PER L'ANNO 2012, p. 91, 111,130. Tables 4.1, 5.1, 6.1. Available online at http://www.covip.it/wp-content/uploads/Relazione-Annuale-2012.pdf, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Davidoff, T., Brown, J. and Diamond, P. (2005) Annuities and individual welfare. American Economic Review, 95(5): 15731590.Google Scholar
DOL (U.S. Department of Labor, Employee Benefits Security Administration) (2012) Private Pension Plan Bulletin; Historical Tables and Graphs, (2010 Data Release Version 1.0), p. 25. (401k Plan assets). Available online at http://www.dol.gov/ebsa/pdf/historicaltables.pdf, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Dus, I. and Maurer, R. (2009) Zur Eigenmittelunterlegung von Leistungszusagen in der Auszahlphase bei investmentfondsbasierten Altersvorsorgeverträgen: Ein Gestaltungsvorschlag. Kredit und Kapital, 42(2): 277312.Google Scholar
Dus, I., Maurer, R. and Mitchell, O. S. (2005) Betting on death and capital markets in retirement: a shortfall risk analysis of life annuities versus phased withdrawal plans. Financial Services Review, 14(3): 169196.Google Scholar
Dushi, I. and Webb, A. (2004) Household annuitization decisions: simulations and empirical analyses. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance, 3(2): 109–43.Google Scholar
Eurostat (ed.) (2013) Statistical Database. Available online at http://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/submitViewTableAction.do, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
FFSA (Fédération française des sociétés d'assurances) (2011) Assurance de personnes – Données clés 2011, pp. 3334. Available online at http://www.ffs, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
FFSA (Fédération française des sociétés d'assurances) (2013) Les contrats d'assurance retraite en 2011: progression des contrats de particuliers. Available online at http://www.ffsa.fr/sites/jcms/p1_900752/fr/les-contrats-dassurance-retraite-en-2011-progression-des-contrats-de-particuliers?cc=fn_7351, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Finkelstein, A. and Poterba, J. M. (2004) Adverse selection in insurance markets: policyholder evidence from the U.K. annuity market. Journal of Political Economy, 112(1): 183208.Google Scholar
FMA (Österreichische Finanzmarktaufsicht) (2012) Der Markt für die prämienbegünstigte Zukunftsvorsorge 2011, Stand 5. Oktober 2012, p. 9. Available online at https://www.fma.gv.at/typo3conf/ext/dam_download/secure.php?u=0&file=8320&t=1353164960&hash=a95f216e3089102dc82167ca96a01861, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
FP (Fachverband Pensionskassen) (2013) Regelungen für Leistungsberechtigte. Available online at http://portal.wko.at/wk/format_detail.wk?angid=1&stid=192510&dstid=293&opennavid=35450, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
FRG (Federal Republic of Germany) (2013) Gesetz zur Verbesserung der Betrieblichen Altersversorgung (1974, last modified 2008), Gesetz über die Zertifizierung von Altersvorsorgeverträgen (2001, last modified 2010), Einkommenssteuergesetz – (1934, last modified 2013), Gesetz zur Reform der gesetzlichen Rentenversicherung und zur Förderung eines kalpitalgedecken Altersvorsorgevermögens/Altersvermögensgesetz (2001), Gesetz zur Neuordnung der einkommenssteuerrechtlichen Behandlung von Altersvorsorgeaufwendungen/Alterseinkünftegesetz (2005). Available online at http://www.gesetze-im-internet.de (service of the Federal Ministry of Justice), accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Friedman, B. M. and Warshawsky, M. J. (1990) The cost of annuities: implications for saving behavior and bequests bequests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(1): 135154.Google Scholar
GDV (Gesamtverband der Deutschen Versicherungswirtschaft e. V.) (2012) Lebensversicherung in Zahlen 2012, p. 16. Available online at http://www.gdv.de/category/downloads/zahlen-fakten/lebensversicherung-in-zahlen/, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Gomes, F. J., Kotlikoff, L. J. and Viciera, L. M. (2008) Optimal life-cycle investing with flexible labor supply: a welfare analysis of life-cycle funds. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 98: 297303.Google Scholar
HMRC (HM Revenues and Customs) (2013) Registered Pension Schemes Manual, Technical Pages. Available online at http://www.hmrc.gov.uk/manuals/rpsmmanual/RPSM00100000.htm, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Horneff, W., Maurer, R., Mitchell, O. S. and Dus, I. (2008a) Following the rules: integrating asset allocation and annuitisation in retirement portfolios. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 42: 396408.Google Scholar
Horneff, W., Maurer, R. and Stamos, M. (2008b) Optimal gradual annuitization: quantifying the costs of switching to annuities. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 75: 10191038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horneff, W., Maurer, R., Mitchell, O. S. and Stamos, M. (2009) Asset Allocation and Location over the Life Cycle with Survival-Contingent Payouts. Journal of Banking and Finance, 33: 16881699.Google Scholar
