1. Introduction
Over the past few decades, the traditional defined benefit (DB) pension plan has been gradually losing its dominance in private sector pension systems in many countries and the defined contribution (DC) pension plan has become increasingly popular (OECD, 2016). Under the DC pension scheme, members contribute towards their personal pension savings in a way that enables them to make decisions on how to invest during the accumulation stage and how to decumulate during retirement.
In the area of retirement, a constant focus is on whether retirees receive adequate protection against longevity risk, the risk of outliving one's wealth. As an insurance product that eliminates the longevity risk, a lifetime annuity is a good option for DC pensioners. A lifetime annuity provides a stream of income payments for as long as the annuitant is alive, in exchange for an upfront premium charge. Yaari (Reference Yaari1965) demonstrates that in a life-cycle model a risk-averse individual without a bequest motive should hold all their assets in annuities. However, empirical data have shown that retirees are reluctant to convert retirement savings into annuities. The disparity between the theoretical optimal choice and consumers’ actual preferences leads to the ‘annuity puzzle’. This can be illustrated by low levels of voluntary annuitisation in the UK market. In the past, the UK had two distinct annuity markets: a voluntary segment called the Purchased Life Annuity (PLA) market and a compulsory section called the Compulsory Purchase Annuity (CPA). Based on UK annuity sales figures for the 1994–2006, sales in the CPA market had been consistently higher than that in the PLA market. By 2010, the CPA market had grown to £11.5 billion worth of annuity premiums while the PLA market only had £72 million worth of sales (Cannon and Tonks, Reference Cannon and Tonks2011).
Recently, the UK government implemented pension reforms to encourage free choice of the mode of pension distribution and, as a result, retirees’ real preferences on annuity products could be clearly seen. The reform follows the international trend of greater pension flexibility, which has been observed in countries such as the USA, Australia and Switzerland. Prior to the 2014 UK reform, there were strict restrictions on accessing pension savings at retirement. For example, if a pensioner had overall pension savings of greater than £18,000 but could not access a guaranteed retirement income of more than £20,000 per year,Footnote 1 the only two choices that they could make were to either to buy an annuity or enrol in a ‘capped drawdown’, which allowed them to withdraw as much as 120% of an equivalent annuity each year during retirement. However, after the 2014 policy change, everyone is able to choose a lump sum (full withdrawal), an annuity or a drawdown, regardless of the size of their pension wealth (HM Treasury, 2014). With this move towards greater freedom of choice on how and when to access pension wealth, annuity sales have experienced a large decline. In Q2 2015, £990 m was invested in annuities, showing a 44% decrease from the £1.8 bn invested in Q2 2014. Moreover, 18,200 annuities had been purchased in the three months after the pension reform, showing a 61% decrease compared with Q2 2014 when 46,700 were purchased (ABI, 2015).
Many studies have suggested a number of reasons for the annuity puzzle, such as mortality risk-sharing among families (Brown and Poterba, Reference Brown and Poterba2000) and the existence of social security (Butler et al., Reference Butler, Peijnenburg and Staubli2017). Some research has examined the possible influences of behavioural factors such as the framing effect, cumulative prospect theory (CPT) and low level of financial literacy; the findings suggest that the low demand for annuity could be simply due to irrational behaviour (Cannon and Tonks, Reference Cannon and Tonks2008). In the next section, Literature review, we will provide a more detailed explanation of the reasons.
Since the annuity is a product that involves a series of payments at different points of time, one of the behavioural factors that affects decision making is the inconsistency of intertemporal choices. More specifically, when people assign values to future payouts, the discount rate used to evaluate intertemporal choice is not fixed, but varies in line with the length of the delay period, size and signs of the benefits. This effect is called hyperbolic discounting and is interpreted as ‘temporal myopia’. The concept has been widely used to account for behavioural bias in savings, nutrition, healthcare, drug addictions and other problems of willpower (Frederick et al., Reference Frederick, Loewenstein and O'donoghue2002). Laibson et al. (Reference Laibson, Repetto and Tobacman2003) have used the model to explain the puzzle of simultaneously having large credit card debts and pre-retirement savings.
In this paper, we use the hyperbolic discount model derived from experimental results to analyse annuitisation decisions. In Section 3, we provide a full explanation of the model and suggest how to apply the model in valuing annuities. In terms of the products considered, we are interested in both immediate annuities and deferred annuities. The deferred annuity is a contract that is purchased today but does not pay until the annuitant survives to a pre-specified age. Compared with a conventional immediate annuity, a deferred annuity has competitive advantages of a much lower price and provides almost the same level of longevity insurance; therefore, it has aroused much discussion in the area of retirement financial planning (see Milevsky, Reference Milevsky2005; Gong and Webb, Reference Gong and Webb2010; Denuit et al., Reference Denuit, Haberman and Renshaw2015). To uncover the annuitisation decisions of people at different ages, two types of deferred annuities are studied: a working age deferred annuity (WADA), which is purchased at working age and starts paying at retirement, and a retirement age deferred annuity (RADA), which is purchased at retirement and starts paying a few years later. To be more specific, we seek to explore four questions:
1. Can we use the hyperbolic discount model to explain the low demand for immediate annuities at retirement and at a more advanced age?
2. Are pensioners at 65 years old interested in purchasing a RADA?
3. Would people at working age have an interest in purchasing a WADA (with a single premium or with regular premiums)?
4. How would working-age members respond to a question asking them to decide today whether to buy an immediate annuity at retirement?
