Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-d8cs5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T05:14:01.185Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The fundamental Coase of development: property rights foundations of the effective state

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 June 2020

Ennio E. Piano*
Affiliation:
Middle Tennessee State University, Murfreesboro, TN, USA
Alexander W. Salter
Affiliation:
Texas Tech University, Lubbock, TX, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: Ennio.Piano@MTSU.Edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper identifies political property rights and jurisdictional rivalry as two important mechanisms that drive political and economic development. After developing a general framework to explain relative performance in the ‘market for governance’, we argue that Western Europe during the High Middle Ages presented initial conditions conducive to the development of effective states. We extend the framework by analyzing city-state governance in Renaissance Italy, as well as public finance practices in early modern Germany. We conclude by discussing the implications of our argument for the literature on state capacity and economic development. The takeaway is that well-aligned political property rights and competition in the provision of governance services can promote the protective and productive state while forestalling the predatory state.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2020

1. Introduction

In a book that will influence scholarly conversations for some time to come, Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2019) argue that countries can only become wealthy if their governments are simultaneously strong and responsible. When Leviathan is absent, they argue, societies descend into tribal conflict. When Leviathan is despotic, the centralized state crushes economic initiative. Only when Leviathan is shackled can societies escape the Malthusian trap. But who, or what, does the shackling? Acemoglu and Robinson's answer is the institutions of civil society, which serve as a contravening source of authority. We find much of value in their thesis. We also believe there is more to the story. Focusing on the Western nations since the High Middle Ages, we pose our own answer as to how societies can build a protective and productive state while avoiding a predatory state (cf. Buchanan, Reference Buchanan2000). We suggest the twin mechanisms of political property rights and jurisdictional competition can help achieve this. We offer these mechanisms as one way to solve the ultimate political-economic problem posed by Acemoglu and Robinson. In other words, Acemoglu and Robinson have identified a problem that all societies must solve to become wealthy. We argue for one specific way to solve that problem, as well as offer historical evidence of the solution at work.

Related work has identified the ‘effective state’ as necessary for sustained economic growth (Besley and Persson, Reference Besley and Persson2010; Johnson and Koyama, Reference Johnson and Koyama2017).Footnote 1 Most of this work falls within one of the following categories: (1) identifying the causal effect of state capacity on long-run economic performance (Dincecco and Prado, Reference Dincecco and Prado2012); (2) identifying the determinants of different levels of state capacity across time and space (Besley and Persson, Reference Besley and Persson2009); and (3) historical case studies of the evolution of effective states (or lack thereof) in different contexts (Acemoglu et al., Reference Acemoglu, Moscona and Robinson2016; Grassi and Memoli, Reference Grassi and Memoli2016; Muralidharan et al., Reference Muralidharan, Niehaus and Sukhtankar2016). However, this literature lacks a theoretical framework capable of explaining the evolution of the (Western European) state since the decline of feudalism. In particular, the literature has failed to address the distributional consequences of the rise of the modern state. In other words, why did political elites not use state capacity to enrich themselves at the expense of the rest of society? As in countless other societies, this would have made elites rich, while everyone else stayed poor. Although some predation did continue, what instead resulted was a generalized increase in living standards. Elites got richer over time, but everyone else got richer, too. In the European experience, rulers' investment in state capacity came about alongside an increase in the supply of public goods and generalized enforcement of property rights and contracts.Footnote 2

What explains these facts? We offer a theory that incorporates two fundamental mechanisms from the ‘market for governance’.Footnote 3 The first is political property rights (Salter, Reference Salter2015). These refer to control over the use of political assets, and the stream of returns generated therefrom.Footnote 4 The second is jurisdictional competition. Combining the two, we develop a framework to study governance institutions, their relationship with economic performance, and their distributional effects.

Our theory can explain why some countries experienced a generalized increase in living standards following the rise of strong centralized states (Dincecco, Reference Dincecco2015; Onis, Reference Onis1991), whereas others saw only the accumulation of wealth by the ruling class (Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012). The development of state capacity in the West resulted in economic success because it took place against a backdrop of well-aligned political property rights among competing ‘realm-owners’. The context within which state capacity develops plays a fundamental role in determining its form, function, and trajectory. One cannot understand the historical development of the effective state in Europe if one ignores the institutional context within which European rulers invested in state capacity. Even more fundamentally, without such context, one cannot understand why this investment took the form that it did. The development of the protective–productive state in Western Europe was the result of the peculiar governance structure that characterized the region during the High Middle Ages.Footnote 5 This was a polycentric governance structure (Aligica and Tarko, Reference Aligica and Tarko2013; Ostrom, Reference Ostrom2009; Thrasher and Vallier, Reference Thrasher and Vallier2018), in which competition for a mobile tax base constituted a de facto constraint on the ruler's predatory ambitions (North, Reference North1979).Footnote 6 Competition among governance providers, in turn, created a sociopolitical ‘space’ in which commercial society could flourish (Cox, Reference Cox2017; Lopez, Reference Lopez1976). The combined effect of the effective allocation of residual claimancy across different political actors and the presence of jurisdictionally competitive pressures led to market-like institutions that facilitated informational feedback and aligned incentives. The result was rising productivity rather than devolution to predation or rent-seeking (Salter, Reference Salter2015). Against this backdrop, the growth of state capacity resulted in the rise of the effective state.Footnote 7

Our argument relates to the idea of state capacity in two ways. First, we question the usefulness of state capacity as an explanation for long-run growth. If state capacity takes radically different forms depending on the circumstances within which it develops, looking at it in isolation will not much help us understand economic and political development across time or space. As a result, we should become more skeptical of claims that investments in state capacity are the solution to the problem of development in Least Developed Countries. Thus, we see our main contribution as a corrective of a growing body of literature in the social sciences that focuses on state capacity to the exclusion of other institutional factors.

Second, to isolate the social-scientific mechanisms that are actually ‘doing the work’, we dehomogenize state-capacity through the ‘political property rights’ framework developed by Salter (Reference Salter2015) and expanded, among others, by Young (Reference Young2016), Murtazashvili and Murtazashvili (Reference Murtazashvili and Murtazashvili2019), and Piano (Reference Piano2019). We also revive the classic view of the role of inter-jurisdictional competition in the development of Western Europe. Both approaches take inspiration from the work of Barzel (Reference Barzel2002) and Libecap (Reference Libecap1993). Our analysis also complements existing studies on the role of institutions as determinants of economic development (Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2019; DeLong and Shleifer, Reference DeLong and Shleifer1993; Nunn, Reference Nunn2009). Similar to Acemoglu and Robinson (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012), we wish to explain why societies diverge in their trajectory of political and economic development, with some adopting ‘inclusive institutions’ and others ‘extractive ones’.Footnote 8

Our framework shares some similarities with that of North et al. (Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009). Both focus on how property rights affect the interaction between elites and subjects and between members of the elites. For example, North et al. (Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009) emphasize that the extension of the rule of law outside of the ruling coalition will only occur when this move is consistent with the interest of its members. They also make the rise of institutions that reduce the costs of organizing political exchange a key part of their story. This led to more robust political property rights (although they do not use that terminology). Overall, the most important agreement between our framework and theirs is that political institutions exist to minimize losses from violence in society. However, our framework differs from theirs in two critical respects. First, beliefs and ideology play a significant role in their story, whereas we mostly abstract from them. Second, inter-jurisdictional competition is central to our argument and only marginal to theirs. Although they recognize that jurisdictional competition between open-access orders helps to keep them from ‘regressing’ to natural states (North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009), we claim that jurisdictional competition was crucial to the emergence of open-access orders in the first place.

