1. Introduction
It has been recognized for some time that institutions shape the actions of entrepreneurs (e.g., Parker, Reference Parker2009: Part II) and help determine the supply of entrepreneurship. Yet Baumol's seminal work (1990) contributed to the literature by showing that institutions determine not only the level, but also the type of entrepreneurship. According to Baumol, individuals put their entrepreneurial talent to use in activities that are productive, unproductive, or destructive. The institutional setup or ‘the rules of the game’ dictate relative return, and hence the allocation across these activities. However, institutions do not merely control entrepreneurs; entrepreneurs in turn control them – through business activity, evasive methods, and political entrepreneurship. This paper will explore both sides of this interaction: how the institutional framework influences entrepreneurship and how entrepreneurs in turn influence the emergence and evolution of institutions.
An influential stream of research has built on the insight that productive abilities can also be used for rent-extracting purposes (e.g., Murphy et al., Reference Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny1991; Acemoglu, Reference Acemoglu1995). This literature typically stresses that institutions determine the relative rates of return of productive and unproductive types of activities. This relationship has typically been assumed to be unilateral, running from institutions to entrepreneurship, while a potential reverse or bilateral causality has been largely neglected. Boettke and Coyne (Reference Boettke and Coyne2003) probably contain the strongest assertion that institutions are the ultimate cause of growth, whereas entrepreneurship is merely a proximate cause, since according to them its supply and direction is fully determined by the institutional setup.Footnote 1
In addition to the large and growing literature that uncovers the impact of institutions on entrepreneurship, it has long been recognized within political science that institutions and policies are influenced by entrepreneurial individuals as well. We show that institutional entrepreneurship can be fruitfully classified according to Baumol's typology of productive and unproductive entrepreneurship. We further aim to bring these two fields of research together, and also explore the synthesis, which is the two-way interaction of entrepreneurship and institutions.
Because the causal relationship goes in both directions, entrepreneurship interacts with institutions within the course of a bilateral relationship. This possibility has been touched upon previously in the public choice school. Buchanan (Reference Buchanan, Buchanan and Tollison1980: 14) noted:
Faced with a prospect of differentially unfavorable tax treatment by government, a person or a group may (1) engage in lobbying effort; (2) engage directly in politics to secure access to decision-making power, and/or (3) make plans to shift into or out of the affected activity.
In general terms, Buchanan concludes that entrepreneurs affect institutions by: (i) market innovations that alter institutions or the effect of institutions, (ii) evasion of institutions, and (iii) direct political entrepreneurship.
Economists and political scientists are not the only ones who have studied the interactions of entrepreneurs and institutions. Within the field of sociology there exists an interesting interpretation of institutional entrepreneurship, which differs in certain respects from the received view among economists. We briefly examine the strand of literature in sociology which examines the impact of entrepreneurial individuals on organizations and institutions and contrast this perspective with that of economics and political science.
2. Entrepreneurship defined and categorized
Entrepreneurial talent
In line with Baumol (Reference Baumol1990) and Murphy et al. (Reference Murphy, Shleifer and Vishny1991), an entrepreneur is defined here according to a set of talents. There is no consensus in the literature regarding the nature of these talents; some scholars emphasize cognitive abilities while others point to motivation (preferences).Footnote 2 We define entrepreneurial talent as a combination of perceptiveness, the ability to detect opportunities, and the capability of undertaking new ventures in response. The definition thus includes both motivation and ability. Profitable business projects, the chance to appropriate or earn rents, and the possibility to affect policy constitute the opportunities explored here.
Self-employment and start-ups embody the most typical forms of business entrepreneurship. Our definition of entrepreneurship precludes many forms of self-employment, however. Most importantly, self-employment that is not innovative in nature does not qualify as entrepreneurship. In reality, no clear boundary delineating truly innovative entrepreneurship from non-innovative self-employment can be drawn; as a result, we employ a continuum of self-employment activity organized from purely non-innovative to highly dynamic entrepreneurship.
The idea that innovative individuals contribute to institutional change has a long history in political science. In his case study of political power in New Haven, Dahl (Reference Dahl1961) introduced the term ‘political entrepreneurs’, individuals who recombine resources in the policy arena to bring about change. The political arena in New Haven was entrepreneurial in its alertness to ‘citizen desires’ and ‘the ease with which the political stratum can be penetrated’ (Dahl, Reference Dahl1961: 93) by new individuals. In accordance with political scientists, we also call entrepreneurship, undertaken with the direct aim of altering institutions, political entrepreneurship.Footnote 3 The term business or market entrepreneur is used here, somewhat loosely, to refer to traditional Schumpeterian entrepreneurs, distinct from political entrepreneurs. Similar to business entrepreneurs, political entrepreneurs are people who are alert to opportunities, bear risk, reorganize coalitions and resources, and ultimately bring about innovation, be it socially positive or negative.
Despite clear differences in undertakings and goals, business and policy entrepreneurs enjoy similar functions. Law-abiding business entrepreneurs and institution-altering political entrepreneurs both discover and meet unfulfilled needs, and both must bear the personal risk associated with their ventures. Lastly, all entrepreneurs need to coordinate and reorganize the resources needed to undertake change, be it capital, labor, or political alliances. In light of these parallel functions, it is likely that all types of entrepreneurs share at least some individual characteristics.
Lee Kuan Yew, Robert Mugabe, and Silvio Berlusconi are some of the major political entrepreneurs discussed here. While they are quite obvious examples, Lee, Mugabe, and Berlusconi only form the tip of the iceberg of political entrepreneurship. Innovative political activity occurs constantly at all levels of government. Similar to business entrepreneurship, the most iconic figures become national heroes, although most political entrepreneurship is local and small-scale. Societal factors, such as demographic change and technological development, drive the need for such activity. For example, the expansion of a suburb entails new roads and public services, and the individual who identifies and responds to this need is the political entrepreneur. Schneider et al. (Reference Schneider, Teske and Minton1995) focus on community entrepreneurs, who organize to provide local public goods. They find that 30% of city clerks in suburban American counties could identify an individual in their community whose ‘policy proposals and political position represented a dynamic change from existing procedures’. Again, akin to business entrepreneurs, entrepreneurial individuals often start out as small-scale local political entrepreneurs who expand the scope of their activity if successful. Current US president Barack Obama famously started his political career as a ‘community organizer’ in Chicago.