To seek the answers to these questions, we adopt the hyperbolic discount model to evaluate the perceived value of an annuity, which enables us to work out the reservation price. By comparing the reservation price with the theoretical market price we can determine whether an individual would choose an annuity or not. We show that time inconsistent preference is one of the factors that stops retirees from converting their DC account balances into annuities at retirement. More importantly, we identify a high willingness to purchase long-term deferred annuities for hyperbolic discounters, both at working age and in retirement. As the deferred period increases, the relative difference between reservation price and actuarial price increases considerably and at a much faster rate. Furthermore, if members are simply asked to make a decision on annuity purchase and could delay the action until the point of retirement, those with around ten years until retirement value the longevity protection the most.
The rest of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 provides a literature review of the explanation for the annuity puzzle from both the rational and behavioural framework. In Section 3, a detailed introduction of the hyperbolic model is offered. In Section 4, we explain how the annuities in the four questions above are evaluated and how the maximum acceptable price is derived. Major results and a sensitivity analysis are presented in Sections 5 and 6. Finally, in Section 7 we conclude with major findings, limitations of this study and suggestions for future work.
2. Literature review
Yaari (Reference Yaari1965) is the first to demonstrate the benefits of annuitisation in a life cycle model with an uncertain lifetime. He shows that a rational investor should invest his retirement savings in annuities rather than bonds to finance retirement. This result rests on three fundamental assumptions: a complete annuity market, a specific utility function (having the property of additive separability) and the absence of a bequest motive. The subsequent literature on annuities has relaxed one or two of these assumptions in order to assess if these factors lead to the low demand for annuities.
2.1 Annuities in a rational framework
Observing the annuity market from the supply side, a less competitive price could be the reason for low demand. Brown and Warshawsky (Reference Brown and Warshawsky2001) calculate the money's worth value of an annuity using average mortality rates of the population and find that an individual could expect to receive only 85 pence per pound invested, thus justifying the existence of adverse selection in annuity pricing.
Since an annuity stops paying once the annuitant dies, people with a motive to bequeath part of their wealth obtain less welfare by purchasing a life annuity. A large literature has focused on how the bequest motive impacts the demand for annuities and shows that a strong bequest motive can eliminate the desire to purchase annuities (see Friedman and Warshawsky, Reference Friedman and Warshawsky1990; Vidal-Melia and Lejarraga-Garcia, Reference Vidal-Melia and Lejarraga-Garcia2006; Lockwood, Reference Lockwood2012).
Intra-family mortality sharing can also be regarded as a substitute for an annuity. Since families often share a common budget constraint, mortality risk sharing among family members can offer a substitution for risk sharing in the annuity market. To an extent, this resembles the bequest motive; an individual who dies early leaves his wealth to subsidise other family members who are alive. Brown and Poterba (Reference Brown and Poterba2000) find evidence showing that the utility gain from annuitisation for a couple is significantly lower than that for single people.
An alternative explanation for the low demand for additional annuitisation is the existence of social security and private DB pension plans. According to Dushi and Webb (Reference Dushi and Webb2004), an exceptionally high proportion of a retired household's wealth has been pre-annuitised before retirement. Therefore, without purchasing an annuity in the open market, these retirees already have a minimum level of income that will last for life. Butler et al. (Reference Butler, Peijnenburg and Staubli2017) also prove that the presence of social security reduces the value of annuitisation.
A more recent discussion relates to the worry about health care expenditure shocks at an older age and the fact that retirees may not need the smooth consumption that an annuity provides. It is true that people have a higher probability of falling ill when they become older; they may also have to make some age-specific investments in a house such as installing a stair lift. Therefore we have reason to believe that a rational retiree might want to live a very simple life in their early retirement period so that they can save for unexpected health-related expenses (Sinclair and Smetters, Reference Sinclair and Smetters2004).
Lastly, while most research focuses on a comparison of full annuitisation aged 65 with the alternative of never annuitising, in practice, a retiree can choose between annuitising now and delaying the decision until the next period. They can also annuitise only a fraction of their wealth and enter a drawdown of the rest. Gavranovic (Reference Gavranovic2011) has demonstrated that the optimal annuitisation strategy for a pensioner without bequest motive is to gradually convert all pension wealth to annuities by around age 80.
2.2 Annuities in a behavioural framework
The literature mentioned above seeks to solve the annuity puzzle within a strictly rational framework. In recent years, however, there is an extensive literature on the behavioural economics of retirement savings. This moves beyond the fully rational paradigm and proposes some behavioural factors that could play important roles in determining how retirees spend their retirement savings.
One important issue is the flaws in the expected utility hypothesis that arise from risk aversion. Hu and Scott (Reference Hu and Scott2007) have explained the annuity puzzle by assuming that retirees are loss-averse rather than risk-averse, and make annuity decisions based on CPT (Tversky and Kahneman, Reference Tversky and Kahneman1992). They also extend the application of CPT to deferred annuities and guaranteed annuities, showing that the deferred annuity becomes optimal only when the first payment starts on or after age 93.
Another behavioural factor, the framing effect, which states that individuals’ behaviour depends heavily on the way in which available choices are presented, is also shown to be one of the influencing factors by Brown et al. (Reference Brown, Kling, Mullainathan and Wrobel2008). They have shown that 72% of subjects prefer an annuity rather than a savings account when the choice is framed in terms of consumption while 12% subjects choose an annuity when it is framed in terms of an investment.
Moreover, Brown et al. (Reference Brown, Kapteyn, Luttmer and Mitchell2012) show that it is difficult for people to make decisions when choices are very complex and not repeated. The annuity is one example of a complex financial product and the observed low level of annuity purchases may be explained by this.