Horneff, W., Maurer, R., Mitchell, O. S. and Stamos, M. (2010) Variable payout annuities and dynamic portfolio choice in retirement. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance, 9: 163183.Google Scholar
Hu, W. Y. and Scott, J. S. (2007) Behavioral obstacles in the annuity market. Financial Analysts Journal, 63: 7182.Google Scholar
Hubener, A., Maurer, R. and Rogalla, R. (2013) Optimal Portfolio Choice with Annuities and Life Insurance for Retired Couples. Forthcoming in Review of Finance.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hülsmann, J., Schmid, J. and Schöll, S. (2001) Rentenreform in sechs westeuropäischen Ländern – Ein Blick über den Tellerrand, WIP – Occasional Papers Nr. 15-2001.Google Scholar
ICI (Investment Company Institute) (2013) Report: Quarterly Retirement Market Data, First Quarter 2013. Available online at http://www.ici.org/search, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Inkman, J., Lopes, P. and Michaelides, A. (2011) How deep is the annuity market participation puzzle? Review of Financial Studies, 24: 279319.Google Scholar
James, E. and Song, X. (2001) Annuities markets around the world: Money's worth and risk intermediation. SSRN Working Paper. Available online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=287375Google Scholar
Johnson, R. W., Burman, L. E. and Kobes, D. I. (2004) Annuitized wealth at older ages: evidence from the Health and Retirement Study, Final Report to the Employee Benefits Security Administration. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Labor.Google Scholar
Kotlikoff, L. J. and Spivak, A. (1981) The family as an incomplete annuities market. Journal of Political Economy, 89: 372391.Google Scholar
Lockwood, L. (2012) Bequest motives and the annuity puzzle. Review of Economic Dynamics, 15: 226243.Google Scholar
Maurer, R. and Somova, B. (2009) Rethinking retirement income strategies – how can we secure better outcomes for future retirees? Brussels: EFAMA Publication Series.Google Scholar
Maurer, R., Mitchell, O. S., Rogalla, R. and Kartashov, V. (2013) Life-cycle portfolio choice with systematic longevity risk and variable Investment-linked deferred annuities. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 80: 649676.Google Scholar
Milevsky, M. (2002) Optimal annuitization policies: analysis of the options. North American Actuarial Journal, 5: 5769.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milevsky, M. and Young, V. (2007) The timing of annuitization: investment dominance and mortality risk. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 40: 135144.Google Scholar
Mitchell, O. S., Poterba, J. M., Warshawsky, M. J. and Brown, J. R. (1999) New evidence on the money's worth of individual annuities. American Economic Review, 89: 12991318.Google Scholar
OECD (ed.) (2005) Pensions at glance. Paris.Google Scholar
OECD (ed.) (2009) OECD recommendation on core principles of occupational pension regulation. Status per 5th June 2009. Available online at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/14/46/33619987.pdf, accessed in September 2013.Google Scholar
OECD (2012) Pension Statistics. Available online at http://stats.oecd.org/BrandedView.aspx?oecd_bv_id=pension-data-en&doi=data-00517-en, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
OECD (2013) OECD Economic Outlook No. 93 (database). Available online at http://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?queryid=48126, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
ÖNB (Österreichische Nationalbank) (2013a) Statistiken: Pensionskassen-Vermögensbestand. Status per 22nd May 2013. Available online at http://www.oenb.at/isaweb/report.do?lang=DE&report=3.16, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
ÖNB (Österreichische Nationalbank) (2013b) Statistiken: Betriebliche Vorsorgekassen. Status per 22nd May 2013. Available online at http://www.oenb.at/isaweb/report.do?report=3.13.2, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
ONS (Office for National Statistics UK) (2013) Pension Trends – Chapter 9: Pension Scheme Funding and Investment, 2013 Edition, p. 1. Available online at http://www.ons.gov.uk/ons/rel/pensions/pension-trends/chapter-9-pension-scheme-funding-and-investment-2013-edition/art-pt-chapter-9-2013.html, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Palme, M. and Svensson, I. (1999) Social security, occupational pensions, and retirement in Sweden. In Gruber, J. and Wise, D. A. (eds), Social Security and Retirement Around the World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 355402.Google Scholar
Peijnenburg, K., Nijman, T. and Werker, B. (2010a) Optimal Annuitization with Incomplete Annuity Markets and Background Risk during Retirement. Netspar Discussion Paper. Available online at http://arno.uvt.nl/show.cgi?fid=121433Google Scholar