The core of our argument is the application of Coase's (Reference Coase1960) insights into non-market decision making, which explains our paper's title. Building on the literature that extends transaction cost analysis to the study of political institutions, we conceive effective states as bundles of political property rights that align the interests of rulers with the welfare of the ruled.Footnote 9 Well-aligned political property rights (e.g. Salter and Young, Reference Salter and Young2018, Reference Salter and Young2019) give rulers an incentive to act in a manner conducive to broad-based economic prosperity, as well as the information required to do so.Footnote 10 The remainder of our argument is organized as follows. Section 2 develops the theoretical framework. Sections 3, 4, and 5 provide analytical narratives of three historical case studies of Medieval Western Europe, Renaissance Italian city-states, and Early Modern Germany, respectively. Section 6 concludes with a brief discussion of political property rights, state capacity, and inclusive institutions.

2. Rivalry and residual claimancy in the market for governance

The notion of economic property rights refers to the ability of individuals to dispose freely of the services of their assets, whether through consumption or exchange (Allen, Reference Allen1991). Social scientists usually employ this notion when analyzing market behavior and institutions, although it has been extended to the study of non-market contexts also.Footnote 11 Property rights are harder to enforce in political exchanges (Acemoglu, Reference Acemoglu2003; Barzel, Reference Barzel2002). Nevertheless, the control of political assets (e.g. a committee chair, an elected office, an army, and a territory) is desirable, and political agents will use valuable resources to achieve it (Salter, Reference Salter2015).

Similar to economic property rights, political property rights will be effectively aligned whenever residual claimancy over the services of an asset (or on the different attributes of the asset) is allocated to that individual or group whose actions have the most significant effect on its value.Footnote 12 Political markets across time and space have developed all sorts of institutions and mechanisms to facilitate interactions between political agents, such as the exchange of hostages in Medieval Europe, the venality of public offices, and the committee system in the US Congress.Footnote 13

To be effective, an allocation of political property rights must generate incentives to maximize the value of political assets, net of transaction costs. When political property rights are not so aligned, private and social optimality may not coincide. This is best exemplified by Olson's comparison of roving and stationary bandits (Olson, Reference Olson1993). A roving bandit moves from territory to territory, taking all it can from each and moving on to the next. A stationary bandit rules over a territory and defends it from other bandits' attacks.Footnote 14 The two bandits differ in the degree to which they benefit from reducing their plundering of the territory. Roving bandits gain nothing from this because everything they do not take other bandits will. Hence roving bandits loot all they can, and, in response, the villagers reduce their production efforts. Stationary bandits benefit from reducing predation at the margin because what they do not take villagers get to keep, which increases their willingness to produce in the first place. Thus, stationary bandits can secure for themselves a more sizeable stream of payments throughout time. The lesson of the story is that strengthening the bandit's residual claimancy over the realm reduces the value of wealth dissipated in equilibrium.Footnote 15

Even in the presence of well-allocated political property rights, humans are bound to make some mistakes. In the context of politics, fallible actors will often implement policies that are incompatible with the maximization of the value of the realm.Footnote 16 Evolutionary forces can reduce the effects of misguided policies and suboptimal strategies. As an example, in the market, firm owners may not know precisely the marginal cost of producing q*, but only those firms whose price approximates the marginal cost will survive, whereas the system filters out all others (Albrecht et al., Reference Albrecht, Hendrickson and Salter2018; Alchian, Reference Alchian1950).Footnote 17

Realm owners are likely to be more prone to make mistakes than market entrepreneurs.Footnote 18 The goods and services they provide tend to have public good-like features and are allocated according to a logic other than that of markets. The absence of markets in politics prevents one from using market-generated prices as guideposts for ascertaining best practices (Hayek, Reference Hayek1945). However, rivalry between jurisdictions may approximate the result of standard markets (Tiebout, Reference Tiebout1956). Realm owners that adopt extremely destructive policies, or that extract too high a portion of the wealth generated from their subjects, will tend to go out of business as they lose their tax-base to others.

The combination of well-aligned political property rights and inter-jurisdictional competition favors the adoption of optimal governance strategies in the short-run and the evolution of political institutions with wealth-generating properties in the long run.Footnote 19 Well-aligned political property rights minimize the extent of misguided policy-making, whereas jurisdictional rivalry discourages rulers' predatory behavior.

The absence of competitive pressure means that the elite will be able to extract a larger share of the surplus of these innovations from their subjects. Over time, realm owners will adopt the policies and institutions characteristic of predatory states (Moselle and Polak, Reference Moselle and Polak2001; Murtazashvili and Murtazashvili, Reference Murtazashvili and Murtazashvili2016; Vahabi, Reference Vahabi2016). In the opposite scenario, political property rights are not effectively aligned; multiple competing actors can exercise violence within the realm. There is little to no incentive for them to adopt policies and institutions that make the economy more productive. The output of the realm being effectively in the public domain, none of them can expect to capture the benefits of adopting ‘good governance’. Pillaging becomes the dominant strategy for every actor.

The above foreshadows the distinction between an effective state and a predatory state. In the former, there needs to be some institutional mechanism aligning bandits' incentives. An effective state is one in which the ruler has low costs of monitoring and measuring the performance of its subjects, but the subjects can move to the land of a different ruler relatively easily. A predatory state is one in which monitoring costs are low, but the costs of moving away are high. Thus, a predatory state may achieve significant levels of productivity. The result will differ from that of effective states in that the fruit of higher productivity are enjoyed by the many rather than the few.

This discussion suggests potential sources of exogenous variation. Geographic and environmental characteristics can affect the costs of measurement, monitoring, and exit. So does technology. For example, it is hard to imagine the Soviet Block being able to enforce its policy against free-movement (both within the block and away from it) without 20th-century technology. This enabled the Soviet Union to employ its vast bureaucratic apparatus toward the extraction of wealth from its population.Footnote 20

The framework we develop gives us some insights into the process of political development. It also points to the importance of political property rights and jurisdictional competition in this process. In the next three sections, we discuss some evidence that the interplay between these two dimensions played an essential role in the evolution of political institutions in Western Europe.

3. The governance structure of Medieval Europe

In this section, we investigate the political situation that characterized Western Europe at the starting point of the process of political development. The eventual result was the rise of the effective state, one characterized by a comparatively efficient and nondiscriminatory administrative structure in the late modern period. We focus on the political property rights that characterized the regions' political organization and the degree of jurisdictional rivalry between political authorities. The combination of (a) political property rights' allocation based on the ability to influence the region's productivity and (b) jurisdictional competition generated the right conditions for a general increase in standards of living.

3.1 Political property rights in Medieval Europe

The governance structure of Medieval Europe was fundamentally polycentric (Rosenberg and Birdzell, Reference Rosenberg and Birdzell2008). Multiple authorities with overlapping jurisdictions, each with its own specific set of rights-claims under their purview, supplied protection and a few other services to the inhabitants of Western Europe. Property rights over the political assets from one territory was divided to reflect each player's ability to affect their value.

The origins of this governance process trace back to the centuries following the fall of the Roman Empire. Early on, this process consisted of a multitude of wandering barbarian tribes, which roved and pillaged the settled locals (Young, Reference Young2016, Reference Young2018). Following these events, many of Rome's aristocratic families sook refuge within the administrative structure (and sometimes the physical fortresses) of the Roman Catholic Church. The higher ranks of the Church were themselves owners of large tracts of lands (and many of the assets therein), over which they exercised a mix of spiritual and temporal authority. Over time, the wandering tribes settled and started their own hereditary aristocracies. By the late Middle Ages, the territories once occupied by the Roman Empire were governed by a varied set of overlapping jurisdictions: monasteries, universities, guilds, chartered cities, and communes co-existed with the (sometimes nominal) sovereignty of the barbarian kings (Fink, Reference Fink2012; Levy, Reference Levy2014).

