Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-grxwn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T05:50:42.123Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Religious prohibition and sacrifice: evidence from the Amish restriction on high school education

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 September 2020

Liang Choon Wang*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Monash Business School, Monash University, Clayton, Victoria, 3800, Australia
*
Corresponding author. E-mail: liang.c.wang@monash.edu

Abstract

The Amish collective objection to high school education and refusal to comply with compulsory schooling laws can be interpreted with a religious-club-good framework. According to the religious-club interpretation, the Amish use the restriction on secular education as a religious prohibition and sacrifice to improve the welfare of sect members. I exploit the 1972 U.S. Supreme Court's decision in Wisconsin vs. Yoder, which exempts Amish children from compulsory high school education, as a policy shock to test several key predictions of the religious-club explanations. The evidence suggests that the successful restriction on high school education helped the Amish sect exclude individuals with low religious participation, lower members' shadow cost of time, and grow the sect through higher fertility.

Type
Research Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain 2020

1. Introduction

The Amish stirred heated debates in the United States in the mid-twentieth century by stubbornly refusing to comply with compulsory school attendance laws. Their insistence on the eighth grade as the final year of formal schooling, on the basis of their religious belief, frequently led to fines, prosecutions, and even imprisonment by local authorities. After numerous court cases and decades of struggles against the state, the Amish were eventually exempted from compulsory high school education on the grounds of religious liberty by the 1972 U.S. Supreme Court's decision in “State of Wisconsin vs. Jonas Yoder et al.” (Wisconsin vs. Yoder). Given the positive returns to education widely documented in the economics literature, it appears puzzling why the Amish would collectively enforce a ceiling on years of schooling.

This paper extends Iannaccone's (Reference Iannaccone1992) religious club goods model to offer a rational-choice explanation for why the Amish would collectively restrict high school education. The model posits that religious activities among Amish members generate a positive externality to the Amish sect, which an Amish individual does not take into consideration in utility maximization. First, by restricting high school education, the Amish can increase the amount of religious activities chosen within the sect through the price effect of lower wage rates and achieve the socially optimal level. Second, in the presence of unobserved heterogeneity, if the Amish can successfully prohibit high school education, they effectively exclude Amish youths who would lower the positive externality in the sect. The prohibition of high school education serves as a religious sacrifice to help the Amish sect exclude individuals with high shadow cost of time and low religious commitment. According to the religious club goods model, the Amish clashed with the government because compulsory schooling laws imposed a level of schooling exceeding the social optimum for the sect.

The religious club goods model yields a set of testable assumptions and predictions. First, the model predicts that the Supreme Court's ruling would lead to lower educational attainment among the Amish since their restriction on high school education was no longer prevented by the government. Second, the successful prohibition on high school education would reduce the wage rate and increase the fertility of affected Amish individuals. Third, the exemption from compulsory schooling laws permits the Amish to exclude individuals who on average are less likely to attach to the sect and its activities. If the restriction on high school education acts as a religious sacrifice for the Amish to exclude Amish youths who have low religious participation, the Supreme Court's decision should lead to Amish youths with high labor productivity (shadow cost of time) and low fertility leaving the sect. Fourth, exempted Amish individuals with low labor productivity are expected to increase their religious participation due to the price (wage) effect of the exemption. In contrast, exempted Amish individuals with higher labor productivity but chose to remain in the sect might actually decrease religious participation due to the negative income effect of the exemption on their earnings.

Because the Amish speak Pennsylvania Dutch, I can use the U.S. census data to test the model's predictions. The census data reveal that Amish individuals on average have lower educational attainment, lower earnings, lower work hours, and larger family size than former Amish and non-Amish individuals. I estimate that the Supreme Court's decision led to an increase in Amish high school dropout rates by 15 percentage points to 25 percentage points for males and 6 percentage points to 13 percentage points for females. The Supreme Court's exemption decreased average years of completed schooling by 8–10 months for Amish males and 4–12 months for Amish females. The exemption lowered hourly earnings by 23% to 34% and increased births by 0.16–0.34. When I implement a difference-in-difference estimator using non-Amish individuals as a control group to address cohort differences not affected by the exemption, the estimates are similar for earnings, but a little larger for fertility.

If we attribute the fall in log hourly earnings or the increase in fertility to the decrease in educational attainment driven by the exemption, the implied return to education is estimated to be 21–32% in wages and the implied effect of an additional year of schooling on fertility is estimated to be −0.91 births. These estimates are much greater in magnitude than the estimated causal effects of education on earnings and fertility reported by numerous past studies. They are also more than 3–4 times the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates based on a cross-sectional sample of Amish individuals. The large implied effects of education suggest that the Amish became successful in using the restriction on high school education to induce Amish youths who tend to have low religious participation to leave the sect. Exempted Amish youths who chose to stay in the sect have much lower labor productivity and greater fertility rates than older and non-exempted Amish individuals, amplifying the estimated effects of education. When I examine the differential effects of the exemption at various points of the conditional distribution of annual employment hours, which serve as a rough proxy for the lack of religious participation, I find that employment hours decrease at the 0.1 quantile, increase at the 0.9 quantile, and remain unchanged at the mean. The results imply that the restriction on high school education serves as both a religious prohibition that influences the price of religious participation and also a religious sacrifice that induces desirable selection. Given the large implied effects of education and the lack of an employment effect, the findings suggest that the selection effect of religious sacrifice plays a more prominent role than the substitution effect of religious prohibition for the Amish.

The current paper is closely related to Reference ChoyChoy's (in press) paper which also offers insights into the effects of secular education restriction on Amish families. Reference ChoyChoy (in press) develops an overlapping generation model that explains the roles of religious rules and (shunning) punishment in promoting cooperation and altruism within Amish families. He shows theoretically and empirically that as wealthier Amish parents have better capability than poorer Amish parents to impose strong shunning punishment to prevent their children from leaving the sect, the probability of children leaving the sect is inversely related to parental wealth proxied by land size. One of his model extensions shows that the probability of an Amish individual leaving the sect is increasing in the amount of secular education they receive. We can potentially explain the current findings through the lens of Reference ChoyChoy's (in press) model. Accordingly, when Amish parents could not effectively restrict high school education, only the relatively wealthy parents were able to prevent their children from leaving the sect through their stronger punishment power. The Supreme Court's ruling enables poorer parents to keep their children in the sect. The model, however, does not provide further predictions about type selection in the labor productivity dimension like the religious club goods model does. To fully explain the current findings with Reference ChoyChoy's (in press) model, we need to assume further that Amish children's labor productivity is increasing in parental wealth, which is a relationship that we do not have the data to substantiate.

The predictions offered by the religious club goods model for the effects of education restriction are identical to the predictions offered by Carvalho et al.'s (Reference Carvalho, Koyama and Sacks2017) identity model for the effects of education restriction in the context of the ultra-Orthodox Jews. According to Carvalho et al.'s (Reference Carvalho, Koyama and Sacks2017) identity model, when there is a rise in the returns to education, low labor productivity individuals may benefit from restricting education as they individually gain more from retaining their religious identity than they do from the returns to additional secular education. Furthermore, by imposing a restriction on education, the religious organization “can improve individual welfare further and attract members by (imperfectly) screening out individuals with secular values” [Carvalho et al. (Reference Carvalho, Koyama and Sacks2017, p. 128)]. Given that the Amish emphasize community solidarity and suppress individualism [Kraybill (Reference Kraybill2001)], the focus of the religious club goods model on community gains is perhaps more appropriate in the context of the Amish restriction on high school education.

Iannaccone's (Reference Iannaccone1992) religious club goods model has been applied, extended, and tested in a number of settings, including Israeli ultra-Orthodox Jews [Berman (Reference Berman2000)], radical Muslim groups [Berman and Stepanyan (Reference Berman and Stepanyan2004)], Jewish emancipation and schism [Carvalho and Koyama (Reference Carvalho and Koyama2016)], low European Catholic fertility [Berman et al. (Reference Berman, Iannaccone and Ragusa2018)], religious terrorists [Berman and Iannaccone (Reference Berman and Iannaccone2006), Berman and Laitin (Reference Berman and Laitin2008)], and voluntary contribution mechanism [Aimone et al. (Reference Aimone, Iannaccone, Makowsky and Rubin2013)]. In particular, Berman and Laitin's (Reference Berman and Laitin2008) explanation for the effectiveness of radical religious groups in conducting acts of terrorism lies crucially on their ability to use religious sacrifice to screen committed operatives or exclude uncommitted members. Aimone et al. (Reference Aimone, Iannaccone, Makowsky and Rubin2013) show that selection effect is more prominent than price effect and that selection enhances the positive relationship between the size of sacrifice and members' contributions to the club in their laboratory experiment where subjects participate in a modified voluntary contribution mechanism game. There is, however, limited field evidence on the relationship between increased sacrifice, type selection, and growth in group size through natural population growth. This paper provides empirical evidence on how religious sacrifice facilitates the effective selection of the desirable type of members and enables population growth through fertility increase, and shows how public policies can influence outcomes of religious sects. The finding that individuals with higher labor productivity are more likely to leave the Amish sect also echoes research by Abramitzky (Reference Abramitzky2008, Reference Abramitzky2009) that shows productive individuals have a higher tendency to exit Israeli kibbutzim, which practice income sharing. Given the increasing tension between religious groups and states around the globe, understanding how public policies can affect a religious group's capability to increase religious participation and grow its population may shed light on options available to government in influencing the size of religious sect, as well as contributes to the debates pertaining to the freedom to exercise religious beliefs.