As annuity products involve a series of payments that come in the future, we believe that behavioural factors that affect discounting methods would influence annuity valuations, and hence annuity purchase decisions. Laibson (Reference Laibson1998) has used hyperbolic discount models to explain a wide range of empirical anomalies, such as consumption discontinuity at retirement and under-saving. In this paper, we use this model to study annuitisation decisions. In the next section, we give a detailed explanation of the hyperbolic discount model.
3. An introduction to the hyperbolic discount model
In dealing with individuals’ annuitisation decisions and other economic decisions that involve outcomes occurring at different points in time, researchers often use a discounted utility framework to model such decisions. In a normative framework, the discount function adopted is often the exponential discount model, which assumes that the discount rate is constant over time and is independent of money amounts (or utilities). This often leads to a conclusion that individuals’ preferences are stationary over time, i.e. they have time-consistent preferences. In the real world, many empirical studies have observed anomalies in actual behaviour compared with what is predicted by the exponential discount function. Three major anomalies have been found. First, people tend to act impulsively in the short-term but become more patient in the long-term. In other words, the implicit rate at which people discount future rewards will vary inversely with the length of waiting time. Thaler (Reference Thaler1981) illustrates this with a simple example. Subjects are asked to state their preferences on two questions: ‘Would you prefer one apple today or two apples tomorrow?’ and ‘Would you prefer one apple in one year or two apples in one year plus one day?’. According to the exponential discounting method, people who choose one apple today should make consistent choice of one apple in a year. However, empirical results show that a significant fraction of subjects that prefer one apple today would gladly wait one extra day in a year's time in order to receive two apples instead. Second, the implicit discount rates with regard to different reward sizes would not stay the same. Thaler (Reference Thaler1981) finds that the subjects are indifferent between receiving $\$ 15$ immediately and $60 in a year, between $250 now and $350 in a year, and between an immediate $3,000 and $4,000 in a year, which means large reward sizes have lower discount rates compared with small reward sizes. Third, there is a gain-loss asymmetry in terms of discounting. For example, Loewenstein (Reference Loewenstein1987) finds that a group of subjects, on average, are indifferent between receiving an immediate $10 and receiving $21 in a year; but are indifferent between paying $10 immediately and paying $15 in a year. Similarly, the indifferent amount for receiving or paying an immediate $100 were receiving $157 or paying $133 respectively in a year.
The anomalies introduced above can be addressed by a hyperbolic discount model, which has been widely applied to explain the problem of addiction and self control. As an example, people with low self-control often find it difficult to improve their health by doing more exercise and having a diet. These people often pre-commit to forgo all future temptations, in exchange for improved health in the future; however, when they have their next meal, they cannot resist having unhealthy food and desserts (Redden, Reference Redden2007). Presumably, they prefer this because the instant pleasure delivered by delicious food is greater than the heavily discounted future rewards of health. Therefore, the hyperbolic discount model is appropriate to describe the situation that people simultaneously require immediate satisfaction and make commitments for the future.
Loewenstein and Prelec (Reference Loewenstein and Prelec1992) collectively present the experimental evidence and propose an explicit hyperbolic discount model to address the effect.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqn1.png?pub-status=live)
where δ(t) is a discount function; α and β determine how much the function departs from constant exponential discounting.
To identify the parameter values that capture most people's intertemporal preferences, Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009) conducted a parameter-free empirical measurement. In the experiment, each subject is asked to specify an amount at a future time point t that is indifferent relative to a certain gain at the current time; Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009) elicit different time weights by varying t. Relying on their results, we use the ‘power discount model’ where α = 1 so that δ(t) = (1 + t)−β in our analysis; here the best estimate β equals 0.19 for gains and 0.11 for losses. Please note that value of β would vary with country/cultural background of the selected group of subjects and the limitation is embedded in the experimental design. Therefore, in Section 6, sensitivity to the parameter β is explored, to show that the conclusions do not entirely depend on the chosen values of the parameters.
Figure 1 provides a comparison between the hyperbolic discounting and exponential discounting models. The horizontal axis represents the waiting time to receive £1 and the vertical axis is the present value of the £1 to be received. The present value following hyperbolic discounting decreases at a much faster rate in early years than following exponential discounting, which means that the hyperbolic discounters adopt a higher level of discounting for benefits that come in the early years than exponential discounters. However, if the benefits are to be received after 20 years (the intersection point), hyperbolic discounters believe that they have a higher value than exponential discounters.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_fig1.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 1. A comparison of hyperbolic discounting and exponential discounting. Notes: Vertical axis, discount function, represents the present value of £1 to be received at time t. We assume a constant interest rate of 3% for exponential discounting; α = 1 and β = 0.19 for hyperbolic discounting.
In addition to the discount function, a descriptive value function is also required in a complete discounted utility framework. Loewenstein and Prelec (Reference Loewenstein and Prelec1992) discuss the necessary characteristics of the value function without providing an explicit descriptive model. Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009) design a parameter-free measurement of value in intertemporal choices and hence derive the value function which addresses the absolute magnitude effect and the gain-loss asymmetry. In deriving this function, Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009) do not specify the form of the utility model in the beginning; however, they construct the shape of the value function from the experimental results.Footnote 2 After that, they find that the model below (in equation (2)) can provide the best fit to the shape of the value function; and they estimate the parameter values. The value function v(c t) is given below with γ being equal to 0.97 and θ being equal to 0.84. This function is concave for gains and convex for losses, reflecting a property of ‘diminishing marginal sensitivity’. This value function is assumed to be separable and additive over time as recorded in the literature:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqn2.png?pub-status=live)
where c t represents the consumption rate that would take place at a future time t, which is defined on the interval [0,T], and v(c t) represents the value of the consumption amount.