This de facto medieval constitution is characterized by divided political power, with groups rivaling each other over the ability to exert dominion over people and resources. The feudal order of Medieval Western Europe was defined by the presence of numerous centers of hierarchically organized authority. Members of every one level exercised direct authority over those of the level just below, and were sworn to obedience and bound to a set of obligations (mostly of military character) to those above them (Volckart, Reference Volckart2000). This allocation was an efficient response to technological and environmental constraints. A medieval king was poorly positioned to affect the value of a piece of land, nominally his own, while hundreds of miles away. Instead, residual claimancy was mostly allocated down the hierarchy to local lords and their vassals in exchange for military support and other obligations (Contamine, Reference Contamine1986: 77).Footnote 21

The importance of the medieval constitution for later state development lies in the initial structure of political property rights. The essential feature of a political property right is that it grants an individual, or a group of individuals, the right to participate in governance and allocates to them a portion of the revenues generated therefrom (Salter, Reference Salter2015). The medieval constitution represented an institutional equilibrium in which owners of economic property rights over land, capital, and labor services also wielded political authority. One of the critical features of this system was the division of power between competing interest groups, each checking the other's predation (Young, Reference Young2016).

Diffused realm ownership was conducive to the minimization of wealth dissipation. Each realm shareholder would want the system to maximize the capitalized value of their political assets. Consensual decision-making among these shareholders would sometimes give way to armed conflict, as elites took advantage of the perceived insecurity of their rivals' political property rights, and attempted to seize these rights for themselves. Though conflict was always a possibility, it was usually limited to the resolution of specific disputes over political property rights. The mass warfare of modernity was neither feasible nor desirable from the point of view of medieval elites. They lacked the resources necessary for large-scale military mobilization and were aware of the potentially destructive effects of armed conflict on their assets.

3.2 Rivalrous supply of medieval governance

By the turn of the 9th century, a handful of kingdoms controlled the entirety of Western Europe. The Carolingian Empire extended over France, northern and central Italy, the Alps, and a large chunk of Germany. The remainder of the Italian peninsula was divided between the last Lombard kingdom and the western dominions of the Eastern Roman (Byzantine) Empire. The Islamic Caliphate was about to complete its conquest of the Iberian Peninsula, although the Christian Asturian kingdom preserved its independence in the northwest. Each crown's degree of control plummeted the further one moved away from the sovereign's demesne. De facto control was a function of the local lords' loyalty to their monarch. Given the inability of the latter to enforce his claim over the periphery of his own kingdom, these territories were effectively left in the public domain, their resources being up for grabs by adventurous foreign lords as well as hordes of nomads coming from the East. These circumstances had the effect of reducing even further the ruler's incentive to provide public goods across his realm, being unable to protect much of the realm from capture from outsiders.

Four hundred years later, the number of sovereign polities was much higher. The process started around the year 1150 and continued almost uninterrupted for the following two centuries. By the end of this process, there were over fifty autonomous kingdoms, principalities, and city republics in Western Europe (Cervellati et al., Reference Cervellati, Lazzaroni, Prarolo and Vanin2019). Necessarily, the average size of each autonomous territory fell sharply over the same period.

The large number of small sovereignties facilitated exit from any one jurisdiction. Peasants from rural northern Italy and Germany moved from the feudal countryside to the republican communes. Indeed, most urban growth over this period was the result of immigration from the territory of feudal lords rather than that of higher birth rates (Epstein, Reference Epstein and Abulafia1999). Merchants' choice to operate in a given market was also highly dependent on the ‘governance bundle’ supplied within each sovereignty. A local lord or republican city government attempting to extract a large share of the merchant's surplus would lose the latter's ‘business’ for a close-by competitor (Cox, Reference Cox2017).

Innovation in fiscal technology and other public policies spread quickly across jurisdictions. The Italian communes of the late Middle Ages experimented with alternative political and administrative tools. For example, the podesteria system of the 12th centuryFootnote 22 emerged to preserve social peace within increasingly divided cities and was soon adopted across the communal republics of northern and central Italy (Greif, Reference Greif1994). Sovereignties competing for the business of merchants transformed their institutional environment to maximize their appeal. The institutions of the members of the Hanseatic League, the Italian Maritime Republics, the Champaign fairs, and other trade centers across Western Europe are illustrative of this phenomenon. Although these polities differed in the specific strategies due to the relative costs of enforcements, they were all characterized by public institutions that supported and complemented private mechanisms behind the explosion of long-distance, high-value trade of the late Middle Ages.Footnote 23 Operating within very limited geographic confines, polities had an incentive to promote the accumulation of capital and the production of wealth within their territory to economize on the costs of enforcing their sovereignty.Footnote 24 This furthered the benefits of investing in governance technologies that increased the overall productivity of the economies of Western Europe.

By the end of the Middle Ages, Western Europe's ‘market for governance’ conformed to the characteristics we identify in our framework as fostering the development of effective states. However, different Western European regions undertook different trajectories resulting in different degrees of state effectiveness. Throughout the early modern era, some regions (the Iberian Peninsula, France, and the Italian peninsula) saw a consolidation of centralized power and experienced economic stagnation whereas others (the British Isles, the Netherlands, and the Germanic polities) lead the way and set the stage for the ‘European miracle’.Footnote 25

4. The Italian city-states

The Italian city-states emerged out of the feudal system and became major centers of commerce, culture, art, religion, and politics. These polities distributed political property rights among key decision-makers in a productive manner. For example, they extended political power to groups that had been traditionally excluded, such as merchants and artisans. They also operated in a context of significant jurisdictional competition, with major regional centers as close as a few dozen miles from each other. In this regard, they resembled our model of a rivalrous market for governance closely. These conditions favored the development of innovative forms of public administration, political decision making, and public policy, which resulted in a rise in citizens' living standards. The communes developed sophisticated forms of debt finance and introduced innovative tax policies (Martines, Reference Martines1988), anticipating by centuries many similar developments in the rest of the continent, and for which they have been identified as early ‘fiscal states’ (Jones, Reference Jones1997; Stasavage, Reference Stasavage2007).

The city-states emerged and consolidated over a period of three centuries, starting just around the turn of the second millennium. By then, the region between the Alps to the north and the mountains of Umbria and Marche to the south was populated by a wide array of bishoprics, lordships, and principalities, all formally part of the Kingdom of Italy and thus vassals to the Holy Roman Emperor.Footnote 26 The commercial revolution of the 10th century jump-started a process of urbanization, mostly in towns and cities of Roman origins. These small towns were dominated by groups of aristocratic families from the local countryside, often in partnership with the local bishop (Martines, Reference Martines1988: 21). The ruling families came together to form a corporate entity, the commune, that would become the fundamental urban governance institution for the centuries to come. In the early days, the political organization of the communes was modeled on that of republican Rome, with a general assembly of the citizens (i.e. the members of the aristocracy), with executive power entrusted to elected officials (the consuls) for short periods of time.

In just a few decades, the commune had achieved such a degree of autonomy that the emperor felt the need to reassert his authority over the region. What followed is a series of failed attempts by the emperor to force his will on the communes. Finally defeated, the emperor recognized with the Peace of Constance of 1183 the communes' territorial claims to the immediate countryside, as well as the authority to self-govern, including the right to elect public officials.

There were, by this point, hundreds of communes in Northern Italy. Many had already established themselves as local commercial hubs; some had come to dominate the regional market, and a few were emerging as international powers in trade, finance, and manufacturing. The communes were in a constant state of competition. One margin of competition was that for market shares in international trade, especially between the three ‘maritime republics’ of Genoa, Pisa, and Venice. Bologna, Florence, Milan, and Siena were major centers in international banking, competing for the capital of kings, princes, and popes. They also competed to attract their workforce. These cities were also large manufacturing centers. To the men and women of the Italian countryside, they offered an alternative to farming someone else's field. Immigration was a major force behind the drastic increase in the population size of these towns. Between 1050 and 1200, Venice almost doubled its population from 45 to 70 thousand, Verona went from 15 to over 30 thousand, and Florence from 15 to 60 thousand. Of the thirty largest cities in Western Europe in 1200, a third were from the Italian north. One hundred years later, four of the six largest cities in Europe (Venice, Milan, Genoa, and Florence) were from an area of 15 thousand square miles in northern Italy. This growth was only indirectly due to increases in living standards, as infant mortality was still very in the cities. Instead, it was the promise of freedom from feudal obligations and perhaps higher wages that attracted an unprecedented influx of immigrants (Greene, Reference Green and Abulafia1999: 482).