2. Background: Amish society and its educational conflicts with the state

Founded by Jacob Ammann in Alsace, France in the 1690s, the Amish are a religious sect that split from the Swiss Anabaptist Mennonites when Ammann advocated the shunning of excommunicated members in daily life.Footnote 1 Sociopolitical instability and religious persecution in Europe prompted the Amish to migrate to America and settle in Lancaster, Pennsylvania, in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries [Hostetler (Reference Hostetler1993, pp. 31–34)]. In 2000, there were approximately 200,000 Amish residing in the United States, roughly 70% of which are in Pennsylvania, Indiana, and Ohio [Kraybill and Hostetter (Reference Kraybill and Nelson Hostetter2001, pp. 75–77)].Footnote 2 Eighty-five percent of Amish are Old Order Amish, who are the most conservative, whereas other Amish groups, such as New Order Amish, Beachy Amish, and Amish Mennonite, are more progressive [Kraybill and Hostetter (Reference Kraybill and Nelson Hostetter2001, pp. 66–67)].

The Amish and other Anabaptists strive to maintain a simple Christian life that discourages material success, seeking to separate themselves from the world and worldly influences. The emphasis on separation from the world governs many of Amish customs, including dress codes, the use of technology, attitudes toward education, and the choice of school. The conduct of an Amish person is regulated by the Ordnung of each congregation, which is a set of standards or expectations for behavior [Kraybill (Reference Kraybill2001, p. 112)]. Unlike other Christian denominations, the Amish and other Anabaptists practice adult baptism. Starting from age 16, unbaptized Amish youths participate in Rumspringa and may leave their communities for the outside world. After experiencing secular life for a few years, adolescents who decide to be baptized into the Church become full-pledged members.Footnote 3 Each Amish community is organized around a church district, which typically consists of 30 families with 60 baptized adults and 75 unbaptized youths. The small size of congregations facilitates both mutual aid provision and social insurance; members help each other with barn raisings, harvesting, quilting, births, weddings, and funerals and assistance in the events of drought, disease, death, injury, bankruptcy, and medical emergency [Kraybill and Bowman (Reference Kraybill and Bowman2001, p. 113)].

The Amish believe that 8 years of formal schooling is adequate to equip their children with basic skills necessary to be good famers and citizens and to interact with non-Amish people in general. The Amish object to high school education because it exposes their children to worldly influences in conflict with their beliefs. Typical high school curricula and activities not only unnecessary for successful careers in Amish life but also stir aspirations and raise occupational hopes that turn Amish youths away from farm and family [Kraybill (Reference Kraybill2001, pp. 175–176)].

The Amish preferred one-room schoolhouses, common in rural America throughout the middle of the twentieth century, because the small scale rural allows the community convenient access and control over multiple facets of their children's education. Parents can unexpectedly visit the classroom, the school board can hire Amish teachers (or otherwise sympathetic) teachers and adjust class schedules when special occasions arise [Meyers (Reference Meyers and Kraybill1993)]. The small local public schools gave the Amish limited contact with non-Amish people and taught the basic skills needed [Huntington (Reference Huntington, Kraybill and Olshan1994)]. As state authorities consolidated rural public schools and enforced high school attendance, especially during the post-WWII period, the Amish resisted and formed parochial schools to avoid compulsory high school attendance and maintain their traditional education standards.

The first recorded conflict between the Amish and school officials occurred in 1914 in Geauga County, Ohio, when Amish fathers were fined for not sending their children under 16 to public high school [Meyers (Reference Meyers and Kraybill1993)]. Over the next 60 years, Amish people continued to face opposition over schooling-related issues from state and local school authorities. Their refusal to comply with compulsory attendance laws frequently led to fines and imprisonments of Amish fathers. Similarly, Amish parochial schools that hired noncertified teachers, who typically had only 8 years of education, also faced repeated shut-down attempts from state agents.

After numerous conflicts between the Amish and school authorities, a compromise was finally reached between the Amish and the state of Pennsylvania in 1956. The concession allowed Amish children who were at least 14 and passed the eighth grade to attend a special vocational school until they were at least 15 years old. Once a week, the children would meet for a minimum of 3 h with an Amish teacher to study English, mathematics, health, and social studies and to report on their week's work at home [Meyers (Reference Meyers and Kraybill1993)]. Classroom learning was supplemented by home projects in agriculture and homemaking [Hostetler and Huntington (Reference Hostetler and Huntington1971, p. 71)]. Attendance records were kept and forwarded to the state. In 1958, a similar settlement was reached in Ohio.Footnote 4 Nevertheless, Ohio state authorities frequently attempted to shut down “substandard” Amish vocational schools and forced Amish children to attend public high schools throughout the 1960s [Meyers (Reference Meyers and Kraybill1993)]. In 1967, a comparable vocational training program was also established in Indiana for Amish children younger than 16 [Hostetler and Huntington (Reference Hostetler and Huntington1971, p. 99)].Footnote 5 However, conflicts between the Amish and school authorities continued in other states throughout the 1960s.

In 1969, three Amish parents were found guilty of violating Wisconsin's compulsory attendance laws for declining to send their children to public high school after finishing the eighth grade in Green County [Keim (Reference Keim1975, p. 151)].Footnote 6 Subsequent appeals to the circuit court failed. In 1971, the Amish brought the case to the Supreme Court of Wisconsin, which reversed the lower courts' decision. Unsatisfied with the result, the State of Wisconsin pressed on to the Supreme Court of the United States. On May 15, 1972, the U.S. Supreme Court ruled that the Amish had the right to refuse their children a high school education [Meyers (Reference Meyers and Kraybill1993)]. Since this decision, the Amish have been able to enforce the prohibition of high school education without governmental interference.

3. A religious club goods model

In this section, I extend Iannaccone's (Reference Iannaccone1992) religious club goods model to explain why the Amish would prohibit high school education and refuse to comply with compulsory schooling laws. According to the religious-club interpretation, the restriction on high school education allows the Amish to (1) internalize the positive externality generated from the social interaction among sect members; and (2) ensure that Amish youths who later join the sect are less likely to be those who would “free-ride” in the sect.

3.1 The basic model: homogeneous type of Amish

Consider a simple two-period model. In period 2, the utility of a baptized adult Amish is:

$$u_{2i} = u\lpar {S_i\comma \;R_i\comma \;Q} \rpar \quad {\rm where}\;Q = \sum {R_{{-}i}/N} \comma \;$$

An adult Amish derives utility from time spent in religious activities, R, as well as from the consumption of secular goods, S. Religious activities are more satisfying when members engaging in them are more committed. The average amount of religious time spent by other adult Amish members, Q, is a positive externality and can be thought as the quality of the Amish “club.” Mutual aid in the form of community members helping one another with barn raisings, quilt making, harvesting, and weddings are typical examples of Q. For simplicity, assume the current number of other members in the sect, N, is exogenously given.

Adults can participate in the labor force, resulting in a budget constraint of the form:

$$w_iT_2 = pS_i + w_iR_i$$

Total time available in the second period is T 2, which is spent on religious activity R and work hours h (i.e., T 2 = R i + h i). Income is earned at wage rate w i per hour worked and spent on consumption of the secular good S, at price p.

The wage rate, w i, is determined by the level of education chosen when the Amish person was young (i.e., period 1):

$$w_i = w\lpar {E_i} \rpar \quad {\rm where}\;{w}^{\prime}\lpar {E_i} \rpar \gt 0.$$

The above equation describes labor productivity as a function of education.Footnote 7 The assumption that education can only be chosen when young is an obvious simplification, but it is consistent with the observation that education is usually completed before working age. Although it is also common that Amish parents make their children's schooling decisions, Amish youths may pursue higher level of education than the eighth grade during the time of Rumspringa and after leaving the sect, or taking a General Educational Development test after dropping out of school.Footnote 8

In the first period, unbaptized individuals derive utility from leisure only:

$$u_{1i} = u\lpar {l_i} \rpar$$

The young Amish cannot work and must allocate total time T 1 between leisure l and education E:

$$T_1 = l_i + E_i$$

A forward-looking young Amish maximizes life-time utility subject to the time constraint in period 1 and solves the problem by backward induction. Period 2 problem is:

$$\eqalign{& \mathop {\max }\limits_{S_i\comma R_i} u_{2i} = u\lpar {S_i\comma \;R_i\comma \;Q} \rpar \cr & {\rm subject}\;{\rm to}\;w\lpar {E_i} \rpar T_2 = pS_i + w\lpar {E_i} \rpar R_i.}$$

Note that the adult individual takes the wage rate, w and the quality of the club, Q, as given in period 2.