Peijnenburg, K., Nijman, T. and Werker, B. (2010b) Health Cost Risk and Optimal Retirement Provision: A Simple Rule for Annuity Demand, Pension Research Council Working Paper No. WPS 2010-08. Available online at http://www.pensionresearchcouncil.org/publications/document.php?file=879CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pensplan (Pensplan Centrum AG) (2012) Ratgeber der Zusatzvorsorge. Available online at http://www.pensplan.com/media/BrochurePensplan_de.pdf, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Queisser, M. and Vittas, D. (2000) The Swiss multi-pillar pension system: triumph of common sense? World Bank Development Research Group (Ed.), Working Paper Series, August 2000.Google Scholar
Read, D., Löwenstein, G. and Rabin, M. (1999) Choice bracketing. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19: 171197.Google Scholar
Schaus, S. L. (2005) Annuities make a comeback. Journal of Pension Benefits, 12: 3438.Google Scholar
Schreiber, P. and Weber, M. (2013) Time inconsistent preferences and the annuitization decision. SSRN Working Paper. Available online at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2217701Google Scholar
Schweizerische Nationalbank (ed.) (2007) Bankenstatistisches Monatsheft Juli 2007, Zürich.Google Scholar
Schweizerische Nationalbank (2013) Monatsheft Mai 2013, p. 77. Available online at http://www.snb.ch/de/mmr/reference/bankenstat_monatsheft_2013_05/source/bankenstat_monatsheft_2013_05.de.pdf, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Schweizerischer Versicherungsverband (2007) Zahlen und Fakten 2007. Zürich.Google Scholar
Schwind, J. (2013) Die Deckungsmittel der betrieblichen Altersversorgung, in: Betriebliche Altersversorgung 4. 346. Available online at http://www.aba-online.de/deckungsmittel-der-bav.html, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
SE (Schweizerische Eidgenossenschaft) (2013) Bundesgesetz über die berufliche Alters-, Hinterlassenen- und Invalidenvorsorge (Stand 1. Januar 2013). Available online at http://www.admin.ch/opc/de/classified-compilation/19820152/index.html,Art.37, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
SPA (Swedish Pension Agency) (2012) Annual Report of the Swedish Pension System (Orange Report) 2012. Available online at http://www.pensionsmyndigheten.se/, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Statistics Sweden (2013) Finansräkenskaperförstakvartalet 2013, p. 34. Table 6. Available online at http://www.scb.se/Statistik/FM/FM0103/2013K01/FM0103_2013K01_SM_FM17SM1302.pdf, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
SVV (Schweizerischer Versicherungsverband) (2009) Zahlen und Fakten: Lebensversicherungsgeschäft Schweiz. Available online at http://www.svv.ch/de/publikationen/archiv-zahlen-und-fakten, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
TPAS (The Pensions Advisory Service UK) (2013) Taking payments from your pension pot. Available online at http://www.pensionsadvisoryservice.org.uk/taking-payments-from-your-pension-pot, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
TPR (The Pensions Regulator UK) (2013) Glossary. Available online at http://www.thepensionsregulator.gov.uk/Glossary.aspx#s1327, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Uniqua (2013) UNIQA Mitarbeitervorsorge – Betriebliche Vorsorgekasse. Available online at http://www.uniqa.at/uniqaat/cms/geschaeftskunden/betrieblichealtersvorsorge/Selbstaendigenvorsorge.xhtml, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
VVÖ (Versicherungsverband Österreich) (2013) Prämienbegünstigte Zukunftsvorsorge. Available online at http://www.vvo.at/pramienbegunstigte-zukunftsvorsorge-4.html, accessed in July 2013.Google Scholar
Yaari, M. (1965) Uncertain lifetime, life insurance and the theory of the consumer. Review of Economic Studies, 32: 137150.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Overview of representative funded pensions programmes

Figure 1

Table 2. Funded pension programmes restricting payout product choice

Figure 2

Figure 1. Classification of payout product choice restrictions.

Source: Authors’ compilation based on the sources referred to in Table 2.
Figure 3

Figure 2. Expected life-cycle profiles and asset allocation – no bequest motive. Notes: Male retiree age 65. Moderate wealth/pension ratio (WPR=5). No bequest motive (k=0). Expected stock (bond) returns: 8% (2%), return volatility stocks (bonds): 25% (0%). Mortality assumptions for annuity pricing: DAV 2004 R (year 2008) plus trend.

Source: Authors’ calculation.
Figure 4

Figure 3. Expected life-cycle profile and asset allocation – moderate bequest motive. Notes: Male retiree aged 65. Moderate wealth/pension ratio (WPR=5). Moderate bequest motive (k=2). Expected stock (bond) returns: 8% (2%), return volatility stocks (bonds): 25% (0%). Mortality assumptions for annuity pricing: DAV 2004 R (year 2008) plus trend.

Source: Authors’ calculation.
Figure 5

Table 3. Welfare implications of alternative product choice restrictions – Fully rational individual

Figure 6

Table 4. Welfare implications of alternative product choice restrictions – behaviourally restricted individual