Of course, all political leaders share some entrepreneurial aspects. Virtually all of them change statutes, introduce new legislation, or carry through reforms at some point during their careers. One would be hard-pressed to find any long-serving politician who has not contributed to at least some minor institutional change. Does that mean that all politicians are political entrepreneurs then? Not necessarily – policy entrepreneurship is not alone in suffering from this problem of delineation. Almost every firm or public institution engages in some degree of innovation and alertness in its day-to-day activities. All economic activity involves a minimum degree of entrepreneurship, regardless of how entrepreneurship is defined (Kirzner, Reference Kirzner2009). Economic entrepreneurship – whether explicit or implicit – can be seen as a matter of degree. Changing the color of a product is not enough; an activity must be sufficiently innovative for it to be defined as entrepreneurial and made distinct from non-entrepreneurial activity. The same is true for political entrepreneurship; institutional reform has to be sufficiently novel for it to qualify as policy entrepreneurship. Where one chooses to draw the line depends on context and the researcher's own judgment.
Institutional entrepreneurs in sociology
The fundamental concept of institutional entrepreneurship in sociological literature is the same as the one discussed here, although its framing and perspective are different (Scott, Reference Scott, Smith and Hitt2004). In this rich literature, institutions appear as deeper and firmer aspects of social structures. Scott writes, for example, that (Reference Scott1995: 33) ‘institutions are social structures that have attained a high degree of resilience. [They] are composed of cultural-cognitive, normative, and regulative elements that, together with associated activities and resources, provide stability and meaning to social life.’ Institutional entrepreneurship can ‘account for institutional change endogenously’ (Battilana, Reference Battilana2006). DiMaggio (Reference DiMaggio and Zucker1988)Footnote 4 introduced this function to explain how individuals can bring about radical change not necessarily in line with prevailing institutions.
Prior to DiMaggio, prevailing sociological theory could only explain institutional change in terms of isomorphism (organizations spreading their rules of behavior); it had difficulty accounting for situations in which dramatic change takes place in the opposite direction of initial institutional inertia, such as a rapid shift in the market structure or the fact of a mature firm suddenly changing its core business and strategy. Other types of discontinuous change also represented something of a puzzle to this theory. ‘How can organizations or individuals innovate if their beliefs and actions are all determined by the very instructional environment they wish to change?’ (Battilana, Reference Battilana2006: 654). The paradox is to some extent resolved by introducing the entrepreneur. This allows for the capacity of agents to ‘make a difference’, acting sometimes contrary to what the prevailing institutional structure would predict, and even change these prevailing institutions.
The sociological perspective that builds on DiMaggio's institutional entrepreneur coincides in part with the economic and political science definition of institutions, namely informal institutions, such as norms and culture. Discontinuous change of institutions through individual actions fits well with the idea of political entrepreneurs altering institutions. The sociological view of structures and institutions, which is reinforced every time individuals act in line with them, resembles most economists’ definition of habits and hardwired preferences (Becker and Murphy, Reference Becker and Murphy2000).
In contrast to sociologists, economists fail to see a paradox in the fact of entrepreneurs being influenced by institutions at the same time as they contribute to institutional change and evolution. Nor do economists recognize agents being ‘trapped’ in institutions, requiring entrepreneurs to escape. This reflects sociologists’ much broader definition of institutions and structures, including most beliefs and preferences. (Sociologists view these institutions as stronger and more binding, and comparatively more important than economic incentives or relative prices.) Ultimately, this difference in perspective mirrors the classical disagreement between sociologists and economists regarding the extent to which individuals are free to make choices and control their own circumstances. Nevertheless, since sociologists allow for entrepreneurs to escape their structural bonds, while economists emphasize the role of broad institutions and social context in forming individual choice in this area, the two disciplines are closer to each other regarding institutional entrepreneurship than on many other issues.
Entrepreneurship – a typology
In our analysis, we follow Baumol's lead (1990) in distinguishing between productive and unproductive/destructive entrepreneurship.Footnote 5 Due to differences in focus, however, we do not discriminate between destructive and merely unproductive entrepreneurship, choosing rather to merge the two categories. Our attention is directed rather at entrepreneurs’ response to institutions. Entrepreneurs can abide by institutions, and later even evade institutions. Finally, we include the possibility for entrepreneurs to alter institutions. This creates a 2 × 3 matrix, where each entrepreneurial activity can be assigned to one of the six types.
Baumol (Reference Baumol1990) introduces his analysis as an extension of Schumpeter's (1934) theory of innovations as new combinations, particularly when discussing productive entrepreneurship.Footnote 6 Innovative entrepreneurship may be, and often is, incremental in nature, progressing in small steps over long periods. The same is true for political entrepreneurship.
Unproductive/destructive entrepreneurship, on the other hand, entails some combination of rent-seeking technologies that enables the entrepreneur to appropriate rents from other agents. In this process, the social product may be unaffected, as in the case of a simple transfer, or be lowered, as in the case of destructive entrepreneurship. In the terminology of the neoclassical theory of the firm, the distinction between the different types can be characterized as a shift inward (destructive) or outward (productive) of the production possibility frontier (Coyne and Leeson, Reference Coyne and Leeson2004).
Given the definition of the entrepreneur, it simply cannot be assumed that entrepreneurs passively respond to institutions. Indeed, theories within the school of new institutional economics usually describe the entrepreneur as a key agent in institutional change. North (Reference North1990), for instance, holds that the entrepreneur acts on the fringe of a given institutional setup and is the agent that embodies dynamism and change, all occurring in a setting in which agents’ behavior is otherwise determined by institutions. This is broadly consistent with the framework presented here. A second dimension of our typology distinguishes behavior within the constraints of the institutions from behavior aimed at evading these constraints. Evasive entrepreneurship is defined as an activity aimed at circumventing the institutional framework. Finally, entrepreneurs may actively alter institutions through political activity. These definitions are illustrated in Figure 1.Footnote 7
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160626192509-19866-mediumThumb-S1744137410000342_fig1g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Figure 1. A typology of entrepreneurship and some illustrative examples
The allocation of entrepreneurship between abiding, evading and altering institutions is influenced by the relative payoff of those activities, much like the allocation between productive and unproductive/destructive entrepreneurship (Baumol, Reference Baumol1990). It is important to keep the vertical distinctions in Figure 1 (from productive to unproductive/destructive) separate from the horizontal ones (choosing to follow a career as an abiding business entrepreneur, an evasive [legal or illegal] entrepreneur, or an altering political entrepreneur).