The discount rates and the value function are combined to arrive at the overall value of consumption streams:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqn3.png?pub-status=live)
A standard approach in the literature has been to use the exponential discount model for δ(t) and an utility function, for example constant relative risk aversion (CRRA), for v(c t). In this analysis, we instead use the hyperbolic discount model in equation (1) and the corresponding value function given by equation (2) to analyse annuity purchase decisions. We therefore are able to analyse the effect of subjective views on the underlying consumption streams.
4. Annuity valuation
In this section, we introduce four scenarios to address the questions of annuitisation decisions for people at different stages. Two types of annuities, immediate annuities and deferred annuities, are discussed in this paper and they are priced at actuarially fair rates. In order to make a fair decision, the overall utility, V, of the investment in each scenario will be calculated. As we focus on people who show ‘temporal myopia’, the amount of money is evaluated based on equation (2) and time preference is modelled by the ‘power discount model’, equation (1) with α = 1. Let tp x denote the probability that an x-year-old person can survive for t years and the maximum attainable age is set to be 120. Four scenarios are described in detail below and the corresponding valuation of the annuity investment is introduced.
4.1 Immediate annuities for retirees (Scenario a)
Consider a retiree at age x (x ≥ 65) who needs to make a decision on whether to spend a lump sum amount A to purchase an immediate annuity which pays ψ per annum in advance. The overall value of this investment for the x-year-old is:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqn4.png?pub-status=live)
4.2 Retirement age deferred annuity (RADA) for retirees (Scenario b)
Consider a 65-year-old pensioner (x = 65) who has just retired. The individual is faced with a wide variety of RADA products which have deferred periods (d) from 1 to 30 years. By investing the pension lump sum amount A in a d-year deferred annuity, the pensioner is entitled to a lifelong guaranteed annual income of ψ in d years. However, nothing is paid back if he dies within the deferred period. The overall value of this deferred annuity investment at the time of purchase is:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqn5.png?pub-status=live)
4.3 Working age deferred annuity (WADA) for working age individuals (Scenario c)Footnote 3
An individual at age x (25 ≤ x ≤ 64) considers investing in a WADA which provides annual incomes of ψ once the annuitant survives to retirement age 65. Either a single premium A (at age x) or a series of regular premiums (spreading between age x and age 65) is required. The overall perceived value of this investment at the time of purchase is (below we show the formulae of the case with a single premium):
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqn6.png?pub-status=live)
4.4 Decision on purchasing an immediate annuity at retirement for working age individuals (Scenario d)
In this scenario pension scheme members within the working age range (25 ≤ x ≤ 64) are asked to make decisions in advance on whether to choose a pension lump sum A at age 65 or a corresponding fair annuity starting at the same age. When evaluating this annuity, the cash flows involved are exactly the same as the immediate annuity purchased at age 65 (scenario a); however the perceived value may be different because the decision is made at an earlier age. If an individual decides to convert the lump sum A into an annuity at retirement, the overall perceived value of this investment for the individual is:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqn7.png?pub-status=live)
To determine whether an actuarially fairly priced annuity is attractive to purchase, we follow Hu and Scott (Reference Hu and Scott2007) to use the ‘relative difference between reservation price and fair price’, R, as the benchmark measure:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqnU1.png?pub-status=live)
The ‘reservation price’, also called the ‘maximum acceptable price’, is the annuity price that would make an individual indifferent to buying an annuity. According to the valuation functions above, the reservation price is the initial price, A, that makes the hyperbolic present value of an annuity, V, equal to zero. If the reservation price is below the market price, the annuity would not be attractive for individuals to buy. Therefore, a positive R means individuals are willing to purchase a fairly priced annuity, and a higher value of R implies greater willingness to purchase an annuity. R can also be interpreted as the percentage more or less than the market price that an individual would be prepared to pay for a product.
5. Results
In this analysis, we assume the annuity price is actuarially fair with no expenses or profit loading. The price calculation is based on the UK mortality table ‘S2PMLFootnote 4’, which describes the mortality experience of UK male pensioners of self-administered pension schemes for the period from 2004 to 2011, and a constant interest rate of 3%. Annual income from annuity, ψ, is assumed to be 1 unit. Therefore, the fair market price of the annuity and the reservation price that individuals would like to pay can be calculated accordingly. In what follows, we provide results for the relative price differences, R, under the four different scenarios, analyse the attitudes of investors towards each type of annuity and discuss the relation between the relative price differences and investors’ age or the length of the deferred period.
5.1 Immediate annuities for retirees (Scenario a)
The results of the relative price differences (R) with regards to different ages of purchase are presented in Figure 2. Two major conclusions can be drawn from the figure. First, all the outcomes in terms of R are negative, which means that for a group of retirees who are aged between 65 and 95, fairly priced immediate annuities are unattractive to purchase. Thus, evaluating annuitisation decisions by assuming time inconsistent preferences is indeed a powerful behavioural explanation for retirees’ not converting their DC account balances into annuities. Second, as a newly retired pensioner becomes older, his preference for the immediate annuity declines at first and then increases after he reaches age 85. However, the relative difference in price is small with R lying in the range of $-3\% $ and
$-10\% $.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_fig2.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 2. The relative price difference (R) of immediate annuities for retirees at age (x).