Competition between communes was facilitated by the relatively small size of their territories. Initially, their authority extended only up to the original Roman walls. The peace of Costanza recognized their jurisdiction over the entire bishopric, and over time the communes had grown to incorporate their immediate countryside. The nature of the communal economy also favored competition between the city-states. To be successful, they had to attract labor and capital from throughout the region and beyond. In particular, they had to provide favorable conditions to the development of the local economy. One way was to extend political representation. By the turn of the 13th century, the most productive members of the communal economy began organizing themselves into professional associations to influence the government of their cities. Within a few decades, these Arti or guilds achieved political power and formal constitutional representation.Footnote 27 For example, in Florence, in the 1250s, the constitution of the primo popolo gave access to the local levers of power to the thousands of members of the city's main guilds (Najemy, Reference Najemy2008: 66–70). In Siena, the local popolo (an alliance of the members of the banking guild and the largest merchant groups and other professionals) grew in political relevance until its elected officials were officially recognized by the constitution of 1262 (Schevill, Reference Schevill1909: 143). Other major communes went through similar developments, including Bologna, Genoa, and Lucca (Martines, Reference Martines1988: 48). In 1296, the city reformed its constitution by introducing strict requirements for a citizen's eligibility to one of the many legislative and executive bodies of the republic. Counterintuitively, this actually expanded the size of these bodies and the number of individuals that could participate in domestic politics. Within 50 years of the reforms, the size of Venice's highest political assembly went from 210 to more than 1200 (Norwich, Reference Norwich2003: 184). At the same time, the reform generated rents for the members of the local commercial community, effectively reallocating property rights in an incentive-compatible way (De Lara, Reference De Lara2008).

The combination of jurisdictional rivalry with an incentive-compatible allocation of political property rights characterized the region throughout the 13th and beyond. Over the same period, the Italian city-states emerged as among the most dynamic polities in Western Europe. Venice and Genoa distinguished themselves in international trade; Florence and Venice were at the cutting edge of financial innovation; Bologna, Padova, and Siena became major cultural centers thanks to the establishment of some of the oldest universities in Europe. This institutional environment had large effects on wealth and standards of living. Numbers for the 13th century are scant, but Malanima (Reference Malanima1998) estimates that by the year 1300 there were more than 7 million people in the Italian center-north. Also, this area had an urbanization rate four times that of Western Europe at the time (Malanima, Reference Malanima2009). These numbers suggest a high level of productivity for the region. In 1300, agricultural output per worker in northern Italy was twice that of 14th century England and as high as that of France in the 19th century (Federico and Malanima, Reference Federico and Malanima2004: 457). Most measures of economic well-being indicate that the standard of living of an Italian commune's average citizen in the year 1300 was higher than that of the average Italian as late as 1861.Footnote 28

Economic progress was supported by the evolution of communal institutions and the government's accumulation of administrative, legal, and fiscal capacity. On the administrative side, the city-states introduced additional bureaucracies to manage the commune's expanding responsibilities. Communes started to undertake significant public investments. Defense considerations played an important role in this development. As population was growing rapidly, the old Roman walls could only protect a shrinking percentage of the city's capital and labor, so the city-states started building new walls with a larger diameter (Epstein, Reference Epstein and Abulafia1999: 29).

On the legal side, one of the most pressing problems in the first decades of the 13th century was that of violence between clans from among a city's oldest and most prestigious families. With the rise of the popolo and its enfranchisement, new regulations put an end to the feuding. The ordinances of justice of 1293 created the figure of the Gonfaloniere di Giustizia, with the explicit task of monitoring the behavior of the city's aristocratic families and enforcing the laws against feuding and private violence (Najemy, Reference Najemy2008: 82–85). To meet the growth of public spending necessary to a stronger communal administration, the city-states had to rationalize and expand their tax regimes. Since their birth, communes had relied mostly on in-kind contributions, including for the provision of defense services.Footnote 29 Over time, as the towns assumed a primary role as local and regional centers of commerce, the communes introduced trade taxes, soon to become their major source of revenue.Footnote 30 By the late-12th-to-early-13th century, the Italian city-states started to experiment with fiscal technology, including wealth taxes and forced loans. In cases of need, communes relied on exceptional forms of taxation. These dazi were introduced in the late 13th century by the largest towns in Tuscany. This form of taxation is particularly interesting because its effectiveness relied on an assessment, by the commune, of its citizens' wealth. This forced the towns to conduct some of the most comprehensive large-scale censuses of the time.Footnote 31 During the same period, the government of Florence gradually removed tax exemptions for the old aristocratic class, as well as those for major clerical figures and church assets. Overall, these reforms ‘suggest considerable improvements in the administrative infrastructure in the territory’ (Day, Reference Day2000: 102). By the turn of the 14th century, city-states such as Genoa, Florence, Siena, and Venice, though smaller in territory and population than most of their neighboring polities, were able to compete with their neighbors in military and geopolitical matters, thanks to their higher administrative efficiency.Footnote 32

5. German cameralism

For our final case study, we look at the evolution of public finance (both theory and practice) in the German polities of the 17th and 18th centuries.Footnote 33 Early modern Germany approximated the conditions favoring the development of effective states.Footnote 34 When the rest of Western Europe was experiencing a rapid process of unification (France, Spain, and the British Isles), the Holy Roman Empire retained a characteristically ‘medieval’ degree of inter-jurisdictional competition, divided as it was among religious and secular principalities, duchies, and free cities.Footnote 35

Consistent with our framework, polycentric Germany took a different path than most of Western Europe in the development of the science and practice of public administration during this time. In most of Western Europe, mercantilism became the fundamental doctrine behind a ruler's administration of his realm. This is consistent with the view that centralized states facing limited jurisdictional rivalry were in a better position to invest in political institutions and adopt public policies that directed wealth-creation to the benefits of the ruling elite. In the German polities, the rival tradition of cameralism emerged instead.Footnote 36

Unlike the relatively small-scale conflicts of the Middle Ages, the Thirty Years' War devastated the populations and economies of the Germanic polities.Footnote 37 The Peace of Westphalia (1648), which put an end to the conflict between Catholic and Protestant rulers in central Europe, recognized more than 300 independent sovereign states (Tilly, Reference Tilly1990). Each was governed by an absolutist regime: the prince of each polity was the ultimate political authority.Footnote 38 The combination of de facto and de jure centralized power, in a broader environment of political fractionalization, resulted in an interesting development in the doctrine and practice of public administration. Although the emperor was formally the ultimate source of authority, the German cities, duchies, and principalities ‘had their own chambers, treasuries and financial officials’:

Consequently, one confronts an apparent paradox whereby – in contrast, for example, to England and France – it was the subordinate levels of the constitutional structure, the Imperial and free cities and the territories, rather than the Empire itself, that during the Middle Ages came to conform more closely to the modern notion of the ‘state’ and of the ‘state finance’.Footnote 39

The most significant post-Westphalian innovation was the creation of a professional bureaucratic apparatus (Wilson, Reference Wilson2002: 86). Before the late 18th century, university-educated commoners could rise to many prominent offices within the nascent bureaucracy (Wilson, Reference Wilson2002: 95). This was part of a political strategy to consolidate authority by princes. To break the feudal privileges and de facto residual rights held by other nobles and trade guilds (remnants of the medieval constitution), princes allied themselves with commoners. This contributed to the development of a uniform legal code and the suppression of private violence (Wilson, Reference Wilson2002: 103). Both princes and commoners had an incentive to form a coalition against intermediate power-holders, namely the local aristocracy, the guilds, and the clergy. From this cooperation, commoners stood to gain wealth and honor, whereas princes stood to gain increased control over their own lands (Backhaus and Wagner, Reference Backhaus and Wagner1987; Jouvenel, Reference Jouvenel1993; Wagner, Reference Wagner and Backhaus2012).