Baumol only discusses business entrepreneurs as productive entrepreneurship, whereas other entrepreneurial activities (such as joining the bureaucracy) are discussed solely in unproductive terms. In our categorization, both institution-abiding business entrepreneurship and institution-altering political entrepreneurship can be productive. Even evasive entrepreneurship can be productive, both directly (by evading institutions that hamper production) and indirectly (by forcing a change in such institutions). This is not based in a disagreement with Baumol; rather, it merely arises from our including two categories – evading and altering entrepreneurship – that he did not.Footnote 8
In practice, however, not all activity can be neatly categorized by our definitions. Entrepreneurship may incorporate aspects of evasion and alteration at the same time, such as the organization of boycotts and passive resistance in order to change a law. The matrix aims solely to give some structure to the discussion, and does not claim perfect and mutually exclusive categorization.
Finally, it should be noted that institutions that direct talent to different activities do not necessarily affect exactly the same individuals. If the rules of the game in a country change in favor of business entrepreneurship, a successful influence peddler does not automatically become an industrialist. Rather, when an individual drops out of political entrepreneurship, room is made for another individual with abilities suited for building productive firms.
3. Entrepreneurship across different activities
The politico-economic approach
Bilateral causal effects between politics, institutions, and economic performance have long captured the interest of economists. Baumol (Reference Baumol1990) asserts that institutions determine ‘the social structure of payoffs’, which govern the conduct of economic activity. Institutions have moved to the fore of mainstream explanations for economic performance, especially over the long term (see, for example, North and Weingast, Reference North and Weingast1989; Rodrik et al., Reference Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi2004; Acemoglu et al., Reference Acemoglu, Johnson, Robinson, Aghion and Durlauf2005). On the macro level, some studies empirically identify the effects of economic performance on political institutions (e.g., La Porta et al., Reference La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer and Vishny1999; Chong and Calderón, Reference Chong and Calderón2000).
Certain economic institutions possess particular importance for entrepreneurship, including property rights, tax codes, social insurance systems, labor market legislation, competition policy, trade policies, capital market regulation, enforcement of contracts, and law and order (Hall and Jones, Reference Hall and Jones1999). A constitution is a prime example of an economically significant political institution because of its implications for voting systems, for example, and directives controlling a country's degree of centralization and federalism (Persson and Tabellini, Reference Persson and Tabellini2004, Reference Persson, Tabellini, Weingast and Wittman2006). Institutions are both formal and informal, and can in both cases be affected by entrepreneurs.Footnote 9 It is much easier to alter formal institutions through political activity than change informal rules, such as norms, values, and codes of conduct.
Abiding entrepreneurship
The abiding market entrepreneur is the archetypical entrepreneur, the one most discussed in the literature. Productive business entrepreneurship increases an economy's degree of innovation and its ability to adapt to exogenous conditions. Innovativeness forms the core of Schumpeter's (1934) entrepreneur who disturbs the existing equilibrium, whereas Kirzner's (Reference Kirzner1973, Reference Kirzner1992) entrepreneur is marked by the ability to adapt.Footnote 10 While productive entrepreneurship is important in all economies, the need for adaptation and innovativeness depends on the external environment. For instance, in times of rapid change, driven for example by a high rate of technological progress or new supplies of resources, adaptability becomes paramount.Footnote 11
The relationship between abiding entrepreneurship and the evolution of institutions is complex. On the one hand, truly innovative entrepreneurship can create so much change that the foundation of the current institutional structure is challenged. Truly disruptive entrepreneurship, such as the successful introduction of a revolutionary new technology, can lead to the reform and dissolution of extant institutions, notably in traditional societies. Technological progress can also alter the effect of institutions; one salient and recent example is the impact of the Internet on intellectual property rights.
On the other hand, entrepreneurship can be self-perpetuating. It creates a constituency of consumers, private-sector workers, and self-employed who support productive institutions. Technological breakthroughs often offer opportunities for new entrepreneurship, both of the market and political types. No less importantly, productive entrepreneurship legitimates the institutions that foster it by creating demonstrable new wealth, products, and jobs. The American economic system, with its high degree of inequality coupled with the opportunity to grow fabulously rich, has maintained its legitimacy largely because entrepreneurs from Andrew Carnegie to Bill Gates have created new value that has benefited the general public (Acs and Phillips, Reference Acs and Phillips2002). Furthermore, entrepreneurs (and non-entrepreneurs) abiding by institutions tend to strengthen these very institutions. This is particularly important for informal institutions, such as codes of conduct and traditions, which are reinforced each time they are acknowledged and allowed to guide behavior. Regarding more formal institutions, it has been noted that the law itself derives much of its value from the respect that it is awarded (Kasper and Streit, Reference Kasper and Streit1998). Becker and Murphy (Reference Becker and Murphy2000) use the neoclassical economic framework to argue that institutions are reinforced through abiding behavior. They use the US constitution as an example of an institution whose rules have been strengthened as Americans throughout history have followed its guiding principles. In contrast, similar constitutions in other countries, notably in Latin America, have been weakened over time as each violation of its principles has reduced people's respect for the constitution and tradition.
Evasive entrepreneurship
In the case of evasive entrepreneurship, the activities of the entrepreneur do not alter the formal institutional set-up but rather the impact of institutions already in place. Imperfections in the institutional framework can be used innovatively to appropriate rents from a third party, exemplified well by the shortcomings in the protection of private property rights. Agents may act on such institutional flaws by outright theft, fraud, litigation, or more sophisticated economic crimes. Productive examples include entrepreneurs who pursue contractual arrangements to escape some costly institution.Footnote 12 Tax avoidance (legal) and tax evasion (illegal) are typical examples. A business-owning entrepreneur may engage in such evasive entrepreneurship to reduce costs, while other entrepreneurs, notably within tax consultancies and law firms, may found a new business based on an innovation that enables others to circumvent institutional barriers. While illegal and harmful for public finances, tax evasion can be productive if the economic activity in question would not take place without such evasion.
Other, more mundane, instances of this type include the businessman who uses his entrepreneurial talent to trace the right bureaucrat to approach with a bribe. In the simplest case, this constitutes an instance of evasive entrepreneurship. One can think of yet more elaborate situations where the entrepreneur earns money by selling services all the while utilizing knowledge of bureaucratic procedures or personal acquaintances. The bureaucrat who receives the bribe can also act entrepreneurially, by increasing the cost of abiding by the institutions, for instance.
Evasive entrepreneurship can be productive or unproductive depending on the circumstances. If a business activity would not have taken place at all without the said circumvention of laws, it may be that the evasive actions are indeed productive. Other times, the evasion of institutions results in a waste of resources (such as costly cross-border smuggling, rather than regular bulk import). More obvious examples of destructive evasive entrepreneurship include predatory (innovative) criminal activity.
Evasive behavior by entrepreneurs, including the creation of contracts to overcome institutional impediments, tends to weaken the institutions that are being evaded. A formal institution that is not enforced is likely to lose its practical relevance. The pursuance of new contractual arrangements in order to evade labor regulations provides another example of this process. As evasion spreads, regulations lose some of their bite, and may in time be abolished if not modified to deal with evasion attempts.
This race between regulators and innovative evaders is also a defining feature of the financial sector. Destructive evasive entrepreneurship in the sub-prime security market contributed to the 2008 financial crisis as implicit government guarantees were exploited by assuming excessive risk (Calomiris, Reference Calomiris2009a, Reference Calomiris2009b). Evasive entrepreneurship also caused institutions to change in this case – albeit in the other direction – making them more binding and comprehensive.
Altering entrepreneurship
Baumol (Reference Baumol1990) describes productive entrepreneurship solely in terms of private sector business activity. However, other types of entrepreneurship can also be productive. Clearly, not all political activities can be defined as rent seeking; policy innovations often improve welfare, especially in favorable institutional environments. The National Science Foundation, for example, was created in part through political entrepreneurship (Polsby, Reference Polsby1984). Good institutions do not arise out of nowhere, and are often the result of policy entrepreneurship by gifted pivotal individuals. The productive political entrepreneur deserves recognition as a fundamental agent in the economy, just like the productive market entrepreneur.
DiLorenzo (Reference DiLorenzo1988) emphasizes the unproductive and destructive activities of rent-seeking political entrepreneurs, writing that ‘[t]he essence of political entrepreneurship is to destroy wealth through negative-sum rent-seeking behavior’ (p. 66, italics in original). He maintains that ignoring political entrepreneurs has led public choice theorists to underestimate the destructive effects of politics. We conclude in turn that the focus on rent seeking has led to an underestimation of the total dynamic potential embodied in institutional change, both when channeled productively and unproductively/destructively. Both types of activities are carried out in modern developed democracies, sometimes concurrently, often leaving the observer to decide whether the policy innovation was productive or destructive (at least as long as the reform does not clearly violate Pareto efficiency). Wagner (Reference Wagner1966) argues that political entrepreneurs can substitute for the rent-seeking activities of large interest groups, which mitigates the central difficulties in overcoming collective action problems and organizing interest groups emphasized by Olson (Reference Olson1965).
The incentive structure guides the allocation of political entrepreneurial effort, just as it guides the allocation of business entrepreneurship. All societies enjoy a mix of incentives; political entrepreneurship is allocated to both productive and unproductive/destructive institutional reform efforts, in analogy to other types of entrepreneurship. Baumol's (1990) broader theory of entrepreneurship holds true for political entrepreneurship in particular. While all three types take place in all societies, relative allocation can vary greatly, helping to determine the societies’ level of welfare and rate of growth.
The same individual may shift between categories, just as a business entrepreneur may introduce a new product one year, and frivolously sue to bar competition the next. Barack Obama and other community organizers in the urban United States arguably engage in both productive political entrepreneurship (such as easing job searches in their community) and unproductive entrepreneurship (jockeying for city subsidies to their respective constituents, for example). The broader rules of the game are not changed by these activities, even if certain pieces of legislation may change. While most political entrepreneurship does not hold enough clout to fundamentally alter the rules of the game, there are examples of entrepreneurship that change institutions so much that the broader rules guiding other political entrepreneurs shift across categories. Some examples of this, such as Zimbabwe's leader Robert Mugabe, will be given later.
Entrepreneurial activity in the market is governed by a strong feedback mechanism, namely profit and survival. Where institutions are productive, individuals with socially beneficial activities make profits, thereby guiding entrepreneurial talent to inherently productive activities. Market entrepreneurship is particularly beneficial in a social sense as it can allocate resources in an efficient manner using profit and loss as a guide; where institutions are unproductive or destructive, individuals can become rich through activities that redistribute wealth, or that are purely predatory. The feedback mechanism is less powerful for political and institutional entrepreneurship, however (Glaeser, Reference Glaeser2005). Politicians can hope to be re-elected or elected/appointed to higher office, but not all policy entrepreneurs are office holders, and the political reward mechanism is rather noisy. Singapore's national leader Lee Kuan Yew was rewarded for his social reforms with a long tenure, but so were Cuba's Fidel Castro and Zimbabwe's Robert Mugabe. Constructive policy entrepreneurs are more often rewarded for good activity and punished for destructive reforms when the broader institutional setting is propitious. The quality of the meta-institutions includes the norms, values, and beliefs of the general public – better informed and more socially oriented voters are more likely to reward socially beneficial reforms (Caplan, Reference Caplan2007; Strömberg, Reference Strömberg2004). Rudolf Giuliani's tenure as Mayor of New York (1994–2001) elevated him to national prominence, since the public perceived him as having responded to the needs of the city with successful reforms.
Another, perhaps more controversial, conclusion is that market entrepreneurship is more likely to be efficient and productive than policy entrepreneurship, precisely because of the weaker feedback mechanism of the latter.Footnote 13 Although both types of activities can be unproductive when the broader institutional setting is of low quality, weak feedback mechanisms ensure that policy entrepreneurship may not be directed in a productive way, even if the meta-institutions are generally favorable. Furthermore, many barriers to political reform exist even in good institutional settings, including the need to mobilize a majority, whereas market innovations enjoy lower barriers to entry.
4. The interaction between the entrepreneur and institutions
Changes in institutions should take into account not only the direct response of entrepreneurs, but also the subsequent change of institutions through entrepreneurial feedback. This feedback may be direct or indirect. Indirect feedback occurs when policy makers or political entrepreneurs feel the need to change institutions due to the response of entrepreneurs to institutions within the given framework. Examples of indirect feedback include the effects of evasive entrepreneurship that weaken institutions (or their actual impact), a decline in productive entrepreneurship that forces institutional reform, or an increase in rent-seeking entrepreneurship that reduces the legitimacy of free-market reform.