The results presented appear to be inconsistent with recent research carried out by Schreiber and Weber (Reference Schreiber and Weber2015), who find that the expected present value of an immediate annuity declines monotonically with the age of purchase. Although both studies use the power discounting model for annuity evaluation, different groups of people are targeted: Schreiber and Weber (Reference Schreiber and Weber2015) survey working age individuals while we focus on retirees above age 65; and this may explain the inconsistency.
5.2 Retirement age deferred annuity (RADA) for retirees (Scenario b)
Figure 3 shows the attractiveness of RADA with different deferred periods for a 65-year-old retiree. It can be seen that although recently retired individuals are reluctant to purchase immediate annuities, they are willing to pay a higher-than-market price for annuities with long deferred periods. From our modelling results, annuities that are deferred for more than 10 years are generally welcomed by 65-year-old retirees. Furthermore, we identify a positive relationship between the length of the deferred period and the attractiveness of the corresponding deferred annuity. If an annuity has a deferred period of 30 years, a 65-year-old individual would be prepared to pay 24% more than the fair price.Footnote 5 This is a much higher margin than that for an immediate annuity. It implies that such a product would have commercial potential since insurance companies could add a greater loading in the pricing of deferred annuity products without changing their attractiveness.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_fig3.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 3. The relative price difference (R) of d-year RADA for 65-year-old retirees.
The popularity of deferred annuities has also been identified in other work. Hu and Scott (Reference Hu and Scott2007) adopt CPT to evaluate deferred annuities with deferred periods of 0, 10, 20 and 30 years and find that the 30-year deferred annuity is the most attractive to buy. In Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Haberman and Thomas2019), we also show that the attractiveness of a deferred annuity increases with the length of the deferred period, according to CPT.
5.3 Working age deferred annuity (WADA) for working age individuals (Scenario c)
If individuals at working age are given the opportunity to enter a deferred annuity contract that promises retirement incomes depending upon survival, their reactions are examined and reflected in Figure 4. It can be seen that although people who are retired are unsure of handing over a lump sum of money to insurance companies in exchange for longevity protection, most people at working age tend to find a WADA attractive to buy. Another interesting point worthy of note is that the decision maker's age has a negative effect on the attractiveness of this type of deferred annuity. For hyperbolic discounters younger than 30-year-old, they appear even to be willing to pay double the price of the WADA.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_fig4.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 4. The relative price difference (R) of d-year WADA with the lump sum premium for individuals at age (x).
We know that as the length of deferred period increases, the actuarially fair price of a deferred annuity which provides the same level of protection becomes cheaper; hence younger individuals would be less hesitant to purchase a WADA which involves a smaller initial outlay. In addition, given the assumption that people have time inconsistent preferences, a young individual tends to overvalue all of the annuity incomes that come in the distant future; however for an older individual, some of the deferred annuity payments are highly likely to be undervalued. The results are consistent with our conclusions in scenario b. Purchasing the pension annuities at an earlier age means a longer deferred period, and in both scenarios an annuity with a longer deferred period is more attractive. The magnitude of R is much higher in scenario c than in scenario b because a longer deferred period is considered.
The major conclusions regarding WADA also hold when we allow the deferred annuity premiums to be spread over the entire deferred period. Being aware that young individuals might not have enough savings to afford the lump sum premium to enter the WADA contract, or a large lump sum to be paid years before receiving any benefits might decrease the marketability, we consider the situation when premiums are to be paid annually in advance between the age of purchase and the retirement age. If they die before the retirement age, no premiums would be returned; otherwise they would start receiving annuity payments from age 65 until the point of death. The results of the relative price difference (R) are shown in Figure 5. It again shows that most people at working age (below age 60) would find a WADA attractive to buy; and the decision maker's age has a negative impact on the attractiveness of WADA.Footnote 6
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_fig5.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 5. The relative price difference (R) of d-year WADA with level premiums for individuals at age (x).
Some of our findings mirror those suggested elsewhere. Shu et al. (Reference Shu, Robert and Payne2016) have conducted a choice-based stated-preference survey of adults aged between 45 and 65 and find that younger subjects report a higher likelihood of purchases for annuities beginning at age 65 than older subjects who are closer in age to the start date. DiCenzo et al. (Reference Dicenzo, Shu, Hadar and Rieth2011) have also discovered that pre-retirees have stronger preferences for annuities than retirees based on online experimental research with 1,009 subjects aged between 45 and 75.
5.4 Decision on purchasing an immediate annuity at retirement for working age individuals (Scenario d)
Similar to the third scenario, we aim to discover the attitude of working age pension scheme members towards an annuity with the first payment starting when pensioners retire at age 65. Although the annuity investment payoffs are exactly the same, the purchase is made at different points. In scenario c, the price is paid now at age x while in scenario d, pensioners simply make a decision at age x but delay the purchase action until age 65. If an individual dies prior to the time of retirement, his financial status remain unchanged in scenario d but he faces an absolute loss of the price paid in scenario c. Therefore, scenario d effectively deals with the decision to buy an immediate annuity rather than a deferred annuity.
Comparing the results of R in Figure 6 with those in Figure 4, we identify a different pattern. For individuals below age 55, the attractiveness of the annuity increases slightly with age. However for individuals above age 55, the attractiveness declines sharply with age and becomes unattractive when individuals reach age 65. We notice that the occurrence of the kink is due to the different discounting parameter β for gains and losses. When the discounting parameter values for gains and losses are set to be the same, the kink disappears and the attractiveness reduces with the waiting period (time point of decision and retirement age).Footnote 7 In future work we would look into the differences in the gain loss discounting, and test how sensitive our results are to the gain-loss asymmetry.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_fig6.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 6. The relative price difference (R) of an immediate annuity purchased at retirement for working age individuals at age (x).