The ruler rewarded commoners who rose to positions of prominence in the bureaucratic hierarchy with wealth, privileges, and sometimes titles of nobility (Benecke, Reference Benecke1971). This was not to last. By the late 18th century, the prevalence of commoners at the top of the bureaucracy had receded.Footnote 40 The political winds had shifted. Whereas previously, princes found it profitable to bargain with commoners against the nobles, eventually, they found it profitable to entice the nobility into prominent positions within the new political order, provided they renounce the last of their medieval privileges and immunities. In exchange, nobles were guaranteed the integrity of their estates and access to prestigious public positions, such as those in the military (Johnson, Reference Johnson1975).

During this period, large states such as England and France adopted mercantilism as a political-economic system (Ekelund and Tollison, Reference Ekelund and Tollison1981). In this system, the sovereign would raise revenue through direct taxation, as well as by auctioning off monopoly production rights to certain goods (North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009).Footnote 41 For this system to work, the ruler's commitment to transfer monopoly rights to interest groups must be credible. In turn, this required some degree of state capacity. Another factor making this system less costly to the ruler was the higher exit costs that his subjects faced: French and English subjects could not easily run away to escape the distortionary effects of mercantilist economic policy.

As we would expect, the case of the Germanic polities was very different, due to the small and fragmented nature of these polities. Formally, the law often bound subjects to the land they worked; in reality, subjects often ‘voted with their feet’ in response to a prince's predatory actions. Rival princes had an obvious interest in attracting labor and capital to their polities. In the struggle to perpetuate their rule, wealth was power, and the means of securing wealth used by the mercantilist polities simply were not within possibility set of the German princes.Footnote 42 As Wagner (Reference Wagner and Backhaus2012: 6) argues,

The prince was the ruler of his lands. He did not have to worry about surviving periodic elections, and he could hope to pass his principality along to his eldest son. His ability to do this, however, varied directly with the extent of economic progress within his land. A prince whose land was supporting a growing population of energetic and enterprising subjects would both be wealthier and face better survival prospects than a prince of a land where the population was stagnant or declining, and whose subjects were dull and lethargic. Furthermore, population was mobile in fact, even if it was mostly tied to the land at law through feudal restrictions. Distances between lands were typically short. A peasant who traveled to a new land was not likely to be returned. The rulers of the cameralist lands faced a competitive labor market. Indeed, the cameralist lands represented the kind of competitive industry among localized governments.

The term ‘cameralist’ refers to a body of thought often identified as the German counterpart to mercantilism. Cameralism was a tradition in early public finance and administration theory focused on advising princes how to maximize revenues and maintain their estates. Because the Germanic princes' ability to extract revenue was limited by their subjects' ability to exit (and with them, their labor services and capital), cameralist writers ‘essentially construed rulers as businessmen with their businesses being the operation of states’ (Backhaus and Wagner, Reference Backhaus and Wagner1987: 6). The bureaucrats were directly in charge of the prince's private wealth and were entrusted with its maximization. Importantly, there were few legal privileges giving the prince's capital-employing enterprises an advantage over the competition. Public enterprise was seen as a source of wealth for the state, rather than an object of subsidy. In contrast, taxation was discouraged both in theory and practice, and was viewed as a mechanism of last resort in case of emergencies, rather than a regular scheme for raising revenue.Footnote 43 Since the Middle Ages, to the extent that the German principalities did rely on taxation, they did so to finance fundamental expenditures, mostly pertaining their defense needs against foreign aggression (Isenmann, Reference Isenmann and Bonney1999: 246). The reluctance to employ taxation, however, soon gave way to political necessity. If a prince's neighbors are all building ‘fiscal-military’ states, that prince cannot help but follow along, so long as he wishes to remain independent (cf. Geloso and Salter, Reference Geloso and Salter2020; Hendrickson et al., Reference Hendrickson, Salter and Albrecht2018).

The next major contribution of German cameralism was the development of a ‘coherent taxation theory’ (Lee, Reference Lee1975: 153).Footnote 44 During the 17th and 18th centuries, as central Europe was recovering from the Thirty Years' War, the principalities reformed their fiscal regimes. They now favored direct taxes as the major source of revenues for the German states, particularly real estate and property taxes (Denzel, Reference Denzel2006: 2). The German polities developed new instruments of government finance, including the supply of government bonds and reliance on private individuals and firms in the administration of public debt (Denzel, Reference Denzel2006: 13). The early 19th century was characterized by a rationalization of their tax system, especially land taxes, with a movement toward the creation of registers and adjustments in tax rates based on land yields (Lee, Reference Lee1975: 159). Throughout the 19th century, the German states' competition to attract investment (especially that which could foster industrialization) led to lower tax rates over the secondary, industrial sector, and relatively higher ones on the agricultural sector (Lee, Reference Lee1975: 162–165).Footnote 45 Competition discouraged the taxation of foreign capital, out of fear that it would flow to some other region.Footnote 46 Similar forces led to a shift away from direct and toward indirect taxation, and to a tax system that heavily favored investment over present consumption (Lee, Reference Lee1975: 169). Thus, the ‘apparently archaic’ Holy Roman Empire offered fertile ground for fiscal competition and experimentation with ‘surprisingly modern techniques and principles of taxation’ (Isenmann, Reference Isenmann and Bonney1999: 244).

Both the initial reluctance to employ widespread taxation, and the latter development of ‘rationalized’ taxation, make sense in light of elites' political property rights, in an environment of robust jurisdictional competition. That largely illiberal governance structures resulted in surprisingly liberal (for the time) economic policy was a function of the underlying political property rights. Those who participated in governance were still largely residual claimants. Princes and nobles obviously possessed their lands and estates, and their rewards (both in cash flows and the capitalized value of their assets) were reflected in the quality of governance they supplied. Poor governance meant labor and capital exiting their territory in search for rulers offering better terms.

6. Conclusion

State capacity does partly explain economic development. But it is ultimately epiphenomenal; what determines how rulers act within the nexus of administrative capabilities created by modern states depends on the information they have and the incentives they face. This is a function of the structure of political property rights, suggesting the potential for reconciling the literature on polycentricity and jurisdictional competition with that on state capacity. The polycentric governance arrangements of Medieval Europe were the starting point, from which subsequent political bargains would transform into the nascent states of early modernity. Political property rights afforded elites a degree of residual claimancy to the wealth arising from governance. Both features – political property rights conducive to wealth creation and centralized administrative capacity to transcend the medieval governance ‘anticommons’ – are important to explain the prosperity of Western polities.

In addition to explaining the institutional underpinnings of state capacity, the theory we develop also speaks to the ongoing project exploring the sources and effects of inclusive governance institutions (Acemoglu and Robinson, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2005, Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012; North et al., Reference North, Wallis and Weingast2009). These theories suggest economic prosperity will follow after breaking the monopoly on governance held by traditional elites, who tend to use the means of governance to enact distributionally favorable policies, but ones that are also socially wealth reducing. Making governance more inclusive brings in parties whose personal interests align with more growth-friendly policies, as well as institutionalizing checks on predatory governance more generally. Our account suggests we interpret these results with caution. State capacity solidified, and economic growth followed, during a time when traditional elites were still residual claimants to governance revenues, whether in the Parliament-dominated ‘aristocratic republic’ of England, or the monarch-dominated ‘absolutist’ polities of Germany.

Thus it makes sense to view the breakup of rent-preserving feudal privileges as conducive to economic growth; but whether stripping traditional elites' roles and privileges in governance was likewise growth-enhancing is far less certain. Governance institutions that are too inclusive have their own pathologies that can stifle economic growth. For example, political power can become so fragmented that no individual has an incentive to acquire the information necessary to wield that power responsibly. Such situations devolve into either the mob tyranny of the Greek polis, or the soft ‘democratic despotism’ feared by Tocqueville. Today, the latter scenario is clearly more concerning than the former. It is also suited to bureaucratic governance, albeit under an inverted structure of political property rights. Because bureaucrats under inclusive-egalitarian governance institutions will almost certainly not be residual claimants to governance revenues, they do not confront the same information and incentives for social wealth creation. In fact, their incentives are much more oriented toward wealth dissipation. In the absence of residual claimancy, bureaucrats will likely maximize budgets in place of profits. Hence bureaucrats inadvertently maximize the value of resources used up in governing (Niskanen, [1971] Reference Niskanen2007; Tullock, Reference Tullock2005; von Mises, Reference von Mises1944). Instead of evolutionary pressure for cost-minimizing behavior, we get evolutionary pressure for cost-maximizing behavior.