Direct feedback includes changes in institutions by market entrepreneurs, such as transaction costs or protective technology. Thorstein Veblen argued that technological change results in new habits of life and thought, thus giving rise to new institutions (Walker, Reference Walker1977). When technology is introduced by entrepreneurs, this creates a link between entrepreneurship and institutions.Footnote 14 Yet Boettke and Leeson (Reference Boettke and Leeson2009: 57) point to a different way of altering institutions, namely through productive entrepreneurs’ ‘creation of protective technologies that secure citizens’ private property rights vis-à-vis one another’. These activities are most important in weak institutional environments, such as in many third world countries. Entrepreneurs help improve institutions by creating private protection methods that restrict predation in the absence of a well-functioning government. These include private law courts, private police protection, bilateral punishment schemes (for example ostracism), reputation mechanisms for multilateral punishment of dishonest conduct, and social norms and customs. An example of this process can be found in the informal, unwritten rules of commercial activity and private courts in tribal units in Africa. Hwang and Powell (Reference Hwang, Powell, Alvarez, Agarwal and Sorenson2005) consider the creation of standards to guide the activities of organizations – itself a form of institution – as an entrepreneurial act. In his discussion of second-best institutions, Rodrik (Reference Rodrik2008) points out that Ghanaian firms find courts too costly as a method of contract enforcement. Such firms have relied on self-organized measures of contract enforcement instead, namely relational contracting through personal relationships and repeated interactions.
Political entrepreneurship obviously houses an endogenous component. Productive political entrepreneurship improves the quality of institutions, but only in such environments with institutions of high quality where political entrepreneurship is directed towards productive activities in the first place. Conversely, political entrepreneurs in countries with low quality institutions are more likely to engage in rent-seeking activities, some of which are likely to cause institutional quality to deteriorate even further. This mechanism forms the root of the so-called curse of natural resources (e.g., Boschini et al., Reference Boschini, Pettersson and Roine2007).
The interaction between institutions and entrepreneurship is not limited to political entrepreneurship. Productive market entrepreneurship can change the operating field and create new opportunities for political entrepreneurship. British institutions, for example, not only encouraged the Industrial Revolution, they adapted rapidly to the new technology and production methods introduced by market entrepreneurs. The same is true for the recent revolution in information and communications technology centered in the United States, which evolved in tandem with institutional changes pursued by politicians that aided the growth of the venture capital industry (Fenn et al., Reference Fenn, Liang and Prowse1995; Gompers and Lerner, Reference Gompers and Lerner2004).
These examples illustrate that abiding market entrepreneurship can be complementary to altering political entrepreneurship, increasing the scope of the other by creating new opportunities. Traditional market entrepreneurship differs from other factors of production in the sense that the marginal product does not typically diminish in the supply of the factor. Additional capital competes with and generally lowers the marginal productivity of already existing capital. The same is true for additional labor. While entrepreneurs also compete with each other, entrepreneurship is distinct as a factor of production in that other people's innovations can pave the way for one's own innovations by creating further opportunities for new ventures (Holcombe, Reference Holcombe2007).Footnote 15 As we see it, such complementarity may also be true for political and business entrepreneurship. There is no guarantee that opportunities created by new reforms will be used solely for productive policy innovations. Productive market innovations may lead to destructive political innovation, especially when the broader institutional setting is less geared towards socially beneficial activity. For example, surveillance technology developed largely by entrepreneurial IT firms has been used to increase political oppression in countries such as Iran and China.
The feedback between entrepreneurship and institutions can help explain the discontinuous nature of the dynamics of economic growth. This provides one possible explanation for the phenomenon that the economies of some countries, long mired in stagnation, suddenly take off, propelled by a virtuous cycle of entrepreneurship and institutional change. The breaking point of stagnation can be either reforms by political entrepreneurs that create opportunity for market entrepreneurship, or technological change promoted by business entrepreneurs that in turn creates opportunity for productive political entrepreneurship. The growth and reform cycle continues as more market entrepreneurship raises the possibility for additional institutional reforms and political return, which leads to further growth and entrepreneurship.
5. Examples from recent history
Productive and destructive policy entrepreneurship in Singapore and Zimbabwe
Singapore's Lee Kuan Yew embodies an example of productive institutional entrepreneurship that dramatically increased productive business activity. Early in his life, he helped found a political party that eventually grew to be the largest in the city-state. He maintained cohesion and secured room for impressive reforms by forging political alliances in an ethnically fragmented country. From Singapore's independence in 1965 through 1990, Lee and his People's Action Party developed the unique set of pro-growth institutions in Singapore that would see the isolated and resource-poor country grow to become one of the richest in the world (Peebles and Wilson, Reference Peebles and Wilson2002). Singapore's soaring growth can be traced to both market entrepreneurship and foreign direct investment by large public firms. This success further strengthened the evolution of institutions through increased legitimacy for capitalism and created a pro-reform constituency. As growth took off, new investments and business ventures created the opportunity for additional policy entrepreneurship, which was readily provided. Singapore illustrates how one policy entrepreneur can positively change the entire incentive structure of a society.
Zimbabwe's Robert Mugabe, on the other hand, is the destructive equivalent of Lee Kuan Yew. His political entrepreneurship also changed the incentive structures of his country, although in the opposite direction (Meredith, Reference Meredith2002). Zimbabwe's path to wealth suffered an about-face, shifting from production to destructive rent extraction. The entrepreneur behind this transformation – Robert Mugabe – became wealthy in the transformative process, while his nation suffered. As Baumol pointed out in his original theory, there is no guarantee that an entrepreneur's wealth will be auspicious for society. Indeed, Mugabe's example allows us to point to what distinguishes our expanded theory from Baumol's own. In his theory, the institutional framework of Zimbabwe led an entrepreneur to act destructively for personal gain. In ours, the originally productive institutions of Zimbabwe were altered by the policy entrepreneur Mugabe. The incentives in the country changed as a result, with destructive entrepreneurship becoming the easiest path to wealth for thousands of Zimbabweans, whose predatory behavior also destroyed some of the wealth of the country; indeed, the successful occupation of a farm requires alertness, organizational power, and risk-taking. Previously productive entrepreneurs were put out of business, and many left the country altogether. Zimbabwe illustrates that destructive institutional entrepreneurship can be much more powerful than destructive abiding entrepreneurship.
Interaction of political and productive entrepreneurship in China
China's two-fold transition to a Socialist command economy and later back to one of the fastest growing countries in the world exemplifies some of the interactions between entrepreneurship and institutions. China is a particularly interesting case since entrepreneurs have also been key agents in the more recent transition from Socialist planning. The move to a full-blown Socialist regime after the Communist revolution in 1949 was a gradual process completed in 1956/57.Footnote 16 Step-by-step, private enterprise was circumscribed as more and more sectors were collectivized and government involvement in management was extended. In a first move taking place between 1949 and 1952, private financial institutions were nationalized and private capital markets were shut down. The government began placing processing orders with private producers and took charge of most resource allocation. Plans for production and sales had to be approved by officials.
Entrepreneurs were still allowed to engage on the market and respond to market signals, but the institutional reforms brought about far-reaching changes in their operations. Entrepreneurial activity was reduced to a contest for winning orders and escaping controls. At the same time, the system offered ample opportunities for officials in charge of processing orders and means of production to earn rents through corruption. The consequences for private firms and the economy as a whole were highly detrimental. In 1951, the government began to strike back at these so-called ‘five evils’: bribery of government officials, tax evasion, theft of state property, cheating on government contracts, and theft of economic information for speculative purposes. The blame was largely directed towards the private sector and resulted in an accelerated rate of collectivization and nationalization of resources.
The Communist takeover radically changed China's institutional setup, with the new institutions drastically decreasing incentives for productive entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurs were forced to expend more effort on evasive activities. The new institutions also provided fertile soil for unproductive forms of entrepreneurship. Rents could be earned by competing for bureaucratic positions that functioned as gatekeepers for licenses and government contracts. These changes legitimated demands for further institutional reforms. Radical Communist factions gained political power as private enterprise was blamed for the malfunctioning quasi-Socialist economy. The increased power of these groups induced further changes in economic institutions.
Soon enough, a political entrepreneur came to the aid of business entrepreneurship. After the death of Mao in 1976, Deng Xiaoping rose to power in 1978 and initiated reforms that extended the scope of private enterprise. The subsequent events illustrate the endogenous relationship between entrepreneurial activities and institutions. Unlike the transformation in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe, Deng's reforms were far from wholesale privatization (Heilmann, Reference Heilmann2008). Rather, they opened small arenas for productive business entrepreneurship at first, sometimes abiding and sometimes evading. The initially small productive sector of the Chinese economy began to grow year by year through successful entrepreneurial ventures (Tsai, Reference Tsai2006).
One example of the role of the entrepreneur in the ensuing transformation of Chinese institutions was the implementation of the practice of ‘contract-production-to-household’, which allocated land to households on a long-term basis and allowed farmers to retain profits. This practice was officially endorsed in 1983, but had already been widely adopted in practice. The former laws that had prohibited private profits from household farming had lost all practical relevance. Another example is the policy document enforced in 1981, which allowed limited private enterprise, with severe restrictions on the maximum number of employees (two employees and five apprentices). However, these limitations did little to constrict the size of private firms, of which many grew well beyond the permitted size. By the end of 1986, an official survey showed that a large number of firms had exceeded the stipulated limits. New institutional reforms in 1987/88 later granted these firms legitimate status. Lu (Reference Lu1994: 117) concludes that ‘the Chinese policy makers did not pre-design the boom of the private sector in the 1980s and the relating changes in institutions. In many cases, what happened was the official adaptation to reforms initiated by private entrepreneurs.’
Deng's small windows of productive entrepreneurship opened up the entire system in time. China's new productive institutions were greatly strengthened through abiding productive ventures, and have now organically evolved from exceptions to the dominant institutions of Chinese society. As incentives changed, talented individuals shifted from government employment or Communist Party careers to private enterprise (sometimes combining the two in a unique Chinese mix). Political support for productive activity grew as a larger part of the elite began to derive its income from these institutions. While business entrepreneurs were presumably driven by a profit motive, the political class also had stronger incentives to support reform.Footnote 17 Without these feedback mechanisms, it is unlikely that reform would have been so far-reaching.
Daokui et al. (Reference Daokui, Feng and Jiang2006) argue that market entrepreneurs help improve institutions by starting a business venture, thereby contributing to the destruction of prevailing institutions that are unfavorable to entrepreneurship. Apart from open advocacy of reforms and the private persuasion of politicians, they mention two other strategies. The first involves a business owner who claims that he represents a special case, and that exceptions should be made for him. Once a concession has been made, additional concessions are easier to obtain, eventually adding up to a de facto change in institutions. The other strategy requires one to circumvent regulations and, once a successful enterprise has been established, argue for an ex post modification. This type of entrepreneurship has, according to the authors, changed the institutional environment not only in China but also in other rapidly growing economies such as India and Vietnam. As observed by Gilley (Reference Gilley, Bonnell and Gold2002), Chinese politicians appointed at the local level frequently have a background as former (or current) entrepreneurs.Footnote 18
The Chinese experience also highlights the role of productive evasive entrepreneurship as an engine for institutional change. Although many of the Chinese institutions that imposed restrictions on entrepreneurship were still in place in the mid-1970s, the political will to enforce such restrictions weakened under Deng Xiaoping, and the institutions were eventually phased out as attention waned. The risk of sanctions – and thereby the cost of evading the institutions in question – decreased significantly, enhancing productive entrepreneurial activity. This was a cumulative process by which the costs of evading regulation fell to a level where the institutions had lost all practical relevance, and in the end they were formally abolished.
The Chinese experience also indicates that institutions can affect not only the direction of entrepreneurship, but also its total supply. It would be difficult to argue that the torrent of entrepreneurial business activity that has been unleashed during the last few years, transforming not only the Chinese but also the world economy, does not represent an increase over previous levels. Even when taking into account rent-seeking activity, evasion, and political entrepreneurship within the Communist party, China doubtlessly has more entrepreneurship in its current institutional framework than under pure Communism.
A vicious cycle of unproductive entrepreneurship in post-transition Russia
According to Åslund et al. (Reference Åslund, Bonne and Johnson2002), post-Soviet Russia is locked in an ‘under-reform trap’. Institutions that reward rent seeking more than productive activities dominate the economy, and political influence from the Russian private sector can often be traced to oligarchs (Guriev and Rachinsky, Reference Guriev and Rachinsky2005). This group consists of people from the former Soviet nomenclature who seized power over the companies they managed after the fall of the Soviet Union. The oligarchs took advantage of the huge arbitrage opportunities created by partial reforms and the co-existence of regulated and quasi-market prices during the Gorbachev era.
There is no denying that rising from virtually nothing to amassing billions in the era of reform required entrepreneurial talent. However, most activity was non-productive; wealth was generated by taking control over firms or plundering them rather than creating new value. Kalantaridis and Labrianidis (Reference Kalantaridis and Labrianidis2004: 663) argue that the most important group of entrepreneurs during the transition period was the ‘directors of the Socialist Era’ who were ‘individuals in positions of authority during the Socialist Era, who adapted successfully to change’. While the allocation of entrepreneurs from a Socialist system to a free market system may seem dramatic, the move was modest seen through the framework of this paper. Largely unproductive entrepreneurship under the low-quality Soviet institutions moved to largely unproductive entrepreneurship in the only marginally less distortive institutions of the transition era.
Unproductive entrepreneurship in Russia proved self-reinforcing in at least two ways. For one, the legitimacy of free market capitalism was deeply damaged by the initial era of unproductive entrepreneurship. Second, the current oligarchs continue to use their political power to defend the current system, exemplified by their takeover of the Russian Union of Industrialists and Entrepreneurs. Slinko et al. (Reference Slinko, Yakovlev and Zhuravskaya2005) underscore the negative effect of the establishment's political influence, finding that large firms with high political stakes can prevent entry of new firms. Aidis et al. (Reference Aidis, Estrin and Mickiewicz2008) show that Russia has less business entrepreneurship than other transition countries, and that Russian institutions provide advantages to insiders over new ventures. In comparison to other transition economies, Russian entrepreneurs face more corruption, higher official and unofficial start-up costs, higher tax rates, more bureaucracy, and weaker protection of property rights (Åslund et al., Reference Åslund, Bonne and Johnson2002). Contrasting Russia's current trap with the virtuous cycle of institutional reform and entrepreneurship in China makes for an interesting task, and may offer hints about how to escape a bad equilibrium.
The market entrepreneur as political entrepreneur in Italy
Italian Prime Minister Silvio Berlusconi represents a conspicuous example of an individual who acted both as a business entrepreneur and as a political entrepreneur, profoundly affecting institutions in both roles. Circumventing laws that only allowed Italian public television to broadcast nationally, he set up a system of local stations that broadcast the same programs simultaneously. In doing so, Berlusconi essentially created Italy's first private national television network. Italian public television capitulated in due course, allowing free competition over the airwaves. This is a striking example of how evasive entrepreneurship can alter institutions.Footnote 19 On the one hand, the reform shows a form of productive entrepreneurship, simply because there was a demand for private entertainment television in Italy. On the other hand, Berlusconi's political exploitation of his private control over television networks has been deemed socially destructive by some observers, which complicates matters. Throughout his business career, Berlusconi has not shied away from using his political connection to extract rents and favors for himself. His case illustrates that political entrepreneurship can be both productive and unproductive at the same time.
The story does not end there, however. Aided by his media empire, Berlusconi ventured into large-scale political entrepreneurship, shattering the previous Italian party system. The political party he founded grew to be the largest one in the most recent Italian elections. By changing the election laws and arduously forming new alliances, he transformed Italy into what resembles a two-party system. Berlusconi used his political power to dramatically alter Italian formal institutions in several more important dimensions, largely to aid his own private ventures and to shield himself from legal action.
Needless to say, Berlusconi is not only a mover of certain Italian institutions, but also a product of the country's broader institutional setting. More than other western countries, Italy combines rigid regulations with endemic evasion. Berlusconi's dual involvement in politics and business was aided by his early political connections, which are common for successful businessmen in contemporary Italy. While posterity will have to determine whether Berlusconi's political entrepreneurship was largely productive or destructive, his case illustrates without a doubt that entrepreneurs are not only influenced by the institutional setting, but can shape institutions themselves.
Welfare state entrepreneurship in Sweden
The Swedish example illustrates several venues of interaction between institutions and entrepreneurship. Unlike other examples, high level of wealth produced by entrepreneurship did not initially lead to a virtuous cycle of further institutional improvements, instead funding a welfare state that was detrimental to market entrepreneurship. In addition, and perhaps partially in lieu of private sector innovativeness and talent, Sweden offered a well-functioning political system amenable to political entrepreneurship. Because of the responsiveness of political entrepreneurship to diminished market entrepreneurship, the institutional environment was ultimately reformed to become more favorable for market entrepreneurs.
Between 1870 and 1970, Sweden enjoyed a fertile institutional climate for market entrepreneurship, which resulted in the second highest growth rate in the world over that century (Maddison, Reference Maddison1982). Based on this wealth, Social-Democratic Sweden implemented policies in the post-war period that eroded the accumulation of household assets, constrained private ownership of the business sector and, ultimately, diminished productive business entrepreneurship. As Henrekson and Jakobsson (Reference Henrekson and Jakobsson2001) show, tax and industrial policies moved the economy towards larger business entities and institutional rather than individual ownership. Tax policy created a large wedge between wealth accumulation at the corporate and individual levels, thereby benefiting large incumbent firms over new entrants and individual entrepreneurs.Footnote 20 Export firms, often initially founded by individual entrepreneurs, had by this time grown into large public companies, providing the economic base of the welfare state. The major incumbent owners managed to retain control, despite this large wedge, through a growing disparity between control rights and cash-flow rights. A number of devices were used to achieve this, the most important of which were dual-class shares and pyramiding with tax-favored closed-end investment funds as the prime control vehicle. By the late 1980s, it became apparent that higher taxes and such intrusions in market mechanisms had taken a heavy toll on economic growth and productive business entrepreneurship. Virtually all the 50 largest firms in Sweden in the year 2000 were founded before 1970 (Henrekson, Reference Henrekson2005). The lack of productive business entrepreneurship has been called ‘the Achilles heel of the Swedish welfare state’ (Högfeldt, Reference Högfeldt and Morck2005).
A balanced history of the welfare state should account for its successes and failures at one and the same time. As productive business entrepreneurship was hampered in Sweden, a corresponding increase in unproductive entrepreneurship did not occur, in contrast to what the Baumol (Reference Baumol1990) framework would suggest. Sweden's political institutions worked reasonably well throughout the era, with little evidence of rent seeking. One interpretation could take up the stifling, long-run effects of Social Democratic institutions on the total supply of entrepreneurship, which led to a decrease in productive entrepreneurship but no corresponding increase in unproductive/destructive entrepreneurship.Footnote 21 While total entrepreneurship declined, political entrepreneurship was on the rise. However, in contrast to what Baumol's theory would predict, this political entrepreneurship was not unproductive. Rather, Sweden channeled much of its innovative energy of this period into welfare state entrepreneurship, pioneering policies that were later adopted by other countries (Pontusson, Reference Pontusson2005). This includes the health care system, social insurance, active labor market programs, and the care of children and the elderly. The political system was attentive to the changing needs of industry (Steinmo, Reference Steinmo2010). In addition, there was a myriad of policies at the municipal level aimed at producing local public goods. Much of the country's talent that would have otherwise gone to the private sector was drawn into the public sector. Talented individuals, including Nobel laureates, were attracted to the creation of the new system and helped design and improve the welfare state.
A public sector as large and intrusive as the Swedish one would not have functioned without a focus on mitigating incentive problems as much as possible (Freeman et al., Reference Freeman, Topel and Swedenborg1997; Lindert, Reference Lindert2004). In order to ensure high labor force participation, despite punitive tax levels, participating in the labor force became a requirement for access to many highly subsidized services and transfers (Lindbeck, Reference Lindbeck1982). Furthermore, women's participation was encouraged by subsidizing consumption complementary to work. The system was responsive above all. Government programs were continuously reformed in order to maintain economic performance. Social insurance programs whose generosity was being exploited were often quickly reformed. In many ways the Swedish system outperformed others, not necessarily in an absolute sense, but compared to the likely outcome in other countries had they ventured this far in expanding the welfare state. Continental European countries such as France and Belgium with lower taxes have fewer hours worked than Sweden. Recent research on taxes and hours worked in Europe has identified Sweden and other similar Scandinavian countries as positive ‘outliers’ in the relationship between taxation and work, a fact attributed to the unique design of public spending programs aimed at mitigating the problems caused by the high levels of taxation (Rogerson, Reference Rogerson2007).
The high degree of productive political entrepreneurship in the Swedish system became most apparent as the problems of the welfare state grew in its mature phase. The country responded by rolling back some of the most far-reaching reform programs in history (Bergh and Erlingsson, Reference Bergh and Erlingsson2009; Steinmo, Reference Steinmo2010). This included a fundamental tax reform, financial deregulation, restructuring of macroeconomic policy, reduction of the generosity of social insurance programs, transformation of the pension system, and modification of labor market policies. While we do not want to push the story too hard – many problems remain in the Swedish economy, in particular a high level of unemployment in marginal groups – Sweden's adaptive responsiveness has contained a high degree of productive political entrepreneurship. As a result, room for business entrepreneurship has also increased. Most of the underlying principles of the welfare state were maintained, but the system became much more favorable for productive business entrepreneurship.
This showcases another aspect of the interaction between institutions and entrepreneurship. When the institutions that guide politics and political entrepreneurship are of sufficient quality, the political system will have a highly elastic supply of productive policy entrepreneurship. In such an environment, the institutions that regulate market activity are unlikely to be allowed to evolve in too detrimental a fashion. The welfare state institutions were bounded by their impact on the supply of business entrepreneurship, and ultimately reformed in order to stimulate the supply of new rapidly growing firms again.
6. Conclusion
This paper expands on the framework introduced by Baumol (Reference Baumol1990). Entrepreneurship is not only shaped by institutions, it also influences institutions in turn. On the one hand, entrepreneurs choose how to employ their entrepreneurial talent depending on the relevant incentive structure determined by the pertinent institutions. In this way, institutions fundamentally determine the distribution across productive, unproductive, and destructive entrepreneurial activities. On the other hand, entrepreneurs respond actively to the environment they face, which tends to affect institutions.
Since these types of activities all involve a measure of innovation, politicians cannot fully anticipate these effects when designing institutions. Our analysis highlights the need to view the formation of institutions as an adaptive process. Politicians cannot design optimal institutions once and for all; unpredictable entrepreneurial responses to these institutions will force them to respond by continually changing and amending the institutional environment.
Designers of institutions should attempt to take into account the reaction of entrepreneurs to the rules (which, by nature, are hard to anticipate), and the ultimate outcome which is determined by the interaction of the policy entrepreneurs and the market entrepreneurs. The regulatory game between financial actors and financial regulators is a particularly important example of this phenomenon. A reform that is welfare improving given the current economy may not be wise to undertake if it can be expected to invite entrepreneurial exploitation. The most obvious recent example is again in the field of financial regulation. In contrast, a reform that has little positive impact given the current state of the world, but invites productive entrepreneurial entry (be it market entrepreneurship or further policy entrepreneurship) should be judged more favorably. Examples include deregulation of the telecom industry that, after a non-negligible lag, helped bring about the communication revolution. Research on the political economy of entrepreneurship cannot be restricted to just analyzing how institutions affect the level and type of entrepreneurial activity, but it preferably ought to incorporate the reverse line of causality as well as the interplay of the two.
It is also necessary to consider how entrepreneurial activities affect institutions and thereby the prospects for long-term growth. Institutional changes aimed at promoting entrepreneurship must always be evaluated with respect to what kind of entrepreneurship is promoted. A tax hike may not only deter productive entrepreneurs, but also encourage unproductive entrepreneurship. Baumol (Reference Baumol1990) showed that institutions should be designed to promote productive market entrepreneurship compared to unproductive rent seeking. In addition, broader institutions should at best be designed in a way to increase the chance of future productive policy entrepreneurship, as well as virtuous cycles of productive market entrepreneurship followed by further improvement of institutions. This characterizes the race between technology and innovations (which are to a considerable extent entrepreneurial in nature) and formal rules in well-governed economies, such as during the industrial revolution and again during the recent IT-boom.
Finally, it is worth asking whether altering political entrepreneurship can change the allocation of political entrepreneurship. Most political entrepreneurship is too insignificant to palpably change the broader incentive structures. The allocation and lucrativeness of policy entrepreneurship itself changes, however, either through comprehensive acts of reform by single policy entrepreneurs or through slow incremental change.
In terms of contemporary protracted reform, various reform-minded policy entrepreneurs are slowly bringing the old statist system to an end. An example of more radical change is the promise to stifle lobbying in the United States (not yet realized at the time of writing). Such an act of large-scale policy entrepreneurship could change institutions enough to alter the allocation of multitudes of smaller scale policy entrepreneurship, presumably reducing unproductive political entrepreneurship. There would be positive multipliers associated with this reform due to the mechanisms we have pointed to. Not only would unproductive lobbying be reduced, some of the entrepreneurial resources could also be redirected to business entrepreneurship or more productive political entrepreneurship. Perhaps some of these activities would someday in turn lead to additional institutional improvements. The gains from channeling entrepreneurship into productive use is thus larger than a narrow look at the market activity would suggest, and larger still due to (by its nature) hard-to-anticipate improvements in institutions.