With the results indicated in Figure 6, we suggest that policy makers who want to promote annuitisation in public ask individuals to make a choice between lump sum and annuities around 10 years before retirement. On the other hand, one may notice that the change in R is relatively small, varying between 4% and 8%. It is similar to the results for immediate annuities in scenario a.
These findings confirm those in the survey by Schreiber and Weber (Reference Schreiber and Weber2015). In their survey, subjects are asked to predict whether they will annuitise if they were at age 66. The total sample results show that the effect of age on the decision to purchase an annuity is negative. However, observing the answers from a subsample of individuals below age 51, the effect is no longer statistically significant. To some extent, it reveals that people above age 51 have significant decreasing preferences towards annuities.
6. Sensitivity analysis
Previously, we assumed that each parameter value in the annuity calculations is based on the work of Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009). However, questions remain as to whether the behavioural biases would be stronger or weaker for people with different levels of impatience, different income levels or different health status. In this section, we test the sensitivity of the interest rate, the power discounting parameter, the value function parameter, the income levels and mortality rates (by changing mortality tables).
Table 1 shows the results for R in scenarios a and b under different combinations of assumptions. The row ‘Baseline’ lists the standard results that are based on the benchmark assumptions in Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009). In the row ‘Sensitivity analysis’, we change one factor listed in each row at a time so that we can observe the impact of that factor on R. ‘Less’ or ‘greater’ is relative to the baseline results. Each column represents different types of annuity products with the first payment starting at a different age. For example, an annuity starts paying at age 75 represents an immediate annuity purchased at age 75 in scenario a and a 10-year deferred annuity purchased at age 65 in scenario b.
Table 1. Sensitivity analysis of the relative price difference (R) in scenarios a and b
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_tab1.png?pub-status=live)
The first factor that is of interest is the interest rate, which is an important factor in pricing an annuity. As the interest rate moves from lower (r = 1%) to higher (r = 3%), R consistently increases, for all types of immediate annuities and deferred annuities. This feature is simply because a higher interest rate leads to a lower annuity price, which helps investors lock in a high rate of return. For immediate annuity purchasers (scenario a), it is better to choose an annuity starting at age 65 when the interest rate is high; however, it is better to delay the purchase when the rate in the market is low. For deferred annuities (scenario b), the interest rate is of less concern compared with immediate annuities (because a smaller number of payments will be discounted). The attractiveness of the deferred annuity will depend on the relative level of patience of investors. For an individual with a certain level of impatience, they tend to overvalue future benefits more heavily when the interest rate is higher. Therefore the longer-term annuity becomes more attractive in a high interest rate environment.
Another factor that we investigate is the level of impatience, measured by β. Given that the annuity pricing rate is deterministic, a higher β means that the decision maker adopts a heavier undervaluation of earlier benefits and a lighter overvaluation of later benefits. Reflecting on the curves in Figure 7, the intersection point between exponential discounting and hyperbolic discounting would come at a later stage as β increases. Comparing our baseline results with less/greater impatience for both immediate annuities and RADA, we conclude that the attractiveness of annuity products is consistently lower in response to a greater level of impatience. This makes sense intuitively since an individual with a greater level of impatience would have stronger present bias; they would gain much higher satisfaction from consuming now rather than converting the lump sum into future cash flows and consuming regularly. According to Table 1, relatively patient individuals (β = 0.15) are willing to pay a slightly higher price, 4.82% and 1.64% respectively, for immediate annuities at age 65 and 70. It is because they are patient to wait and assign more weight to future incomes. Investment opportunities that convert current consumption into a future stream of cash flow are attractive to them. The same reasons lead to the attractiveness of deferred annuities for this group of people (see the row corresponding to β = 0.15 in scenario b).
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_fig7.png?pub-status=live)
Figure 7. A comparison of hyperbolic discounting with different levels of impatience. Notes: We assume a constant interest rate of 3% for exponential discounting; α = 1 for hyperbolic discounting.
Greater or lower value sensitivity is measured by the parameters in the value function. A smaller value of θ (or γ) means the marginal value that an individual would gain (loss) from an additional amount of gain (loss) is smaller. As the experimental results suggest that people's attitudes towards gains and losses are different, we maintain a difference of 0.1 between γ and θ in the sensitivity analysis. In scenario a, we find that immediate annuities becomes less popular as people become older. However, if retirees underestimate the losses from paying annuity premiums (γ = 0.9), an annuity could become more popular (with a positive R). This impact is also seen in scenario b with regard to the case of deferred annuities. Previously in the baseline results, only annuities with long deferred periods would be popular, however, with an assumption of loss underestimation (γ = 0.9), annuities with shorter deferred periods are also attractive.
The effect of annuity income levels is examined to capture the variation in decisions of people with different wealth levels. Two levels of annual income, 0.0721Footnote 8 unit and 3 units, are adopted to represent relatively poor people and relatively rich people. Based on the value function in the hyperbolic discount model introduced above, people tend to overvalue the amount of less than one unit and undervalue the amount of greater than one unit. This is reasonable since people often place more values on the initial accumulation of an amount of money and this portion of money is intended for the purchase of necessities such as food, utilities and rent. Therefore, the results corresponding to ψ = 0.0721 and ψ = 3 in scenarios a and b show that relatively wealthy people who can afford an annuity with higher annual incomes are willing to pay a lower-than-market price, while relatively poor people are willing to pay a much higher-than-market price for annuities.
The mortality sensitivity analysis is conducted by comparing results from two mortality tables: S2PMA-L, the mortality experience of male pensioners with high pension amounts and relatively lower mortality rates, and S2PMA-H, the mortality experience of male pensioners with low pension amounts and relatively higher mortality rates. Results in scenario a show pensioners with the highest mortality rates (S2PMA-H) tend to find immediate annuities the least attractive. Similarly, those with low mortality rates and long life expectancies (S2PMA-L) show the greatest interest in RADA, as is observed in scenario b.
Table 2 shows the results in terms of R in scenarios c and d. In Table 2, we can see the sensitivity of four factors: the interest rate, the level of impatience, the value sensitivity, the level of income and mortality rates, on the annuitisation decisions.
Table 2. Sensitivity analysis of the relative price difference (R) in scenarios c and d
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_tab2.png?pub-status=live)
The sensitivity analysis of the interest rate in scenarios c and d again shows that annuities are generally attractive in a high interest rate environment. Moreover, as the deferred period increase, the increase in attractiveness (R) is greater when the interest rate is higher. As explained previously, the reason behind this is that an individual with a certain level of impatience would overvalue future benefits more heavily when the interest rate is higher. When the deferred period is greater than a certain number of years, it is possible that all payments will be overvalued.
By comparing results corresponding to β = 0.15 and β = 0.25, we find those at working age see annuities as more valuable when they experience less impatience. In addition, for decision makers with different levels of impatience, the effect of their age on the WADA's attractiveness is consistently negative. In other words, the longer the waiting period to receive the first annuity income is, the higher the possibility of purchase will be. The intuition behind these features is as follows: incomes that arrive further in the future are more likely to be overvalued and thus the deferred annuity with a longer waiting period has a higher maximum acceptable price.
The results with different levels of value sensitivities in scenarios c and d reinforce our conclusions drawn from Table 1. In general, deferred annuities are more attractive when the deferred period is longer. A greater underestimation of losses would make the deferred annuities even more attractive. We note that the underestimation of gains also has an impact on the results, however the impact (for example θ changing from 0.9 to 0.8) is much less significant than that of the underestimation of losses. This feature occurs because our model considers a one-off lump sum premium payment for entering an annuity contract.
In scenario d where the real purchase of an immediate annuity is delayed until retirement, we have shown in the baseline results (which assume that β is 0.19 for gains and 0.11 for losses in the power discount function) that people have the greatest interest in buying an annuity around age 55. However in the sensitivity analysis when we let discount rates for gains and losses be the same, the peak in the trend of R disappears and we see a gradual decrease of value of R relative to the age of decision making. In such a case, governments may simply encourage individuals to make annuitisation decisions earlier rather than 10 years before retirement. Whether people use different discount rates for gains and losses and the resulting impact on annuitisation decisions needs future research.
Results corresponding to ψ = 0.0721 and ψ = 3 in scenarios c and d show that wealthy decision makers who can afford an annuity with a high annual income tend to find annuities less attractive. The impact of income levels on the annuity purchasing behaviour is consistent for decision makers at all ages.Footnote 9
The sensitivity of mortality rates in Table 2 indicates intuitively that annuities are more attractive for individuals with longer life expectancies, regardless of the age of decision making and the age of annuity purchase. Furthermore, for different mortality groups, age presents a negative influence on the attractiveness of a WADA. If the annuitisation decision needs to be made at working age and the actual purchases could be delayed until retirement, those between 50 and 55 are the most likely to choose an annuity and a strong decline in annuity preferences exists for pensioners older than 55.
In order to measure the responsiveness of the relative price difference to the change in each parameter, we calculate the elasticity of the relative price difference, E R. It addresses the percentage change in the relative price difference for a given percentage change in the parameter value and the formula is as follows:
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_eqn8.png?pub-status=live)
In equation (8), ΔR stands for the absolute change in R and Δparameter stands for the absolute change in the considered parameter values. R average stands for the absolute value of average of R under different parameter values and parameter average is the absolute value of the average of chosen parameter values. As the average value is used to calculate the percentage change, the elasticity of the relative price difference can be regarded as a point mid-way among all of the R results. After we calculate E R for each immediate annuity or for each deferred annuity, we average the results and obtain the elasticity of the relative price difference for annuities in four different scenarios. The results are presented in Table 3. Please note that we use life expectancy at the age of annuity purchase as an index for each mortality table.
Table 3. Elasticity of the relative price difference (E R)
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20200611020450951-0061:S1474747218000343:S1474747218000343_tab3.png?pub-status=live)
Notes: r represents the interest rate, β defines the level of impatience, θ and γ define the value function, ψ represents the income level and e ° represents the life expectancy corresponding to each mortality table.
If E R is greater than 1, the relative price difference changes proportionately more than the parameter value changes. If E R is less than 1, the relative price difference changes proportionately less than the parameter value changes, implying a less sensitive parameter. Based on the results in Table 3, the following conclusions can be drawn. First, the interest rate is a very sensitive factor in influencing annuity purchase decisions, especially immediate annuity purchase decisions. This is reasonable as the interest rate is one of the most important annuity pricing factors. For immediate annuity products that require a large initial payment, a small change in interest rate can change premium greatly. Second, the relative price difference is responsive to a small change in the level of impatience, which is measured by β. It confirms our findings in the sensitivity results of Tables 1 and 2 that people with different levels of patience would hold distinct opinions regarding the purchase of annuities. Third, the relative price difference is very sensitive to the parameter values of the value function; and the sensitivity is more significant for immediate annuity products than for deferred annuity products. This is due to the property of ‘diminishing marginal sensitivity’, the deviation of the perceived value from the real value would be more significant for an annuity product with a higher price. Fourth, deferred annuities have greater sensitivity to mortality parameters than immediate annuities. This is partly due to the fact that incomes generated from the deferred annuities will be delayed for a few years; hence there is a possibility that the annuitant would not receive any incomes should they die during the deferred period.
7. Conclusions
Although purchasing an annuity at retirement can guarantee lifetime incomes, people are reluctant to spend their retirement savings on annuities voluntarily. In the UK, with fewer restrictions on accessing retirement savings, the demand for annuities has decreased and thus insurance companies are making efforts to design more attractive annuity products. This paper discusses the implications of one behavioural factor, time inconsistent preferences (as represented by the hyperbolic discount model), on the annuity purchasing decision.
Based on the analysis, we have the following primary findings. First, for a 65-year-old retiree, the reservation price of an immediate annuity is lower than the market price, and thus the hyperbolic discount method captures the low demand for annuities at retirement, as seen in practice.
Second, under the hyperbolic discount model, deferred annuities are attractive for pension scheme members at all ages. The attractiveness generally increases with the deferred period. For instance, those below the age of 30 would pay more than double the market price for the WADA. However, our model does not account for factors such as affordability, a liquidity requirement and expected retirement living standards. While a 25-year-old man who wants to receive an annual annuity income of £40,000 after retirement might find a 40-year deferred annuity attractive; he will most probably not be able to afford the annuity price of £150,034Footnote 10 at this young age. With time passing, he will accumulate wealth and set aside a portion for retirement protection. Often, there will be a point when accumulated retirement savings equal the deferred annuity price; this is the optimal age of purchase. Alternatively, a more affordable plan is to choose regular premiums spreading over the period between current age and retirement age. We have shown that the positive relationship between attractiveness and the deferred period is maintained under this scenario of regular premiums.
We recommend using the deferred annuity contract as a retirement solution because it requires a smaller initial investment than the immediate annuity and provides similar longevity insurance. In addition, based on the fact that analytical cognitive function ability declines dramatically for older adults, it would be wise to buy a RADA to protect consumption at very advanced ages. For those in their 80s, it has been shown that 20% have fully diagnosed dementia and 30% have severe cognitive impairment; and thus, it would be difficult for these individuals to make rational withdrawal decisions if there were no income protection in place (Agarwal et al., Reference Agarwal, Driscoll, Gabaix and Laibson2009).
Currently when the public has limited knowledge on deferred annuities, a policy recommendation we would like to draw is to introduce compulsory annuitisation with respect to deferred annuities. The significant decrease in annuity sales after the pension reform may cause unforeseeable social problems in future especially for those who have limited financial knowledge to manage pension savings effectively and wisely. Although we support the idea of flexible choices in pension arrangements, we believe that the annuity product's main function of providing longevity risk protection should be retained to some extent. Overall, making the deferred annuity purchase a compulsory choice would have the following benefits. First, it can protect individuals against myopia, and protect governments from potential increasing expenditure on social benefits. Second, it would encourage life insurance companies to enter the market and start offering deferred annuity products. Third, a compulsory policy helps to reduce or remove adverse selection, which is of vital importance in insurance markets. A reduced degree of adverse selection would ensure a large efficient market, and it would mean that annuitants are more likely to receive close to 100% of the fair annuity value.
In scenario d, we observe that individuals around the age of 55 are those who would most likely commit to buy an immediate annuity at the point of retirement. Relying on this result, another policy recommendation can be drawn. With the aim of promoting the purchase of annuities among retirees and releasing the burden from social benefit claiming, governments are advised to introduce a pre-commitment device asking people to make annuitisation decisions around 10 years before retirement. When they reach retirement, their original decisions could be changed but some efforts, such as making a phone call or writing a letter, are required. In fact, in Denmark, the decisions on annuity purchases can be made during the accumulation period. As a result, about 50% of DC assets are used to buy WADA type products for those aged in their 40s, 50s and 60s (Andersen and Skjodt, Reference Andersen and Skjodt2008).
In the sensitivity analysis, we have explained that the optimal point of age 55 is due to different discounting parameter values used for gains and losses. The kink would disappear if we were to assume the same discounting factors for gains and losses. In future work, we would like to look into the area of gain-loss discounting asymmetry and examine more detailed impacts on our conclusions.
Although we have shown that inconsistent time preference is one of the reasons for the annuity puzzle, the results largely rely on how the hyperbolic discount model is calibrated in Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009). In summary, there are three limitations with the model calibration. First, the discount model was built using the concept of consumption, but Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009) study the discounting of money amounts. Consumption is different from money amounts since a decision maker who has no liquidity constraints would not consider his preferences when valuing money amounts. Hence, experimental results do not measure the true discount function, but a combination of the discount function, liquidity constraints and bounded rational thinking about money. Second, subjects in the experiment were young university students who may share completely different views about money and time discounting compared with older workers and retirees. Their views may reflect a specific cultural or country background as well. Third, the money amounts in the experimental questions are much smaller than the size of one's pension savings. Overall, the results provide a more qualitative rather than a precise quantitative explanation of the relative attractiveness of annuities.
In general, there are some other limitations and implications for future work. First, this paper uses the value function and discount function directly from the results in Abdellaoui et al. (Reference Abdellaoui, Attema and Bleichrodt2009). Both functions are consistently based on the same experiments. We leave to future work an exploration of other variations of the utility function, such as the CRRA or Epstein-Zin utility functions, and the impact of risk aversion. Second, this paper does not consider the bequest motive and long-term care needs. These two factors are very important in making annuity purchase decisions, and hence allowing for them in the modelling framework would give more robust conclusions.