By focusing on political property rights and jurisdictional competition, future developments in the theory of state capacity may help solve the puzzle of why polities that appeared destined for economic and political development failed to achieve sustainable growth. Any social-scientific explanation must focus on information and incentives. We hope our framework will provide some new analytical tools to the study of political and economic development in Western Europe, and in other regions and time periods as well.

Acknowledgements

We thank Bryan Cutsinger and David Skarbek for helpful comments on an early draft of the manuscript.

Footnotes

1 What this literature calls the ‘effective state’ is, we believe, mostly the same as the conjunction of the protective and productive state in Buchanan's (Reference Buchanan2000) typology.

2 See De Soto (Reference De Soto2000) for the role of secure property rights for economic development.

3 We use ‘market for governance’ to refer to the supply and demand for public services, such as the enforcement of property rights, the provision of public goods, and the supply of administrative services within a given territory.

4 For example, a region or territory would be a political asset if the sovereign can extract a stream of tax revenues from it, or some other services, such as the supply of men for military defense. Political property rights are, therefore, a subset of economic property rights as defined by Allen (Reference Allen1991).

5 Throughout this paper, we use the phrase ‘Western Europe’ to refer to the territories of continental Europe to the West of today's Poland, Slovakia, Hungary, and Slovenia. The latter is a somewhat arbitrary line, but it historically coincides with the Eastern border of the Frankish empire at the death of Charlemagne in 814.

6 This point shows that there is an essential distinction between the technological and competitive dimensions of state capacity. A state may very well have the technological ability to predate, yet not act in a predatory manner in equilibrium, due to the fear of losing taxpayers to its jurisdictional competitors (Piano, Reference Piano2019).

7 This is broadly consistent with the growing realization of the importance of historical path dependencies in political-economic development (Nunn, Reference Nunn2009; Pierson, Reference Pierson2000).

8 Although Acemoglu and Robinson's (Reference Acemoglu and Robinson2012) framework provides valuable insights into the feedback mechanism between political and economic institutions, their focus is on power asymmetries between elites and non-elites. Our focus is on the alignment of incentives between rulers and subjects and the competition between rulers for taxing the subjects' product.

9 See, for example, Acemoglu (Reference Acemoglu2003) and Munger (Reference Munger2019).

10 Political property rights affect the incentives of all members of society, not just rulers. To qualify as well-aligned, political property rights must provide incentives for everyone to foster wealth-creation.

11 See, among others, Allen (Reference Allen1995), Cheung (Reference Cheung1974), and Shepsle and Weingast (Reference Shepsle and Weingast1987).

12 See Barzel (Reference Barzel1997: 7): ‘The maximization of the value of an asset … involves the ownership or ownership pattern that can most effectively constrain uncompensated exploitation’.

13 Our approach suggests that all political institutions, including the rule of law, constitutions, and political parties, can all be understood as wealth maximizing, net of transaction costs. However, one need not be an adherent of the ‘efficiency always’ school to appreciate the explanatory power of viewing institutions as the result of exchanges by maximizing agents.

14 Consider a basic stationary bandit model. There is a local economy producing some quantity of output by combining labor and land. Assume for simplicity that both land and labor are entirely unalienable (i.e. the bandit has no way to appropriate labor in the form of slaves or take the land with them). Bandits come in, take that period's output, and leave. As such, they bear none of the losses in the value of land due to their actions (they do bear some loss in terms of the reduced equilibrium level of production if locals expect bandits to come by and steal their output). In this scenario, bandits own the flow over a given period but not the stock. A stationary bandit, on the other hand, is a residual claimant over the stock. In the most basic stationary bandit model, the stationary bandit is the (economic) owner of all the land and ‘employees’.

15 See Kurrild-Klitgaard and Svendsen (Reference Kurrild-Klitgaard and Svendsen2003), Skarbek (Reference Skarbek2011), and Young (Reference Young2016) for historical case studies of the emergence of stationary bandits.

16 However, the better aligned the incentives, the less likely this will be.

17 The key pieces in the literature on efficient political institutions are Wittman (Reference Wittman1989) and Stigler (Reference Stigler1992). For recent applications, see Barzel (Reference Barzel2002) and Allen (Reference Allen2011). See also Acemoglu (Reference Acemoglu2003) and Caplan (Reference Caplan2001) for criticisms of this view.

18 A realm-owner must ultimately be an individual (or group of individuals), although they may find it optimal to exercise their control indirectly (say, through the institution of the crown rather than the person of the King).

19 Our framework is related (and reaches similar conclusions) to that developed by Barzel (Reference Barzel2002). Barzel's and our frameworks both emphasize the importance of seeing the relationship between rulers and society as self-enforcing. However, Barzel focuses on how society forces constraints on the ruler to prevent the latter from acting against its interests. In our framework, these constraints play a significant role, but the ruler has incentives to behave in a ‘productive’ manner, in part due to competing pressures from other rulers and its subjects' ability to exit.

20 See the discussion in Olson (Reference Olson1995).

21 The argument that de facto political property rights were generally exercised by local lords rather than by de jure rulers is common in the historical literature (Ganshof, Reference Ganshof1996). For example, as we discuss below, the communes of Northern Italy fell under the jurisdiction of the Holy Roman Emperor, who had the right to hand-pick public officials and demanded the payment of tributes (monetary and in-kind). However, the reality on the ground was quite different, as local communities became de facto independent from the emperor's authority over the 11th and 12th centuries.

22 In this system, some military, executive, and judicial powers were outsourced by the commune to a foreign dignitary, selected by the domestic elite and monitored for the duration of service by a specialized committee.

23 See Fink (Reference Fink2012) for the Hanseatic League, Greif (Reference Greif1994) and de Lara (Reference De Lara2008) for Genoa and Venice, Edwards and Ogilvie (Reference Edwards and Ogilvie2012) for the Champaign fairs, and Kallioinen (Reference Kallioinen2017) for the Baltic polities.

24 This argument was originally developed to apply to familiar economic assets and commodities (Allen, Reference Allen2002). Batchelder and Sanchez (Reference Batchelder and Sanchez2013) make a similar claim about the strategy of Imperial Spain during the 16th century. However, Hendrickson et al. (Reference Hendrickson, Salter and Albrecht2018) point out the existence of negative political externalities associated with increasing social wealth.

25 Nevertheless, even the most badly administered western European polities gained from the success of the rest, and their subjects benefited from the competitive nature of the regions' market for governance. For example, in the 17th century, daily wages for unskilled workers in Spanish Milan were much larger than those of the same workers in China (Broadberry and Gupta, Reference Broadberry and Gupta2006).

26 Venice was an exception, as it formally belonged to the Eastern empire.

27 This process was far from smooth and was often punctuated by episodes of violence. Nevertheless, for more than a century, many Italian polities expanded political representation to include previously disenfranchised categories.

28 See the discussion in Malanima (Reference Malanima2003).

29 See Contamine (Reference Contamine1986).

30 See the discussion in Hansen (Reference Hansen2000).

31 Bowsky and Bowsky (Reference Bowsky and Bowsky1981) discusses the case of Siena, where the dazio was employed continuously for 70 years.

32 See the discussion in Hansen (Reference Hansen2000: 287–288).

33 Salter (Reference Salter2016) provides an extensive overview of the political economy of these themes.

34 In this section, we use ‘Early modern Germany’, German polities, and ‘Holy Roman Empire’ interchangeably to refer to the regions that were nominally under the rule of the Holy Roman Emperor between the 16th and the early 19th century. Although its border changed somewhat during this period, the Empire encompassed most of today's Germany, Austria, Belgium, Czechia, and Slovenia, as well as territories from eastern France, northern Italy, and western Poland.