Because the Amish individual does not take into consideration the positive externality generated by his religious activities, the chosen level of R and S will only satisfy the following condition:

$$\displaystyle{{w\lpar {E_i} \rpar } \over p} = MRS_{RS}$$

The person ignores the external benefit of his religious participation, MRS QS, that a social planner would consider in the following condition:

$$\displaystyle{{w\lpar {E_i} \rpar } \over p} = MRS_{RS} + MRS_{QS}$$

Solving the period 2 problem yields the optimal consumption of the secular good $S_i^\ast \lpar {p\comma \;w\lpar {E_i} \rpar \semicolon \;Q} \rpar$, the optimal level of religious activities $R_i^\ast \lpar {p\comma \;w\lpar {E_i} \rpar \semicolon \;Q} \rpar$, and the indirect utility v 2i(p, w(E i);Q). Because the marginal external benefit of religious participation MRSQS is not taken into consideration and that MRSRS is decreasing in R, the privately chosen $R_i^\ast \lpar {p\comma \;w\lpar {E_i} \rpar \semicolon \;Q} \rpar$ and v 2i(p, w(E i);Q) will be lower than the socially desired level.

Assuming no discount factor, the individual's problem in period 1 is:

$$\eqalign{& \mathop {\max }\limits_{E_i} v_i = u_{1i}\lpar {l_i} \rpar + v_{2i}\lpar {\,p\comma \;w\lpar {E_i} \rpar \comma \;Q} \rpar \cr & {\rm subject}\;{\rm to}\;T_1 = l_i + E_i}$$

The first-order condition yields:

$$\displaystyle{{\partial v_{2i}} \over {\partial w_i}}\displaystyle{{\partial w_i} \over {\partial E_i}} = {-}\displaystyle{{\partial u_{1i}} \over {\partial E_i}}$$

The left-hand side term is the marginal benefit of education and the right-hand side term is the marginal cost of education.Footnote 9 Since the individual will select R and S such that the condition w(E i)/p = MRS RS holds (ignoring the term MRS QS) in period 2, the utility maximizing E* will be higher than the socially optimal level.

According to the religious prohibition interpretation, by imposing a level of education lower than the privately chosen level, the Amish sect can make labor market participation relatively less attractive and induce the socially optimal level of religious participation.

3.2 Unobserved heterogeneity and religious sacrifice

When there are unobserved heterogeneous types of Amish persons, the sect can improve social welfare by requesting a “religious sacrifice” from Amish youths in order to discourage free-riders from staying in the club [Iannaccone (Reference Iannaccone1992)]. Following Berman's (Reference Berman2000) exposition, assume two unobserved (labor productivity) types of individuals: high-type (H) Amish and low-type (L) Amish. For each birth cohort, N, the fraction of high-type Amish, θ H, and the fraction of low-type Amish, θ L = 1 − θ H, are exogenously determined.Footnote 10 High-type Amish enjoy higher return to education in the labor market than low-typesFootnote 11:

$${w}^{\prime}_H\lpar E \rpar \gt {w}^{\prime}_L\lpar E \rpar$$

Furthermore, assume that w H(0) ≥ w L(0), so that without education high-type Amish are more productive than low-type Amish in the secular labor market.

Given that high-types have a higher marginal benefit of education than low-types and that both types of Amish face the same marginal cost of education, high-type youths will optimally select more education than low-types, i.e., $E_H^\ast \gt E_L^\ast$. This means that a high-type adult will earn higher wages and participate less in religious activities than a low-type Amish would, i.e., w H > w L and $R_H^\ast \lt R_L^\ast$.Footnote 12

In the absence of an educational restriction, an Amish sect with predominantly low-type individuals will not gain from having a high-type individual in the sect because that person will lower the average level of religious participation in the sect and decrease the welfare of existing members. That is, because v L(p, w;Q L) > v L(p, w;Q H+L), where Q L > Q H+L, $Q_L\equiv \sum {R_L^\ast{/}N_L}$, $Q_{L + H}\equiv \left({\sum {R_L^\ast } + \sum {R_H^\ast } } \right)/N$, and N L ≡ θ L(N + 1) − 1, low-type individuals enjoy higher Q and utility when high-type individuals are excluded from the sect. If the sect imposes a ceiling on education equivalent to that chosen by low-type individuals and high-type individuals choose to leave, then the sacrifice serves to exclude high-type individuals.

However, if the level of education that low-type individuals would choose optimally is not sufficiently low to deter high-type persons from complying with, then the restriction is not effective in excluding free-riders from the sect. That is, it is possible that high-type individuals enjoy a higher level of utility by complying with the low level of education and joining the low-type Amish sect than by forming their own group:

$$v_H\lpar {\,p\comma \;w\lpar {E_L^\ast } \rpar \semicolon \;Q_{H + L}} \rpar \gt v_H\lpar {\,p\comma \;w\lpar {E_H^\ast } \rpar \semicolon \;Q_H} \rpar \comma \;$$

where $Q_{H + L}\equiv \left({\sum {R_H} \lpar {p\comma \;w\lpar {E_L^\ast } \rpar } \rpar + \sum {R_L^\ast } } \right)/N$, and $Q_H\equiv \sum {R_H^\ast{/}N_H}$ and N H ≡ θ H(N + 1) − 1.

If this is the case, then $E_L^\ast$ is not incentive compatible for high-type individuals.

When $E_L^\ast$ is not incentive compatible, the sect has to set the ceiling level of education $\bar{E} \lt E_L^\ast$ to prevent high-type persons from joining the sect. $\bar{E}$ is incentive compatible, such that:

$$v_H\lpar {\,p\comma \;w\lpar {\bar{E}} \rpar \semicolon \;\bar{Q}} \rpar \gt v_H\lpar {\,p\comma \;w\lpar {E_H^\ast } \rpar \semicolon \;Q_H} \rpar \comma \;$$

where $\bar{Q}\equiv \left({\sum {{\bar{R}}_L} + \sum {{\bar{R}}_H} } \right)/N$ and $\bar{R}_i\lpar {p\comma \;w\lpar {\bar{E}} \rpar } \rpar$ for i = H, L. Furthermore, $\bar{E}$ needs to satisfy the participation constraint:

$$v_L\lpar {\,p\comma \;w\lpar {\bar{E}} \rpar \semicolon \;{\bar{Q}}_L} \rpar \gt v_L\lpar {\,p\comma \;w\lpar {E_L^\ast } \rpar \semicolon \;Q_{H + L}} \rpar \comma \;$$

where $\bar{Q}_L\equiv \sum {{\bar{R}}_L/N_L}$.

Choosing $\bar{E}$ is costly because if types were fully observable, low-type Amish would have chosen $E_L^\ast$ and enjoyed a higher level of utility. We may view $\bar{E}$ as grade eight and $E_L^\ast$ as a high school education. High-type individuals will not comply with the educational restriction $\bar{E}$ and will choose to leave the sect.Footnote 13 Since education can only be chosen when young in this simple model, the sacrifice is an “irreversible” act.

3.3 Government enforcement of compulsory schooling laws

When the government enforced compulsory high school attendance, the Amish could not achieve their socially efficient level of education. In the homogeneous case, when the government enforced compulsory high school attendance, non-exempted Amish cohorts attended high school. High school education “causally” increased their labor productivity and shadow cost of time, leading to lower average time high school-educated Amish spent on Amish activities. In the heterogeneous case, when compulsory schooling laws were enforced on the Amish, the Amish sect could not impose the optimal amount of religious sacrifice and admitted members who would lower the average level of Amish activities in the sect. These explain why the Amish would refuse to comply with compulsory schooling laws.

3.4 Testable implications

According to the Amish religious club goods model, the U.S. Supreme Court's ruling permitted the Amish to enforce their socially optimal level of education. The compulsory schooling exemption switched the Amish from an environment in which they were constrained by the government when setting their optimal level of prohibition and sacrifice to one in which they were unconstrained. Thus, the model predicts that the exemption should have an immediate impact on the educational attainment of Amish individuals. With lower educational attainment, we would expect lower labor productivity (wage rates) and higher fertility among exempted Amish.

If the prohibition on high school education solely helps internalizing the positive externality of religious activities, then we would not expect high-type individuals leaving the sect following the exemption. However, if the restriction on high school education also serves as a religious sacrifice to help exclude members who have low religious participation, then the Amish religious club goods model predicts that (1) Amish individuals tend to have lower labor market wage rates than former Amish or non-Amish individuals; (2) the surprising U.S. Supreme Court's ruling would lead individuals with high labor productivity to leave the sect; and (3) the compulsory schooling exemption would encourage women with high shadow cost of child rearing to select out of the sect. The implication is that Amish fertility increases more than the direct effect of education, leading to the growth in Amish population despite an increase in high-type Amish youths leaving the sect. Moreover, the Amish religious club goods model also predicts that the surprising U.S. Supreme Court's ruling would lead (4) Amish individuals with low labor productivity to increase religious participation given the price effect of lower wages, and (5) Amish individuals with higher labor productivity but who chose to stay to potentially decrease religious participation, as the negative income effect from their lower earnings on religious participation may work against the positive price effect from their lower wage rates on religious participation.

4 Data

Data were sourced from the U.S. censuses to test the religious club goods model's predictions. The Census Bureau collected information of the language spoken at home in recent censuses. According to Meyers and Nolt (Reference Meyers and Nolt2005, p. 61), the Amish and conservative Mennonites represent almost all of the current speakers of Pennsylvania Dutch, which is a German Dialect.Footnote 14 Pollack (Reference Pollack1981) reported that as the Amish people shifted to more liberal Mennonite denominations, they ceased to use Pennsylvania Dutch as their primary language, indicating that speaking Pennsylvania Dutch signals attachment to the Amish and conservative Mennonite Church.Footnote 15 Since I cannot directly identify the religious denominations of Pennsylvania Dutch speakers in the censuses, the Amish referred to in this paper would include some Conservative Mennonites who speak Pennsylvania Dutch.Footnote 16 Specifically, I define a person as an Amish individual when the person resides in a non-single-member household that has at least two Pennsylvania Dutch speakers.Footnote 17 For those who report to speak Pennsylvania Dutch, but live in a non-Pennsylvania Dutch household, I define them as former Amish individuals.Footnote 18 Since former Amish individuals may no longer report to speak Pennsylvania Dutch at home, this method of defining former Amish individuals is likely to lead to severe undercount.Footnote 19 Nevertheless, it provides some crude estimates of the characteristics of former Amish individuals.

Table 1 compares the distributions of Amish population estimates based on different sources of data. The distributions of Amish population estimates across the United States using the decennial censuses are fairly similar to the distributions of Amish population estimated by Kraybill and Hostetter (Reference Kraybill and Nelson Hostetter2001) and Hostetler (Reference Hostetler1993) using Amish Church membership data, with the decennial censuses tending to undercount the total Amish population.Footnote 20 Since 70% of the Amish population resides in Pennsylvania, Ohio, and Indiana, I focus my analysis on individuals living in these three states.

Table 1. Pennsylvania Dutch speakers and Amish population estimates by states

Note: (1) Kraybill and Hostetter's (Reference Kraybill and Nelson Hostetter2001) estimates of Old Order Amish, New Order Amish, Beachy Amish, and Amish Mennonites; (2) Pennsylvania Dutch speaking households in Census 2000; (3) Hostetler's (Reference Hostetler1993) estimates of Old Order Amish; (4) Pennsylvania Dutch speaking households in Census 1990.

Tables 2 and 3 compare the characteristics of the Amish, former Amish, and non-Amish adult population aged 18–64 in 1990 and 2000, respectively. Amish are more likely to drop out of school upon finishing grade eight, to be farmers, to have larger families, and to be employed than former Amish and non-Amish individuals. A high fraction of adult Amish males and females have no more than an eighth-grade education. The fraction of eighth-grade dropouts (i.e., individuals dropping out after completing eighth grade) is less than 5% for non-Amish population and around 15% for former Amish persons, but as much as two-thirds for the Amish. Furthermore, the trend in educational attainment is decreasing for the Amish population, but increasing for the non-Amish and former Amish population. The low educational attainment reported here for the Amish is consistent with their objection to high school education. The educational attainment of the Amish is also much lower than members of other religious sects in the United States [Iannaccone (Reference Iannaccone1992)]. Amish individuals tend to have higher employment rates, potentially because they refuse any form of government assistance, including unemployment insurance, and cannot devote as much time to job search when unemployed. It may also be because the Amish have a stronger social network, which makes finding employment easier than for non-Amish people.Footnote 21 The observation that Amish have larger family size is consistent with previous findings regarding the high fertility rates of the Amish.Footnote 22

Table 2. Descriptive statistics by groups – Census 1990

Note: Native-born adult population aged 18–64 living in Pennsylvania, Indiana, and Ohio. Eighth-grade dropout means having no more than an eighth-grade education. Years of education was coded according to Park's (Reference Park1994) method. Former Amish are sole speakers of Pennsylvania Dutch in non-single-member households. Non-positive earnings were dropped. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. ***Significant 1%, **significant 5%, *significant 10%.

Table 3. Descriptive statistics by groups – Census 2000

Note: Native-born adult population aged 18–64 living in Pennsylvania, Indiana, and Ohio. Eighth-grade dropout means having no more than an eighth-grade education. Years of education was coded according to Park's (Reference Park1994) method. Former Amish are sole speakers of Pennsylvania Dutch in non-single-member households. Non-positive earnings were dropped. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses. ***Significant 1%, **significant 5%, *significant 10%.

Tables 2 and 3 also show that the Amish participate less in the labor force, have lower earnings, and work fewer hours on average than former Amish persons and non-Amish persons. These estimates are consistent with the idea that Amish may spend more time on unpaid community activities. The wage gap between the Amish and non-Amish populations is similar to the relative differences in incomes between adherents to most Church-like religious groups and sect members in the United States reported by Iannaccone (Reference Iannaccone1992) and between Israeli ultra-Orthodox Jews and non-ultra-Orthodox Jews reported by Berman (Reference Berman2000).Footnote 23 However, the differences documented here do not imply that the Amish are disadvantaged. Indeed, the Amish eschew material wealth and many Amish activities and mutual aids are non-monetary in nature.

The simple comparison between Amish, former Amish, and non-Amish population shows that Amish individuals have fewer years of completed schooling, earn significantly less, and participate less in labor market activities. The differences are consistent with the Amish religious club goods model's predictions. In the next section, I exploit the policy shock induced by the U.S. Supreme Court's decision to test the model's predictions.

5. Empirical evidence

5.1 The impact of exemption on dropout and years of completed schooling

Based on the pooled sample of 1990 and 2000 censuses, Figure 1 shows the fraction of eighth-grade dropouts by Amish and non-Amish birth cohorts living in Pennsylvania, Ohio, and Indiana. The figure clearly reveals that the cohorts born before 1958, who reached age 14 before the Supreme Court's 1972 ruling in Wisconsin vs. Yoder and were affected by compulsory high school attendance laws, are considerably more likely to have some high school education. In contrast, there is no discernible difference in the fraction of dropouts for non-Amish cohorts who are never exempted by the U.S. Supreme Court's decision.

Figure 1. Cohort differences in eighth-grade dropout. Notes: Author's own calculation based on pooled Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). Sample includes Amish and non-Amish residing in Pennsylvania, Indiana, and Ohio. Non-Amish are native born white population. Eighth-grade dropout means having no more than an eighth-grade education.

I estimate the impact of the exemption on the probability of an Amish person not pursuing a high school education using the following linear probability model:

$$Dropout_i = \alpha _0 + \alpha _1Post_i + {X}^{\prime}_i\alpha + u_i$$

where Dropout takes the value 1 if person i did not pursue a high school education upon completing grade eight, and 0 otherwise; Post indicates if the person was born in 1958 or after (exempted by compulsory high school attendance laws); X is a set of control variables, including metropolitan indicator and state dummies; and u is the error term. The coefficient α 1 measures the cohort difference in the likelihood of an Amish dropping out of school upon completing grade eight. Using only individuals born between 1956 and 1959 as the sample, we can avoid confounding cohort effects other than that due to the exemption.

Tables 4 and 5 report the estimated α 1 for males and females, respectively. Columns (1)–(3) report estimates using Census 1990, columns (4)–(6) report estimates using Census 2000. According to the preferred specification (columns 3 and 6) that controls for residential location, the effect of the exemption from compulsory high school education on the probability of an Amish male to drop out of school upon completing grade eight is estimated to be 24 percentage points based on Census 1990 data and 15 percentage points using Census 2000 data. On the other hand, the exemption is estimated to increase the likelihood of an Amish female not pursuing a high school education by 9 percentage points based on Census 1990 data and 13 percentage points based on Census 2000 data.

Table 4. Amish male cohort differences in high school dropout likelihood

Note: Author's estimates using Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable, Dropout, means having no more than an eighth-grade education. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 are included in the sample. Exempted cohorts were born in 1958 and 1959. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Table 5. Amish female cohort differences in high school dropout likelihood

Note: Author's estimates using Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable, Dropout, means having no more than an eighth-grade education. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 are included in the sample. Exempted cohorts were born in 1958 and 1959. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

To examine how the exemption affected Amish completed years of schooling, I estimate the following regression model:

$$Education_i = \alpha _0 + \alpha _1Post_i + {X}^{\prime}_i\alpha + u_i$$

where Education is the years of completed schooling; Post equals 1 if the person was born in 1958 and after (exempted by compulsory high school attendance laws), and 0 otherwise; X is a set of control variables, including metropolitan indicator and state dummies; and u is the error term. The coefficient α 1 measures the effect of the exemption on Amish completed years of schooling.

Tables 6 and 7 report the estimates for males and females, respectively. Columns (1)–(3) show estimates based on Census 1990 data, and columns (4)–(6) are based on Census 2000 data. The preferred specification in columns (3) and (6), the compulsory schooling exemption is estimated to decrease the average years completed schooling for Amish males by 0.7 years based on Census 1990 data and by 0.8 years using Census 2000 data. The estimated effect of the exemption on the average years of completed schooling for Amish females is −0.4 years using Census 1990 data and −1 year using Census 2000 data. The average years of completed schooling fall from roughly 9 years (indicated by the intercept terms) to approximately 8 years (see Figure 2).

Figure 2. Cohort differences in mean years of completed schooling. Notes: Author's own calculation based on pooled Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). Sample includes Amish and non-Amish residing in Pennsylvania, Indiana, and Ohio. Non-Amish are native born white population.

Table 6. Amish male cohort differences in mean years of completed education

Note: Author's estimates using Census 1990 data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable, Educ, is years of completed education based on Park's (Reference Park1994) code. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 are included in the sample. Exempted cohorts were born in 1958 and 1959. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Table 7. Amish female cohort differences in mean years of completed education

Note: Author's estimates using Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable, Educ, is years of completed education based on Park's (Reference Park1994) code. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 are included in the sample. Exempted cohorts were born in 1958 and 1959. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

The results show that the exemption permits the Amish to impose their restriction on high school education. The restriction raised the probability of not pursuing a high school education and reduced the average years of completed schooling for both Amish males and females.

5.2 Amish cohort differences in log hourly earnings

Since Amish women have low labor force participation rates, the analysis will focus on Amish males only. Table 8 reports the estimated cohort differences in the log hourly earnings of Amish males based on the following regression model:

$${\rm log}\lpar {Earnings_i} \rpar = \beta _0 + \beta _1Post_i + {X}^{\prime}_i\beta + \epsilon _i$$

where Log(Earnings) is the log hourly earnings; Post equals 1 if the person was born in 1958 and after (exempted by compulsory high school attendance laws), and 0 otherwise; X is a set of control variables, including metropolitan indicator, state dummies, marital status, potential experience, and potential experience squared; and ε is the error term.

Table 8. Amish male cohort differences in log hourly earnings

Note: Author's estimates using Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable, Log(Earnings), is the log hourly wage salary and business or farm income. Experience = Age − Educ − 6. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 are included in the sample. Exempted cohorts were born in 1958 and 1959. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

The estimates reported in columns (1)–(3) and columns (4)–(6) are based on Census 1990 data and Census 2000 data, respectively. The estimated cohort differences reported in columns (1) and (2) or (4) and (5) are similar whether or not indicators for metropolitan status and marital status are included as regressors. Estimates based on Census 1990 show that the exempted Amish cohorts earned roughly 23% less than non-exempted Amish cohorts. Estimates based on Census 2000 indicate that exempted Amish cohorts earned approximately 34% less than non-exempted Amish cohorts.

Since wage is likely to grow with age and work experience, especially for prime working age males, it is possible that the earnings differences presented in columns (1), (2), (4), and (5) of Table 8 are not totally due to the U.S. Supreme Court's decision. Column (3) shows that the estimated cohort difference becomes greater when potential work experience is controlled for, whereas column (6) shows that the estimated cohort difference is not sensitive to the control variables. However, because exempted Amish cohorts are less educated and they started accumulating work experience at younger ages due to the exemption, potential experience is endogenous. Moreover, as the samples cover only four age cohorts, the variation in potential experience is primarily driven by small differences in ages, which are also correlated with the variable Post.Footnote 24 Hence, including potential work experience as a regressor might actually confound the estimated effect of the exemption on log hourly earnings. Given the problems and the little gain associated with controlling for potential experience, estimates without controlling for potential experience are preferred. I will deal with the problems of age and experience in the next section using a difference-in-difference estimator.

5.3 Amish cohort differences in fertility

Table 9 presents the estimated cohort differences in Amish fertility using the following regression model:

$$Chborn_i = \beta _0 + \beta _1Post_i + {X}^{\prime}_i\beta + \epsilon _i$$

where Chborn is the number of children ever born to a woman; Post equals 1 if the woman was born in 1958 and after (exempted by compulsory high school attendance laws), and 0 otherwise; X is a set of control variables, including metropolitan indicator, state dummies, and marital status; and ε is the error term. Because Census 2000 did not collect fertility information, only estimates based on Census 1990 data are reported.

Table 9. Amish female cohort differences in fertility – Census 1990

Note: Author's estimates using Census 1990 data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable, Chborn, is the number of children ever born to a woman. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Columns (1)–(4) use cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 as the sample; column (5) uses cohorts born between 1955 and 1960 as the sample; and column (6) uses cohorts born between 1953 and 1962 as the sample. The variable age is scaled to zero for individuals aged 32 years old (born in 1958). Exempted cohorts were born in 1958 and after. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Columns (1)–(3) present the estimated cohort differences in fertility without controlling for age. Columns (1) and (2) show that exempted Amish women have higher fertility than non-exempted women, who are older. The difference in fertility is roughly 0.35 children. Column (3) shows that controlling for marital status significantly reduces the cohort difference in fertility; exempted Amish women have 0.16 more children than non-exempted women, although the difference is not statistically significant. Given that younger women generally have fewer children than older women, controlling for age may lead to an even greater estimated cohort difference. Column (4) indicates that the estimated cohort difference becomes 0.79 children when age is controlled for. Columns (5) and (6) show that if differential effects of age are allowed for exempted and non-exempted, the cohort difference increases to approximately 0.9 children. However, because the sample covers very few age groups, the estimated cohort differences which have age effects adjusted for are difficult to interpret. Therefore, the estimated cohort difference (without age controls) presented in column (3) is preferred.

5.4 Difference-in-difference estimates

Given the difficulty associated with controlling for age or potential experience in estimating the effects of the exemption on log hourly earnings and fertility, we may use non-Amish individuals as a control group to implement a difference-in-difference estimator to difference out age or work experience specific effect. We can attribute non-Amish cohort differences as differences that are present in the absence of the U.S. Supreme Court's decision.

Table 10 presents the difference-in-difference estimates of the effects of the exemption on log hourly earnings and fertility, respectively. Columns (1) and (2) indicate that the U.S. Supreme Court's decision led to a fall in hourly earnings between 15% and 18% based on Census 1990 data. Columns (3) and (4) show that the exemption decreased hourly earnings by 34% based on Census 2000 data. These estimates are smaller than the Amish cohort differences presented in Table 8.

Table 10. Difference-in-difference estimates of exemption on earnings and fertility

Note: Author's estimates using Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable is Log(Earnings) for estimating the returns to education and Chborn for estimating the effect of education on fertility, respectively. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 are included in the sample. The control group is non-Amish white individuals who were native born. Individuals with zero and top coded annual employment hours are excluded from the log hourly earnings sample. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

According to columns (5) and (6) of Table 10, the U.S. Supreme Court's decision is estimated to increase fertility by 0.28 to 0.46 births. This estimated effect is much larger than the Amish cohort differences presented in column (3) of Table 9, because exempted Amish would have been expected to have fewer children if the exemption were not in place according to the non-Amish cohort difference.

5.5 Implied effects of education on log hourly earnings and fertility

The estimates presented above show that the compulsory schooling exemption led to lower educational attainment, decreased earnings, and higher fertility. If we attribute the decreased earnings and increased fertility solely to the change in completed years of schooling driven by the U.S. Supreme Court's decision, we could estimate the implied returns to education and the implied effect of education on fertility using an instrumental variable estimator. The second-stage instrumental variable regression is:

$$Outcome_i = {\it &#x03C0;} _0 + {\it &#x03C0;} _1 Education_i + {\it &#x03C0;} _2Post_i + {\it &#x03C0;} _3Amish_i + {X}^{\prime}_i{\it &#x03C0;} + \epsilon _i$$

and the first-stage instrumental variable regression is:

$$Education_i = \delta _0 + \delta _1\lpar {Post_i \times Amish_i} \rpar + \delta _2Post_i + \delta _3Amish_i + {X}^{\prime}_i\delta + u_i$$

The dependent variable Outcome is Log(Earnings) or Chborn; the variable Post × Amish serves as the excluded instrument; Amish takes the value of 1 for an Amish person, 0 otherwise; and X is a set of control variables. The coefficient of interest is π 1, which measures the return to education when Outcome is Log(Earnings) and the effect of education on fertility when Outcome is Chborn.

The estimated π 1 does not represent the causal effect of education, because the instrumental variable does not meet the exogenous condition required for the identification of the causal effect of education. As the Amish religious club goods model predicts that individuals with high labor market productivity selected out of the Amish sect, whereas individuals with low labor market productivity selected into the Amish sect following the U.S. Supreme Court's decision, we expect the excluded instrument to be correlated with the error term in the outcome equation.

Columns (1)–(4) of Table 11 report the estimated implied returns to education; and columns (5) and (6) report the implied effect of education on fertility. The specification that includes a set of controls for metropolitan status, marital status, and state of residence is preferred. The estimated implied return to education is large: 21% using Census 1990 data; 32% using Census 2000 data. Similarly, the implied effect of education on fertility is also large: a 1-year decrease in completed years of schooling predicts 0.91 more births.

Table 11. The implied returns to education and effect of education on fertility

Note: Author's estimates using Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable is Log(Earnings) for estimating the returns to education and Chborn for estimating the effect of education on fertility, respectively. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 are included in the sample. The control group is non-Amish white individuals who were native born. Individuals with zero and top coded annual employment hours are excluded from the log hourly earnings sample. The instrumental variable for Educ is (Amish × Post), implying that the effect of the exemption on log hourly earnings or fertility is channeled through education. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Past studies estimated that the causal rates of return to an additional year of schooling range between 7% and 20% [Angrist and Krueger (Reference Angrist and Krueger1991), Card (Reference Card, Ashenfelter and Card1999), Islam et al. (Reference Islam, Ouch, Smyth and Wang2016)]. The estimated rates of return to education of the Amish presented in Table 11 are greater than most estimates previously reported. It is difficult to conceive that the majority of non-exempted Amish who attended classes once a week for one additional year could possibly get as much as a 21–32% return on education. Indeed, columns (1)–(4) of Table 12 show that when a cross-sectional sample of Amish individuals aged 20–50 is used to estimate the returns to education, every additional year of schooling is predicted to raise hourly earnings by only 2.5–5.4%. The low estimated returns to education for the Amish are remarkably similar to those of other religious sects as shown by Berman and Stepanyan (Reference Berman and Stepanyan2004) and Berman (Reference Berman2000).

Table 12. OLS returns to education and effect of education on fertility

Note: Author's estimates using Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable is Log(Earnings) for estimating the returns to education and Chborn for estimating the effect of education on fertility, respectively. The omitted state is Pennsylvania. Amish aged 20–50 are included in the sample. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

The estimated effect of education on fertility reported in column (6) of Table 11 is also significantly larger than past estimates. For example, the estimated causal effect of an additional year of education on fertility was between −0.26 and −0.48 births in Nigeria [Osili and Long (Reference Osili and Long2008)] and −0.23 births in Cambodia [Islam et al. (Reference Islam, Ouch, Smyth and Wang2016)].Footnote 25 When we use a cross-sectional sample of Amish women aged 20–50 years to estimate the effect of education on children ever born, the (OLS) estimate ranges between −0.15 and −0.24 depending on the specifications (columns 5 and 6 of Table 12). On the other hand, the implied effect of education on fertility reported in Table 11 is roughly twice the largest estimate produced by Osili and Long (Reference Osili and Long2008) and almost four times the largest OLS estimate reported in Table 12.

For the implied effect of education on log hourly earnings or fertility to be so large, we would need exempted Amish individuals with high labor productivity leaving the sect and lowering the average hourly earnings or raising the average fertility more than the causal effect of education suggests. To illustrate how this selection affects the estimates, decompose the instrumental variable estimator into the true causal effect and bias:

$$\hat{{\it &#x03C0;} }_1^{IV} \mathop \to \limits^p {\it &#x03C0;} _1 + \displaystyle{{cov\lpar {z_i\comma \;\epsilon_i\vert X_i} \rpar } \over {cov\lpar {z_i\comma \;Education_i\vert X_i} \rpar }} \comma \;$$

where z is the excluded instrument, Amish × Post, π 1 is the true causal effect, cov(z i, ε i|X i)/cov(z i, Education i|X i) is the bias, and X represents all other regressors. According to Tables 4 and 5, we know that cov(z i, Education i|X i) < 0. For $\hat{{\it &#x03C0;} }_1^{IV} \gt {\it &#x03C0;} _1$, it must be the case that cov(z i, ε i|X i) < 0 when estimating the return to education. That is, exempted Amish individuals have unobserved characteristics that are negatively correlated with labor productivity. Similarly, for $\hat{{\it &#x03C0;} }_1^{IV} \lt {\it &#x03C0;} _1$ when estimating the effect of education on fertility, we need cov(z i, ε i|X i) > 0, which is consistent with exempted Amish females having lower shadow cost of child rearing.

Although there is no other direct evidence that Amish youths with high labor productivity and shadow cost of time left the sect following the U.S. Supreme Court's ruling, qualitative evidence based on the stories told by some former Amish is consistent with this selection effect. In the stories of former Old Order Amish members told to Garrett and Garett (Reference Garrett and Irene Garrett1998), there are examples of Amish individuals leaving the sect in the pursuit of more education and a productive career in the mainstream economy. For instance, in the story of LeRoy, some of the main reasons for him to leave the sect was his dream of finishing high school, his eagerness to read and learn of different people and places, and his desire to live a secular life. In the story of Dan, after leaving the sect, he acquired new skills working in the construction industry and eventually owned a successful remodeling business that employed his own crew. Because once a person has left the sect, the person would be either shunned or excommunicated by their own family members, living a non-Amish life without the help of family can be financially difficult. Individuals choosing to leave the sect need to have relatively high labor productivity in the secular labor market in order not to return to the sect. The statement by a former Amish member, Ed, sums it up: “I have the opportunity to see some actual blood kin that also left to better themselves. I have cousins that are lawyers and nurses… I cannot stress enough the importance of an education. Obviously, the others that left the Amish felt the same way, as the majority found the opportunities to continue their education” [Garrett and Garett (Reference Garrett and Irene Garrett1998, p. 45)].

The large estimated effects of education on log hourly earnings and fertility as implied by the surprising U.S. Supreme Court's decision are consistent with the argument that the Amish collectively use the restriction on high school education as a religious sacrifice to discourage individuals with low religious participation and high labor productivity from staying in the sect.

5.6 The impact of exemption on annual employment hours

With the successful restriction on high school education, the religious club goods model predicts potential differential responses in religious participation among Amish individuals who remain in the sect. Amish individuals who are at the bottom tail of the labor productivity distribution are the type that are more likely to remain in the sect and hence experience a positive price effect of lower wage rates on religious participation. In contrast, Amish individuals who are at the upper tail of the labor productivity distribution are the type that are less likely to remain in the sect. If these high-type Amish choose to remain in the sect, their relatively high earnings mean that the negative income effect of lower wage rates on religious participation may dominate over the positive price effect of lower wage rates on religious participation. Differential responses to the U.S. Supreme Court's ruling at different points of the conditional distribution of religious participation will provide further support for the religious club goods model.

Although data on religious participation are not available, we can use annual employment hours as a rough proxy for the lack of religious participation to test these predictions. Specifically, I use a difference-in-difference specification to estimate the conditional treatment effects of the exemption on annual total employment hours of Amish males at the lower and upper quantiles, following Frölich and Melly (Reference Frölich and Melly2010) and Callaway and Li (Reference Callaway and Li2019). Table 13 reports the conditional quantile treatment effects as well as mean effect for comparison. The top panel reports the estimates at the 0.10 quantile. Both Census 1990 and Census 2000 data show that the exemption led to a significant reduction in the labor hours of Amish men at the 0.10 quantile of the conditional distribution. The reduction of 24 to 116 hours is equivalent to between one and four working weeks. The results imply a positive price effect of lower wage rates on the religious participation of Amish men with low labor productivity. The middle panel reports the estimates at the 0.90 quantile. The estimates show that the exemption-induced increase in the labor hours of Amish men at the 0.90 quantile of the conditional distribution is in the range of 9–18 working weeks. The results imply that the negative income effect of lower wage rates on the religious participation more than compensates the positive price effect of lower wage rates on the religious participation for Amish men with higher labor productivity. Finally, the bottom panel reports the estimates at the mean, which indicate that the net effect of the exemption on employment hours is close to zero.

Table 13. Difference-in-difference estimates of exemption on employment hours

Note: Author's estimates using Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (Reference Ruggles, Flood, Goeken, Grover, Meyer, Pacas and Sobek2020). The dependent variable is total annual employment hours. All specifications include a post-exemption cohort indicator, Amish indicator, metropolitan status indicator, marital status indicator, and a set of state dummies. Male cohorts born between 1956 and 1959 are included in the sample. The control group is non-Amish white males who were native born. Individuals with zero and top coded employment hours are excluded from the sample. Robust standard errors reported in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

The results are consistent with the religious-club interpretation that the restriction on high school education serves as both a religious prohibition that aims to increase religious participation of Amish individuals and also a religious sacrifice that helps the Amish sect exclude Amish youths who tend to have low religious participation from staying in the sect. The zero effect of the exemption on total annual employment hours at the mean together with the large implied effects of education on earnings and fertility suggest that the restriction on education primarily promotes a selection effect. This stronger evidence of selection effect is similar to what Aimone et al. (Reference Aimone, Iannaccone, Makowsky and Rubin2013) has shown in their laboratory experiment. Since we do not have direct measures of religious participation, the interpretation here must be applied with the data limitation in mind.

6. Conclusion

Given the positive returns to education, Amish prohibition on high school education appears puzzling from a rational choice perspective. This paper uses Iannaccone's (Reference Iannaccone1992) religious-club-good framework to explain why the Amish would collectively restrict education. According to the religious-club interpretation, restricting secular education helps the Amish internalize the positive externality of religious participation and exclude Amish youths who are more likely to free-ride the religious club goods from staying in the sect. Because the enforcement of compulsory high school attendance by the government interfered with Amish community's socially efficient level of education, the Amish collectively refused to comply.

Interpreting the restriction on secular education as a religious prohibition and sacrifice is testable. When the government was enforcing compulsory schooling laws on the Amish, Amish born individuals with high labor productivity and low religious participation (high-type Amish) could legitimately attend high school. These high-type individuals would have been deterred from staying in the sect if the Amish could effectively request them to sacrifice high school education. The surprising U.S. Supreme Court's decision in 1972, which exempts the Amish from compulsory education beyond the eighth grade, permits the Amish to enforce their desired level of religious sacrifice. This increased religious sacrifice predicts that high-type Amish would leave the sect following the exemption. With the successful prohibition on high school education, Amish youths who choose to stay in the sect would face lower wage rates and participate more in religious activities. This price effect of lower wage rates on religious participation is likely to be most pronounced among Amish individuals with relatively low labor productivity.

I use U.S. Census data to test the predictions of the Amish religious club goods model. First, I find that former Amish persons are more educated and enjoy relatively higher earnings than Amish persons on average. Second, exempted Amish cohorts have significantly lower educational attainment than non-exempted Amish cohorts. Third, the exemption led to lower earnings and higher births. The estimated effects of each additional year of Amish education on log hourly earnings (between 0.21% and 0.32%) and fertility (−0.91 births) implied by the exemption are much greater than past causal estimates. The large implied effects of education suggest that individuals with high labor productivity and high shadow cost of child rearing select out of the sect following the U.S. Supreme Court's ruling. As a result of the Supreme Court's ruling, the Amish are able to achieve population growth through increased fertility rates despite increased attrition among individuals with high labor productivity and high shadow cost of child rearing.

I also find a price effect of lower wage rates on annual employment hours, which serve as a rough proxy for the lack of religious participation, for Amish men with low labor productivity. In contrast, the income effect of lower wage rates on annual employment hours is particularly strong for Amish men with high labor productivity. Evidence of these differential effects provides further support for the religious-club interpretation. However, the net effect of the exemption on total annual employment hours is zero at the mean. Given the large implied effects of education on earnings and fertility and an overall zero employment effect from the successful restriction on high school education, it appears that the restriction on education primarily facilitates type selection and fertility growth for the Amish.

Acknowledgments

I thank Eli Berman, Julian Betts, Tiffany Chou, John Evans, Nora Gordon, Daniel Hamermesh, Larry Iannaccone, Alex Ivanov, Jacob LaRievere, Rachel McCleary, Craig McIntosh, Birendra Rai, and anonymous reviewers for detailed comments and suggestions. Comments and suggestions by seminar and conference participants at the Meetings of the Association for the Study of Religion, Economics, and Culture (2009), Monash University, UC San Diego, and the Graduate Workshop on Religion, Economics, and Politics (2008) are also acknowledged.

Footnotes

1 Other Anabaptist groups that are similar to the Amish include conservative Mennonites and the Hutterites.

2 There are also Amish settlements in the Canadian province of Ontario and Latin America.

3 The Amish and other Anabaptists practice adult baptism. The typical age of baptism ranges from 16 to the early-20s for the Old Order Amish, and roughly 60% join the church before they reach 21 [Kraybill (Reference Kraybill2001, p. 117)].

4 In Ohio, students would continue school until the tenth grade [Hostetler and Huntington (Reference Hostetler and Huntington1971, p. 72)].

5 The vocational school program was never started in other states [Huntington (Reference Huntington, Kraybill and Olshan1994, endnote 13)].

6 The Amish parents are Jonas Yoder, Adin Yutzy, and Wallace Miller. Yoder and Yutzy are Old Order Amish, whereas Miller is an Amish Mennonite.

7 Alternatively, we may view education as a signal of (secular) labor productivity in the spirit of Spence (Reference Spence1973). This alternative view may be appropriate if we think that Amish education provides no human capital relevant for the secular labor market, but only serves to signal labor productivity.

8 See McConnell and Hurst (Reference McConnell and Hurst2006) for a discussion of these cases.

9 The term ∂v 2i/∂w i = [∂v 2i/∂(w i/p)][∂(w i/p)/∂w i] is non-negative by the property of an indirect utility function, which is non-increasing in (p/w) and (p/w) is decreasing in w. To obtain an interior solution, we need to assume that the Hessian matrix of the objective function is negative semi-definite.

10 This assumption is restrictive because each generation of N is endogenously affected by Amish fertility (of the older generation) through the level of prohibition and sacrifice set and θ H may also be affected by assortative mating.

11 Heterogeneity could alternatively be in preferences for religious activities at the margin. I chose heterogeneity in secular returns to education to simplify the exposition, as well as to focus on variables with data available.

12 As long as the substitution effect of a change in wage is greater than the income effect of a change in wage, the labor supply curve is upward sloping and religious participation is decreasing in wages.

13 Typically, Amish youths who are not committed will leave the sect during Rumspringa and join the secular community and pursue more education.

14 Dutch comes from “Deutsch,” meaning German. There are also a number of Amish who speak a Swiss-German dialect [Meyers and Nolt (Reference Meyers and Nolt2005, p. 61)]. Since the 1980 Census, the Census Bureau began collecting information on the language spoken at home for persons above a certain age.

15 In 1977, 100% of Old Order Amish families living in Plain City, Ohio, used Pennsylvania Dutch as their primary language, but only 11.8% of Mennonite families used it as their primary language.

16 Conservative Mennonites (Old Order Mennonites) are similar to the Amish in many aspects, such as their plain clothing, horse-and-buggy mode of transportation, preference for one-room parochial schooling, and prohibition of high school education [Kraybill and Bowman (Reference Kraybill and Bowman2001)].

17 In this paper, Pennsylvania Dutch speakers include those who speak Pennsylvania Dutch at home and those with Pennsylvanian German ancestry and speak German at home. I coded a household as a Pennsylvania Dutch household when the household has at least one Pennsylvania Dutch speaker while any other household members speak Pennsylvania Dutch, German, or Dutch. For those who are Dutch or German speaking, they must be native-born to be included. Pennsylvania Dutch speaking people living in single-member households are coded as Amish. If a person is the sole-speaker of Pennsylvania Dutch in a non-single-member household, I code the person as a former Amish person.

18 A person must communicate with other household members using the same language. Individuals who are the sole-speakers of Pennsylvania Dutch at home are likely to identify Pennsylvania Dutch as their mother tongue, instead of “language spoken at home” per se.

19 It is also unclear whether persons who are the sole speaker of Pennsylvania Dutch at home constitute a representative sample of all former Amish.

20 Since both methods provide estimates, it is not clear which one is closer to the truth. It is also not clear whether non-responses will bias the estimates of the characteristics of Amish. The undercount based on censuses may be due to church membership data that include “Swiss Amish” who do not speak Pennsylvania Dutch. Furthermore, the high percentage of children and young adults and the use of non-English language of the Amish are characteristics associated with census undercount. For detailed discussions of census undercount and the extent of undercount, see Edmonston and Schultze (Reference Edmonston and Schultze1995) and Edmonston (Reference Edmonston2002).

21 Amish work for Amish employers, as well as non-Amish employers. For example, Kraybill (Reference Kraybill2001, p. 247) reports that 11% of Old Order Amish adult men aged 21–30 living in Lancaster work for non-Amish employers.

22 Amish total fertility rates were estimated to be between 6 and 8 [see Ericksen et al. (Reference Ericksen, Ericksen, Hostetler and Huntington1979) and Greksa (Reference Greksa2002)].

23 Comparisons based on household incomes reported in Tables 1 and 2 in Iannaccone (Reference Iannaccone1992) and Table 1 in Berman (Reference Berman2000).

24 We may also widen the age window, but that may introduce model specification bias if the effect of age does not follow the specified functional form.

25 The average years of schooling were 5 years [Osili and Long (Reference Osili and Long2008)] and total fertility rate was 6 [National Population Commission (2000)] in 1990 for Nigeria. The figures were 3.1 years and 4.4 births, respectively, for women born between 1950 and 1965 in Cambodia.

References

Abramitzky, Ran (2008) The limits of equality: insights from the Israeli Kibbutz. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, 11111159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abramitzky, Ran (2009) The effects of redistribution on migration: evidence from the Israeli Kibbutz. Journal of Public Economics 93, 498511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aimone, Jason, Iannaccone, Laurence R., Makowsky, Michael D. and Rubin, Jared (2013) Endogenous group formation via unproductive costs. Review of Economic Studies 80, 12151236.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Angrist, Joshua D. and Krueger, Alan B. (1991) Does compulsory schooling attendance affect schooling and earnings. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 9791014.Google Scholar
Berman, Eli (2000) Sect, subsidy, and sacrifice: an economist's view of ultra-Orthodox Jews. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115, 905953.Google Scholar
Berman, Eli and Iannaccone, Laurence R. (2006) Religious extremists: the good, the bad, and the deadly. Public Choice 128, 109129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Eli, Iannaccone, Laurence R. and Ragusa, Giuseppe (2018) From empty pews to empty cradles: fertility decline among European Catholics. Journal of Demographic Economics 84, 149187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Eli and Laitin, David (2008) Religion, terrorism and public goods: testing the club model. Journal of Public Economics 92, 19421967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Eli, and Stepanyan, Ara (2004) How many radical Islamists? Indirect evidence from five countries. UCSD Mimeo. https://econweb.ucsd.edu/~elib/funfert.pdfGoogle Scholar
Callaway, Brantly and Li, Tong (2019) Quantile treatment effects in difference in differences models with panel data. Quantitative Economics 10, 15791618.Google Scholar
Card, David (1999) The causal effect of education on earnings. In Ashenfelter, Orley and Card, David (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics 3(A), pp. 18011863. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Carvalho, Jean-Paul and Koyama, Mark (2016) Jewish emancipation and schism: economic development and religious change. Journal of Comparative Economics 44, 562584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carvalho, Jean-Paul, Koyama, Mark and Sacks, Michael (2017) Education, identity, and community: lessons from Jewish emancipation. Public Choice 171, 119143.Google Scholar
Choy, James P. (in press) Religious rules as a means of strengthening family ties: theory and evidence from the Amish. Journal of Comparative Economics. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2019.12.007.Google Scholar
Edmonston, Barry (2002) The Undercount in the 2000 Census. Baltimore, Maryland: The Annie E. Casey Foundation and the Population Reference Bureau.Google Scholar
Edmonston, Barry and Schultze, Charles (1995) Modernizing the U.S. Census: Panel on Census Requirements in the Year 2000 and Beyond. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
Ericksen, Julia A., Ericksen, Eugene P., Hostetler, John A. and Huntington, Gertrude E. (1979) Fertility patterns and trends among the Old Order Amish. Population Studies 33, 255276.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Frölich, Markus and Melly, Blaise (2010) Estimation of quantile treatment effects with Stata. Stata Journal 10, 423457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrett, Ottie A., and Irene Garrett, R. (1998) True Stories of the X-Amish. Horse Cave, KY: New Leuben, Incorporated (New Life).Google Scholar
Greksa, Lawrence P. (2002) Population growth and fertility patterns in an Old Order Amish settlement. Annals of Human Biology 29, 192201.Google Scholar
Hostetler, John A. (1993) Amish Society. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Hostetler, John A. and Huntington, Gertrude E. (1971) Children in Amish Society: Socialization and Community Education. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Huntington, Gertrude E. (1994) Persistence and change in Amish education. In Kraybill, Donald B. and Olshan, Marc A. (eds.), The Amish Struggle with Modernity, pp. 7795. Hanover: University Press of New England.Google Scholar
Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1992) Sacrifice and stigma: reducing free-riding in cults, communes, and other collectives. Journal of Political Economy 100, 271291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Islam, Asadul, Ouch, Chandarany, Smyth, Russell and Wang, Liang C. (2016) The long-term effects of civil conflicts on education, earnings, and fertility: evidence from Cambodia. Journal of Comparative Economics 44, 800820.Google Scholar
Keim, Albert N. (1975) Compulsory Education and the Amish: The Right Not to be Modern. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Kraybill, Donald B. (2001) The Riddle of Amish Culture. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Kraybill, Donald B. and Bowman, Carl F. (2001) On the Backroad to Heaven: Old Order Hutterites, Mennonites, Amish, and Brethren. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Kraybill, Donald B. and Nelson Hostetter, C. (2001) Anabaptist World USA. Scottdale: Herald Press.Google Scholar
McConnell, David L. and Hurst, Charles E. (2006) No “Rip Van Winkles” here: Amish education since Wisconsin v. Yoder. Anthropology and Education Quarterly 37, 236254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyers, Thomas J. (1993) Education and schooling. In Kraybill, Donald B. (ed.), The Amish and the State, pp. 87106. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Meyers, Thomas J. and Nolt, Steven M. (2005) An Amish Patchwork. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
National Population Commission (2000) Nigeria Demographic and Health Survey 1999. Calverton, Maryland: National Population Commission and ORC/Macro.Google Scholar
Osili, Una Okonkwo and Long, Bridget Terry (2008) Does female schooling reduce fertility? Evidence from Nigeria. Journal of Development Economics 87, 5775.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, Jin Heum (1994) Estimation of Sheepskin Effects and Returns to Schooling Using the Old and the New CPS Measures of Educational Attainment. Working Paper No. 335, Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Pollack, Randy Beth (1981) Culture change in an Amish community. Central Issues in Anthropology 3, 5167.Google Scholar
Ruggles, Steven, Flood, Sarah, Goeken, Ronald, Grover, Josiah, Meyer, Erin, Pacas, Jose and Sobek, Matthew (2020) Integrated Public Use Microdata Series USA: Version 10.0 [dataset]. Minneapolis, MN: IPUMS. https://doi.org/10.18128/D010.V10.0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, Michael (1973) Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics 87, 355374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Pennsylvania Dutch speakers and Amish population estimates by states

Figure 1

Table 2. Descriptive statistics by groups – Census 1990

Figure 2

Table 3. Descriptive statistics by groups – Census 2000

Figure 3

Figure 1. Cohort differences in eighth-grade dropout. Notes: Author's own calculation based on pooled Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (2020). Sample includes Amish and non-Amish residing in Pennsylvania, Indiana, and Ohio. Non-Amish are native born white population. Eighth-grade dropout means having no more than an eighth-grade education.

Figure 4

Table 4. Amish male cohort differences in high school dropout likelihood

Figure 5

Table 5. Amish female cohort differences in high school dropout likelihood

Figure 6

Figure 2. Cohort differences in mean years of completed schooling. Notes: Author's own calculation based on pooled Census data sourced from Ruggles et al. (2020). Sample includes Amish and non-Amish residing in Pennsylvania, Indiana, and Ohio. Non-Amish are native born white population.

Figure 7

Table 6. Amish male cohort differences in mean years of completed education

Figure 8

Table 7. Amish female cohort differences in mean years of completed education

Figure 9

Table 8. Amish male cohort differences in log hourly earnings

Figure 10

Table 9. Amish female cohort differences in fertility – Census 1990

Figure 11

Table 10. Difference-in-difference estimates of exemption on earnings and fertility

Figure 12

Table 11. The implied returns to education and effect of education on fertility

Figure 13

Table 12. OLS returns to education and effect of education on fertility

Figure 14

Table 13. Difference-in-difference estimates of exemption on employment hours