35 See the discussion on the evolution of the German states in Volckart (Reference Volckart2000). On the process of the development of the territorial state in western Europe, see Abramson (Reference Abramson2017).

36 Cameralism has much in common with mercantilism. However, the two differed significantly in their respective emphases. Mercantilism focused on international trade and related policies, whereas cameralism paid more attention to issues of domestic public finance. This difference is likely to have reflected the peculiar geographical and economic circumstances of the German territories (Magnusson, Reference Magnusson2017).

37 ‘There can be no doubt that the war was a disaster for most of the German-speaking lands’ (Kamen, Reference Kamen1968: 48). On the nature of European warfare during the Middle Ages, see Housley (Reference Housley and Keen1999).

38 On the prince's role as the ultimate executive authority and the concentration of power onto his figure, see Wilson (Reference Wilson2002: 91). For how international competition influenced the trajectory of political development in central Europe, see Wilson (Reference Wilson2002: 18).

40 For example, within the military bureaucracy of the German territories, ‘[n]obles displaced commoners from officer positions from the late seventeenth century, but many were “foreign” in the sense that they came from outside the territory they served’ (Wilson, Reference Wilson2002: 95). Our framework does not speak directly of a ruler's decision to employ members of the aristocracy or commoners within the bureaucracy. On this issue, as it applies to English and British history, see Allen (Reference Allen2011).

41 During this period, the collection of revenues was the purview of so-called ‘tax farmers’ in both England and France (Johnson and Koyama, Reference Johnson and Koyama2014).

42 The one exception was Prussia.

43 Cf. Backhaus and Wagner (Reference Backhaus and Wagner1987: 15): ‘The cameralist state participated in the production of goods and services primarily through its various public enterprises and secondarily through modest taxation. The cameralist states were competing with one another for capital and various forms of labor, so the path to long-term princely prosperity was relatively tightly constrained to follow the road of enlightened political administration, which in turn was administration that facilitated the economic progress of the principality’.

44 See Isenmann (Reference Isenmann and Bonney1999) for a detailed overview of the development of fiscal practices in the German territories during the period of interest.

45 Indeed, ‘tax assessments on the secondary sector were … structured to promote the growth of rural/domestic industries’ (Lee, Reference Lee1975: 165).

46 For example, in Sachsen-Weimar, the government adopted a ‘mild treatment’ of foreign capital taxation to prevent a capital flight (Lee, Reference Lee1975: 167).

References

Abramson, S. F. (2017), ‘The Economic Origins of the Territorial State’, International Organization, 71(1): 97130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2003), ‘Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4): 620652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2005), Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2012), Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty, New York, USA: Broadway Business.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2019), The Narrow Corridor: States, Societies, and the Fate of Liberty, New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Moscona, J. and Robinson, J. A. (2016), ‘State Capacity and American Technology: Evidence from the Nineteenth Century’, American Economic Review, 106(5): 6167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albrecht, B. C., Hendrickson, J. R. and Salter, A. W. (2018), ‘Evolution, Uncertainty, and the Asymptotic Efficiency of Policy’, Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, A. A. (1950), ‘Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory’, Journal of Political Economy, 58(3): 211221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aligica, P. and Tarko, V. (2013), ‘Co-Production, Polycentricity, and Value Heterogeneity: The Ostroms’ Public Choice Institutionalism Revisited’, American Political Science Review, 107(4): 726741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, D. W. (1991). ‘What are Transaction Costs’, Research in Law and Economics, 14(1): 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, D. W. (1995), ‘Order in the Church: A Property Rights Approach’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 27(1): 97117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, D. W. (2011). The Institutional Revolution: Measurement and the Economic Emergence of the Modern World, Chicago, USA: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, D. W. (2002), ‘The Rhino's Horn: Incomplete Property Rights and the Optimal Value of an Asset’, The Journal of Legal Studies, 31(S2): S339S358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhaus, J. and Wagner, R. E. (1987), ‘The Cameralists: A Public Choice Perspective’, Public choice, 53(1): 320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Y. (1997), Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Y. (2002), A Theory of the State: Economic Rights, Legal Rights, and the Scope of the State, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Batchelder, R. W. and Sanchez, N. (2013), ‘The Encomienda and the Optimizing Imperialist: An Interpretation of Spanish Imperialism in the Americas’, Public Choice, 156(1–2): 4560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benecke, G. (1971), ‘Ennoblement and Privilege in Early Modern Germany’, History, 56(188): 360370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and Persson, T. (2009), ‘The Origins of State Capacity: Property Rights, Taxation, and Politics’, American Economic Review, 99(4): 12181244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and Persson, T. (2010), ‘State Capacity, Conflict, and Development’, Econometrica, 78(1): 134.Google Scholar
Bowsky, W. M. and Bowsky, W. M. (1981), A Medieval Italian Commune: Siena Under the Nine, 1287–1355. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S. and Gupta, B. (2006), ‘The Early Modern Great Divergence: Wages, Prices and Economic Development in Europe and Asia, 1500–1800’, The Economic History Review, 59(1): 231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (2000), The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan, Indianapolis, USA: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Caplan, B. (2001). ‘Rational Irrationality and the Microfoundations of Political Failure.’ Public Choice, 107(3–4): 311331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cervellati, M., Lazzaroni, S., Prarolo, G. and Vanin, P. (2019), ‘Political Geography and Pre-Industrial Development: A Theory and Evidence for Europe 1000–1850’, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Cheung, S. N. (1974), ‘A Theory of Price Control’, The Journal of Law and Economics, 17(1): 5371.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960), ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, The Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1): 169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Contamine, P. (1986), War in the Middle Ages, Hoboken: Blackwell Publishing.Google Scholar
Cox, G. W. (2017), ‘Political Institutions, Economic Liberty, and the Great Divergence’, The Journal of Economic History, 77(3): 724755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, W. R. (2000), The early development of the Florentine economy, c. 1100–1275, Doctoral dissertation, London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
De Lara, Y. G. (2008), ‘The Secret of Venetian Success: A Public-Order, Reputation-Based Institution’, European Review of Economic History, 12(3): 247285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeLong, J. B. and Shleifer, A. (1993), ‘Princes and Merchants: European City Growth Before the Industrial Revolution’, The Journal of Law and Economics, 36(2): 671702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denzel, M. A. (2006), ‘State and Finance in the Holy Roman Empire from c. 1650 to c. 1800, a Survey’, Working Paper.Google Scholar
De Soto, H. (2000), The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else, New York, USA: Basic Civitas Books.Google Scholar
Dincecco, M. (2015), ‘The Rise of Effective States in Europe’, The Journal of Economic History, 75(3): 901918.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dincecco, M. and Prado, M. (2012), ‘Warfare, Fiscal Capacity, and Performance’, Journal of Economic Growth, 17(3): 171203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, J. and Ogilvie, S. (2012), ‘What Lessons for Economic Development can we Draw From the Champagne Fairs?’, Explorations in Economic History, 49(2): 131148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekelund, R. B. and Tollison, R. D. (1981), Mercantilism as a Rent-Seeking Society: Economic Regulation in Historical Perspective, College Station, USA: Texas A & M University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, S. (1999), ‘Urban Society’, in Abulafia, D. (ed.), The New Cambridge Medieval History, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 2637.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Federico, G. and Malanima, P. (2004), ‘Progress, Decline, Growth: Product and Productivity in Italian Agriculture, 1000–2000’, The Economic History Review, 57(3): 437464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fink, A. (2012), ‘The Hanseatic League and the Concept of Functional Overlapping Competing Jurisdictions’, Kyklos, 65(2): 194217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ganshof, F. L. (1996), Feudalism, Toronto, Canada: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Geloso, V. and Salter, A. W. (2020), ‘State Capacity and Economic Development: Causal Mechanism or Correlative Filter?’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 170(1), 372385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grassi, D. and Memoli, V. (2016), ‘Political Determinants of State Capacity in Latin America’, World Development, 88(1): 94106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, L. (1999), ‘Florence’, in Abulafia, D. (ed.), The New Cambridge Medieval History, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 479497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. (1994), ‘On the Political Foundations of the Late Medieval Commercial Revolution: Genoa During the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries’, The Journal of Economic History, 54(2): 271287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, M. H. (Ed.). (2000), A Comparative Study of Thirty City-state Cultures: An Investigation. Kgl. Danske Videnskabernes Selskab.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1945), ‘The use of knowledge in society’, The American Economic Review, 35(4): 519530.Google Scholar
Hendrickson, J. R., Salter, A. W. and Albrecht, B. C. (2018), ‘Preventing Plunder: Military Technology, Capital Accumulation, and Economic Growth’, Journal of Macroeconomics, 58(1): 154173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Housley, N. (1999), ‘European Warfare, c. 1200–1320’, in Keen, M. (ed.), Medieval Warfare: A History, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press, pp. 113135.Google Scholar
Isenmann, E. (1999), ‘The Holy Roman Empire in the Middle Ages’, in Bonney, R. (ed.), The Rise of the Fiscal State in Europe c. 1200–1815. Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press, pp. 243278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, H. C. (1975), Frederick the Great and his Officials, New Haven, USA: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Johnson, N. D. and Koyama, M. (2014), ‘Tax Farming and the Origins of State Capacity in England and France’, Explorations in Economic History, 51(1): 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, N. D. and Koyama, M. (2017), ‘States and Economic Growth: Capacity and constraints’, Explorations in Economic History, 64(1): 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, P. (1997), The Italian City-State: From commune to Signoria, Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Jouvenel, B. (1993), On Power: The Natural History of its Growth, Indianapolis, US: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Kallioinen, M. (2017), ‘Inter-Communal Institutions in Medieval Trade’, The Economic History Review, 70(4): 11311152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kamen, H. (1968), ‘The Economic and Social Consequences of the Thirty Years’ War’, Past & Present, 39(1): 4461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. and Svendsen, G. T. (2003), ‘Rational Bandits: Plunder, Public Goods, and the Vikings’, Public Choice, 117(3–4): 255272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, W. R. (1975), ‘Tax Structure and Economic Growth in Germany (1750–1850)’, Journal of European Economic History, 4(1), 153174.Google Scholar
Levy, J. T. (2014), Rationalism, Pluralism, and Freedom, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Libecap, G. D. (1993). Contracting for Property Rights, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lopez, R. S. (1976), The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages, 950–1350, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magnusson, L. (2017), Mercantilism and Cameralism, London, UK: Routledge.Google Scholar
Malanima, P. (1998), ‘Italian Cities 1300–1800. A Quantitative Approach’, Rivista di Storia Economica, 14(2): 91126.Google Scholar
Malanima, P. (2003), ‘Measuring the Italian Economy, 1300–1861’, Rivista di Storia Economica, 19(3): 265296.Google Scholar
Malanima, P. (2009), ‘Decline or Growth? European Cities and Rural Economies,’ Zwischen Land und Stadt, Jahrbuch für Geschichte des ländlichen Raumes, 6(1): 1844.Google Scholar
Martines, L. (1988), Power and Imagination: City-States in Renaissance Italy, London, UK: Taylor & Francis.Google Scholar
Moselle, B. and Polak, B. (2001), ‘A Model of a Predatory State’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 17(1): 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munger, M. C. (2019), ‘Tullock and the Welfare Costs of Corruption: There is a “Political Coase Theorem”’, Public Choice, 181(1–2): 83100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muralidharan, K., Niehaus, P. and Sukhtankar, S. (2016), ‘Building State Capacity: Evidence from Biometric Smartcards in India’, American Economic Review, 106(10): 28952929.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murtazashvili, I. and Murtazashvili, J. (2016), ‘When Does the Emergence of a Stationary Bandit Lead to Property Insecurity?’, Rationality and Society, 28(3): 335360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murtazashvili, J. and Murtazashvili, I. (2019), ‘Wealth-Destroying States’, Public Choice, forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Najemy, J. M. (2008), A History of Florence, 1200–1575, Hoboken, USA: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Niskanen, W. Jr. ([1971] 2007), Bureaucracy and Representative Government, Piscataway, USA: Aldine Transaction.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1979), ‘A Framework for Analyzing the State in Economic History’, Explorations in Economic History, 16(3): 249259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J. and Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norwich, J. J. (2003), A History of Venice, London, UK: Penguin.Google Scholar
Nunn, N. (2009), ‘The Importance of History for Economic Development’, Annual Review of Economics, 1(1): 6592.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1993), ‘Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development’, American Political Science Review, 87(3): 567576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1995), ‘Why the Transition from Communism is so Difficult’, Eastern Economic Journal, 21(4), 437461.Google Scholar
Onis, Z. (1991), ‘The Logic of the Developmental State’, Comparative Politics, 24(1): 109126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2009), Understanding Institutional Diversity, Princeton, USA: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piano, E. E. (2019), ‘State Capacity and Public Choice: A Critical Survey’, Public Choice, 178(1–2): 289309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, P. (2000), ‘Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics’, American Political Science Review, 94(2): 251267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, N. and Birdzell, B. E. (2008), How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transformation of the Industrial World, New York, USA: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Salter, A. W. (2015), ‘Rights to the Realm: Reconsidering Western Political Development’, American Political Science Review, 109(4): 725734.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salter, A. W. (2016), ‘Post-Cameralist Governance: Towards a Robust Political Economy of Bureaucracy’, Economic Affairs, 36(3): 294308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salter, A. W. and Young, A. T. (2018), ‘Medieval Representative Assemblies: Collective Action and Antecedents of Limited Government’, Constitutional Political Economy, 29(2): 171192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Salter, A. W. and Young, A. T. (2019), ‘Polycentric Sovereignty: The Medieval Constitution, Governance Quality, and the Wealth of Nations’, Social Science Quarterly, 100(4): 12411253.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schevill, F. (1909), Siena: The Story of Mediaeval Commune, New York, USA: Charles Scribner's Sons.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. (1987), ‘The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power’, American Political Science Review, 81(1): 85104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skarbek, D. (2011), ‘Governance and Prison Gangs’, American Political Science Review, 105(4): 702716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, D. (2007), ‘Cities, Constitutions, and Sovereign Borrowing in Europe, 1274–1785’, International Organization, 61(3): 489525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1992), ‘Law or Economics?’, The Journal of Law and Economics, 35(2): 455468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thrasher, J. and Vallier, K. (2018), ‘Political Stability in the Open Society’, American Journal of Political Science, 62(2): 398409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tiebout, C. M. (1956), ‘A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures’, Journal of Political Economy, 64(5): 416424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, C. (1990), Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990, Cambridge, UK: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (2005), Bureaucracy, Indianapolis, USA: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Vahabi, M. (2016), ‘A Positive Theory of the Predatory State’, Public Choice, 168(3–4): 153175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volckart, O. (2000), ‘State-building by Bargaining for Monopoly Rents’, Kyklos, 53(3): 265291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Mises, L. (1944), Bureaucracy, New Haven, USA: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Wagner, R. E. (2012), ‘The Cameralists: Fertile Sources for a New Theory of Public Finance’, in Backhaus, J. (ed.), Handbook of the History of Economic Though, New York, USA: Springer, pp. 123135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, P. (2002), Absolutism in Central Europe, London, UK: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittman, D. (1989), ‘Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.’ Journal of Political Economy, 97(6): 13951424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, A. T. (2016), ‘What Does it Take for a roving Bandit Settle Down? Theory and an Illustrative History of the Visigoths’, Public Choice, 168(1–2): 75102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, A. T. (2018), ‘Hospitalitas: Barbarian Settlements and Constitutional Foundations of Medieval Europe’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 14(4): 715737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar