Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T00:08:55.929Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Regulatory Oversight and Benefit-Cost Analysis: A Historical Perspective

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 January 2020

Susan E. Dudley*
Affiliation:
The George Washington University Regulatory Studies Center, USA E-mail: sdudley@gwu.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Extract

The Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) in the Executive Office of the President coordinates the federal government’s regulatory agenda, reviews executive branch agencies’ draft regulations, and oversees government-wide information quality, peer review, privacy, and statistical policies. Remarkably, its regulatory oversight functions, and the benefit-cost framework underlying them, have not changed significantly through six very different presidential administrations. This article examines the evolution of executive regulatory oversight and analysis from the 1970s to today, exploring the reasons for its durability and whether the current imposition of a regulatory budget challenges the bipartisan nature of regulatory practice.

Type
Comment
Copyright
© Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis, 2020

The Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) in the Executive Office of the President coordinates the federal government’s regulatory agenda, reviews executive branch agencies’ draft regulations, and oversees government-wide information quality, peer review, privacy, and statistical policies. Remarkably, its regulatory oversight functions, and the benefit-cost framework underlying them, have not changed significantly through six very different presidential administrations. This article examines the evolution of executive regulatory oversight and analysis from the 1970s to today, exploring the reasons for its durability and whether the current imposition of a regulatory budget challenges the bipartisan nature of regulatory practice.

Regulatory oversight before OIRA

The number and reach of regulatory agencies increased dramatically in the early decades of the 20th century. But, the extensive scope of their authorities raised concerns about the constitutionality of Congress’s apparent delegation of its Article I powers to a “fourth branch.” In response to these concerns, Congress passed the Administrative Procedure Act in 1946 to balance the competing goals of bureaucratic expertise and legislative accountability (Shepherd, Reference Shepherd1996). It required that regulations be grounded in statutory authority, that agencies seek public comment before issuing rules, and that final rules be based on an administrative record.

Most of the early regulatory agencies were established as independent commissions to avoid political influence (Humphrey’s Executer v. United States 1935); they generally issued “economic regulations,” which imposed maximum or minimum prices, quantity restrictions, and service parameters (Weidenbaum, Reference Weidenbaum2004). Evidence that these agencies appeared to be “captured” by the industries they regulated (Stigler, Reference Stigler1971) led to bipartisan deregulatory efforts from all three branches of government (Derthick & Quirk, Reference Derthick and Quirk1985).

While economic forms of regulation were declining in the 1970s and 1980s, a new type of “social” regulation – aimed at environmental, safety, and health concerns – began to emerge (Weidenbaum, Reference Weidenbaum2004). Concerns that these new regulations and reporting requirements were overly burdensome led presidents, beginning with Richard Nixon, to take steps to exert some control over them.

President Richard Nixon initiated a “Quality of Life Review” (QLR) in 1971. It required agencies to submit for Office of Management and Budget (OMB) review agendas of upcoming regulatory actions and certain proposed and final rules before publication in the Federal Register (Schultz, Reference Schultz1971; Tozzi, Reference Tozzi2011).

President Gerald Ford built on the QLR and issued E.O. 11821 (1974), which required agencies to develop an “inflation impact statement” for each major legislative or regulatory proposal. Pursuant to E.O. 11949, these later became “economic impact statements” (1977). He signed a bill establishing the Council on Wage and Price Stability (CWPS) to, among other things, “intervene and otherwise participate on its own behalf in rulemaking, ratemaking, licensing and other proceedings before any of the departments and agencies of the USA, in order to present its views as to the inflationary impact that might result from the possible outcomes of such proceedings” (Council on Wage and Price Stability Act Amendments of 1975 Pub. L. 94-78). The CWPS “regulatory review staff … operated as a relatively freewheeling analytical group that selectively and publicly critiqued regulatory proposals from a wide array of federal agencies” (Hopkins, Reference Hopkins2011, p. 71).

President Jimmy Carter discontinued the QLR but retained the CWPS economists’ role in filing comments on the public record of agency rulemakings. Carter’s “program had three principal objectives: improved regulatory management, economic deregulation, and the adoption of less-intrusive regulatory techniques” (Eads & Fix, Reference Eads, Fix, Palmer and Sawhill1982, p. 135). His cabinet-level Regulatory Analysis Review Group served as an “expert regulatory ‘watchdog’” (Fix & Eads, Reference Fix and Eads1985, fn. 19) that reviewed the most important regulatory proposals with analytical support from the CWPS economists (Weidenbaum, Reference Weidenbaum1997).

Carter’s E.O. 12044 required agency heads to determine the need for a regulation, evaluate the direct and indirect effects of alternatives, and choose the least burdensome approach (1978). He signed the Regulatory Flexibility Act, focused on minimizing regulatory impacts on small entities (Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980 Pub. L. 96-354), and the Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA), which established Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) in OMB to review and approve all new reporting requirements to minimize the burdens associated with the government’s collection of information (Paperwork Reduction Act of 1980 Pub. L. 96-511).

OIRA 1981–2019

Soon after he took office in 1981, President Ronald Reagan issued E.O. 12291, giving OIRA a role in reviewing draft regulations to ensure their benefits exceeded their costs (1981). He abolished the wage and price program and moved the group of CWPS economists responsible for filing comments on regulation to the newly created OIRA along with the OMB analysts who had reviewed regulations under Ford and Carter. The directors of the OMB and CWPS units became deputies to the OIRA administrator (Hopkins, Reference Hopkins2011; Tozzi, Reference Tozzi2011). The former budget staff were assigned to specific agencies and responsible for transactional reviews and the PRA, while the CWPS economists focused on economic efficiency and the quality of agencies’ benefit-cost analysis (BCA).

President George H. W. Bush (“Bush 41”), who had served as Reagan’s Vice President and director of his Task Force on Regulatory Relief, continued the policies and practices of the previous eight years. However, one of his chief regulatory advisors observed that “the Bush administration lost the deregulatory momentum of the Reagan years” largely due to “the relaxed commitment to oversight in the Executive Office of the President” (Gray, Reference Gray1993, p. 31).

President Bill Clinton’s election in 1993 stirred hope among critics of OIRA oversight and the net-benefits approach to regulation that he might abolish regulatory review (Katzen, Reference Katzen2018a ). But, he did not act immediately to rescind the Reagan order. Instead, after several iterations and repeat consultations with various agencies and outside groups, President Clinton signed E.O. 12866 (1993) on September 30, 1993 (Katzen, Reference Katzen2018b ). While the new order’s rhetoric was softer than the Reagan order it replaced, it retained the key features of OIRA regulatory review and reinforced the focus on net benefits and the philosophy that regulations should be issued only if required by law or a “compelling public need” (1993, Sec.1.a)

President George W. Bush (“Bush 43”) retained E.O. 12866 but, at least in some respects, his OIRA administrator implemented it more aggressively than his predecessors, for the first time returning draft regulations to agencies for reconsideration pursuant to Sec. 6(b)(3) and sending “prompt letters” that suggested priority actions agencies could take to improve their regulations. During the Bush 43 administration, OMB also issued Circular A-4 on Regulatory Analysis (OMB, 2003), as well as bulletins articulating good practices for guidance documents (OMB, 2007a ), data quality (OMB, 2002), peer review (OMB, 2004), and principles for risk analysis (OMB, 2007b ).

Upon taking office in 2009, President Barack Obama directed his agencies to develop recommendations for a new executive order (Obama, Reference Obama2009), noting that OIRA oversight can serve to “ensure consistency with Presidential priorities, to coordinate regulatory policy, and to offer a dispassionate and analytical ‘second opinion’ on agency actions” (Obama, Reference Obama2009). Two years later, he issued E.O. 13563, which explicitly reaffirmed E.O. 12866 and supplemented it to address technological developments since 1993 as well as periodic review of existing regulations and other issues (2011). President Obama’s E.O. 13579 was significant in that it encouraged independent regulatory agencies to comply with some of E.O. 13563’s provisions, including retrospective review (2011).

President Donald J. Trump came to office in 2016 promising deregulation. His E.O. 13771 directed agencies to remove two regulations for every new one they issued, and to offset the costs of new regulations by removing or modifying existing rules (2017). While his emphasis on reducing regulatory costs departed from previous administrations’ focus on net benefits, he retained the Clinton and Obama executive orders requiring decisions to be made on the basis regulatory benefits and costs. The relevance of a budget constraint overlaid on existing policies is discussed below.

The durability of OIRA’s procedures and principles

Bruff argues that by the end of the Reagan administration, OIRA’s review procedures had gone from having a “distinctly experimental flavor” to “tentative acceptance in the executive branch” (Reference Bruff1989, p. 562). The fact that they have continued through the next five very different presidents (Bush 41, Clinton, Bush 43, Obama, and Trump) confers on them a rare bipartisan status (DeMuth, Reference Demuth2011; Kagan, Reference Kagan2001).

What accounts for the durability of OIRA’s procedures and principles over the course of almost 40 years and six presidents? Procedurally, as Congress delegates lawmaking authority to an increasingly large and complex body of regulatory agencies, OIRA gives the democratically-elected president a vehicle to monitor, and exert some control over, agency actions. While presidents have increased the size of White House staffs over the years, OIRA – with its transparent procedures and staff of career regulatory experts – complements and supports those advisors.

OIRA coordinates interagency disputes on regulation, liaises with White House officials to ensure regulations are consistent with presidential policies, and reviews regulations through an analytical economic lens to provide a “dispassionate and analytical second opinion” (Obama, Reference Obama2009) on agencies’ actions.

Not only does OIRA review help ensure agency actions are accountable to the elected president, but OIRA itself is accountability to Congress and the public as well. Because the OIRA administrator is a Senate-confirmed position, Congress can compel him or her to testify – something it cannot demand of White House staff. OIRA’s disclosure procedures also provide Congress and the public information on meetings with outside groups on regulations under development.

Equally important are the policies expressed in E.O. 12866, E.O. 13563, and E.O. 12291 before them, which have become well-established regulatory practice (see, for example, OECD, 2008). Although BCA is still not universally supported (Ackerman & Heinzerling, Reference Ackerman and Heinzerling2004), it is increasingly accepted across the ideological spectrum as a valuable tool for informing policymaking (Revesz & Livermore, Reference Revesz and Livermore2008; Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2017). While Congress has not adopted BCA and many statutes are silent on whether it governs regulatory decisions, the Supreme Court is increasingly interpreting silent statutes in favor of analysis (Graham & Noe, Reference Graham and Noe2016; Entergy Corp. v. Riverkeeper, Inc. 2009; Michigan v. EPA 2015).

Role for a regulatory budget

In a world with perfect information and incentives that align with public goals, BCA alone would lead agencies to issue regulations only when they can show they make the public better off. In this ideal world, a budget constraint, such as that imposed by Trump’s E.O. 13771, would be nonbinding or harmful because it would prohibit regulations that could have offered net societal benefits (Pierce, Reference Pierce2016).

In practice, of course, agencies’ analyses are based on neither complete information nor publicly-aligned incentives (Dudley & Mannix, Reference Dudley and Mannix2018). Regulators may seek to maximize their authority rather than social welfare or respond to the preferences of concentrated interests at the expense of the more diffuse public interest. In conducting analysis, they face incentives to show that the benefits of their desired actions outweigh the costs. As a counterweight to these political and institutional incentives that can lead to overregulation, Gayer et al. (Reference Gayer, Litan and Wallach2017) point out that a regulatory budget constraint may not be as anathema as it appears on the surface. When considered as a supplement to BCA requirements, it may motivate agencies to maximize benefits within a budget constraint (Dudley, Reference Dudley2016). Equally important, it may provide agencies with incentives to focus more attention on identifying existing regulations that may be underperforming.

Ever since Carter’s E.O. 12044, presidents have directed agencies to examine the benefits and costs of existing rules (Aldy, Reference Aldy2014). These directives have had limited success because agencies lacked incentives to follow through, and faced analytical difficulties in measuring ex-post impacts (Dudley & Mannix, Reference Dudley and Mannix2018). Trump’s requirement that agencies offset the costs of new regulations by reducing the costs of existing regulations (through modification or rescission) may provide needed incentives. If taken seriously, it could also spur the development of improved analytical tools for evaluating regulatory benefits and costs. Not only could this address the problem of regulatory accumulation, but also it could improve ex ante BCA by testing, and providing valuable feedback on, the assumptions used initially.

As President Carter’s Economic Report of the President concluded in 1980:

Priorities must be set to make certain that the first problems addressed are those in which regulations are likely to bring the greatest social benefits. Admittedly, this is an ideal that can never be perfectly realized, but tools like the regulatory budget may have to be developed if it is to be approached (Carter, Reference Carter1980, p. 26).

Conclusions

Since the emergence of the first social regulatory agencies in the 1970s, presidents have worked to supervise their regulatory policies and required them to show that new regulations will offer net public benefits. However, as Justice Elena Kagan observed, presidents confront a principle-agent problem; “In a world of extraordinary administrative complexity and near-incalculable presidential responsibilities, no President can hope (even with the assistance of close aides) to monitor the agencies so closely as to substitute all his preferences for those of the bureaucracy” (Kagan, Reference Kagan2001). Since 1981, presidents have relied on OIRA to monitor regulatory agency actions, coordinate information, perspectives, and policies across the executive branch, and provide a “dispassionate and analytical ‘second opinion’” on agencies’ analysis (Obama, Reference Obama2009).

The bipartisan support for OIRA across six very different presidents is remarkable. While executive orders can be rescinded with the stroke of a pen, E.O. 12866 remains in effect 26 years after it was issued. (See Forum Celebrating 25 Years of Executive Order 12866: https://regulatorystudies.columbian.gwu.edu/node/916.)

This longevity can be attributed to the principles and procedures that guide OIRA review. Like its CWPS predecessor in earlier administrations, OIRA review applies BCA to improve the economic efficiency of government policies. Most observers agree that its review has motivated agencies to consider the effects of regulations, perhaps leading to “smarter regulations” that yield more benefits than costs (Graham et al., Reference Graham, Branch and Noe2006; Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2011). Nevertheless, OIRA review and ex ante BCA have been inadequate for stemming the accumulation of regulation (DeMuth, Reference Demuth2011; Mandel & Carew, Reference Mandel and Carew2013).

Trump’s regulatory budget has introduced the biggest shift in regulatory oversight and analysis since OIRA was formed. Significantly, he has not abandoned his predecessors’ executive orders nor their BCA approach to regulation but rather has overlaid an incremental regulatory cost cap on top of it. Like previous attempts at constraining regulatory agencies, his has been controversial (Dudley, Reference Dudley2019). Yet, it may provide a useful counterweight to regulators’ institutional tendency toward overregulation (Gayer et al., Reference Gayer, Litan and Wallach2017) and could improve regulatory BCA in the long run.

Acknowledgments.

This article is based on a longer working paper available at www.RegulatoryStudies.gwu.edu. I am grateful for support from the C. Boyden Gray Center for the Study of the Administrative State and feedback on an early draft from participants in a workshop it hosted. I also appreciate constructive comments on the longer paper from my GW Regulatory Studies Center colleagues, Bridget Dooling, Jerry Ellig, Mark Febrizio, Brian Mannix, Daniel Pérez, and Zhoudan Xie. Any errors are my own.

References

References

Ackerman, Frank, and Heinzerling, Lisa. 2004. Priceless: On Knowing the Price of Everything and the Value of Nothing. New York, NY: New Press.Google Scholar
Aldy, Joseph Edgar. 2014. Learning from Experience: An Assessment of the Retrospective Reviews of Agency Rules and the Evidence for Improving the Design and Implementation of Regulatory Policy. Administrative Conference of the United States. Available at http://www.hks.harvard.edu/fs/jaldy/img/aldy_retrospective.pdf. (accessed September 26, 2019).Google Scholar
Bruff, Harold. 1989. “Presidential Management of Agency Rulemaking.” The George Washington Law Review, 57(3): 552562.Google Scholar
Demuth, Christopher. 2011. “OIRA at Thirty.” Administrative Law Review, 63(Jan): 1525.Google Scholar
Derthick, Martha, and Quirk, Paul J.. 1985. The Politics of Deregulation. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Dudley, Susan E. 2016. “Can Fiscal Budget Concepts Improve Regulation?New York University Journal of Legislation and Public Policy, 19(2): 259280.Google Scholar
Dudley, Susan. 2019. “A Brief History of Regulation and Deregulation.” The Regulatory Review. Available at https://www.theregreview.org/2019/03/11/dudley-brief-history-regulation-deregulation/. (accessed September 21, 2019).Google Scholar
Dudley, Susan E., and Mannix, Brian F.. 2018. “Improving Regulatory Benefit-Cost Analysis.” The Journal of Law & Politics, 34(1): 120.Google Scholar
Eads, George C., and Fix, Michael. 1982. “Regulatory Policy.” In The Reagan Experiment: An Examination of Economic and Social Policies Under the Reagan Administration, edited by Palmer, John L., and Sawhill, Isabel V.. Washington, DC : Urban Institute.Google Scholar
E.O. 11821. 1974. Executive Order 11821 of November 29, 1974, Inflation Impact Statements.Google Scholar
E.O. 11949. 1977. Executive Order 11949 of January 5, 1977, Economic Impact Statements.Google Scholar
E.O. 12044. 1978. Executive Order 12044 of March 23, 1978, Improving Government Regulation.Google Scholar
E.O. 12291. 1981. Executive Order 12291 of February 17, 1981, Federal Regulation.Google Scholar
E.O. 12866. 1993. “Executive Order 12866 of September 30, 1993, Regulatory Planning and Review”.Google Scholar
E.O. 13563. 2011. Executive Order 13563 of January 18, 2011, Improving Regulation an Regulatory Review.Google Scholar
E.O. 13579. 2011. Executive Order 13579 of July 11, 2011, Regulation and Independent Regulatory Agencies.Google Scholar
E.O. 13771. 2017. “Executive Order 13771 of January 30, 2017, Reducing Regulation and Controlling Regulatory Costs”.Google Scholar
Fix, Michael, and Eads, George C.. 1985. “The Prospects for Regulatory Reform: The Legacy of Reagan’s First Term.” Yale Journal on Regulation, 2(2): 293318.Google Scholar
Gayer, Ted, Litan, Robert, and Wallach, Phillip. 2017. “Evaluating the Trump Administration’s Regulatory Reform Program.” Series on Regulatory Process and Perspective. Brookings Center on Regulation and Markets. Available at https://www.brookings.edu/research/evaluating-the-trump-administrations-regulatory-reform-program/. (accessed September 26, 2019).Google Scholar
Graham, John D., and Noe, Paul R.. 2016. “A Paradigm Shift in the Cost-Benefit State.” The Regulatory Review. Available at https://www.theregreview.org/2016/04/26/graham-noe-shift-in-the-cost-benefit-state/ (accessed September 26, 2019).Google Scholar
Graham, John D., Branch, Elizabeth L., and Noe, Paul R.. 2006. “Managing the Regulatory State: The Experience of the Bush Administration.” Fordham Urban Law Journal, 33(4): 9531002.Google Scholar
Gray, C. Boyden. 1993. “Lessons. (Bush Administration Regulatory Activities) (Reflections on the Bush Regulatory Record).” Regulation, 16(3): 4.Google Scholar
Hopkins, Thomas D. 2011. “The Evolution of Regulatory Oversight-CWPS to OIRA.” Administrative Law Review, 63: 7177.Google Scholar
Kagan, Elena. 2001. “Presidential Administration.” Harvard Law Review, 114: 8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katzen, Sally. 2018a. “Benefit-Cost Analysis Should Promote Rational Decision Making.” The Regulatory Review. Available at https://www.theregreview.org/2018/04/24/katzen-benefit-cost-analysis-promote-decisionmaking/. (accessed September 21, 2019).Google Scholar
Katzen, Sally. 2018b. “Tracing Executive Order 12866’s Longevity to Its Roots.” Regulatory Studies Center. Available at https://regulatorystudies.columbian.gwu.edu/tracing-executive-order-12866’s-longevity-its-roots-katzen. (accessed September 21, 2019).Google Scholar
Mandel, Michael, and Carew, Diana. 2013. Regulatory Improvement Commission: A Politically-Viable Approach to U.S. Regulatory Reform. Progressive Policy Institute.Google Scholar
OECD . 2008. Introductory Handbook for Undertaking Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA). Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.Google Scholar
Obama, Barack H. 2009. Regulatory Review [Memorandum]. Available at https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/sites/default/files/omb/assets/information_and_regulatory_affairs/regulatory_review_012009.pdf. (accessed September 26, 2019).Google Scholar
OMB. 2002. Guidelines for Ensuring and Maximizing the Quality, Objectivity, Utility, and Integrity of Information Disseminated by Federal Agencies [Memorandum], 67 Fed. Reg. 8452 (February 22, 2002). Available at https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/files/omb/assets/OMB/fedreg/reproducible2.pdf. (accessed September 26, 2019).Google Scholar
OMB. 2003. Regulatory Analysis. OMB Circular A-4 [Memorandum] (September 17, 2003).Google Scholar
OMB. 2004. M-05-03, Issuance of OMB’s “Final Information Quality Bulletin for Peer Review [Memorandum]. Available at https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/files/omb/memoranda/2005/m05-03.pdf. (accessed September 26, 2019).Google Scholar
OMB. 2007a. Final Bulletin for Agency Good Guidance Practices [Memorandum]. 72 Fed. Reg. 3432, 3440 (January 25, 2007).Google Scholar
OMB. 2007b. M-07-24, Updated Principles for Risk Analysis [Memorandum]. Available at https://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/whitehouse.gov/files/omb/memoranda/2007/m07-24.pdf. (accessed September 26, 2019).Google Scholar
Pierce, Richard J.. 2016. “The Regulatory Budget Debate.” New York University Journal of Legislation and Public Policy, 19(2): 249258.Google Scholar
Revesz, Richard L., and Livermore, Michael A.. 2008. Retaking Rationality: How Cost-Benefit Analysis Can Better Protect the Environment and Our Health Oxford. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schultz, George. 1971. Agency regulations, standards, and guidelines pertaining to environmental quality, consumer protection, and occupational and public health and safety [Memorandum]. (October 5, 1971).Google Scholar
Shepherd, George. 1996Fierce Compromise: The Administrative Procedure Act Emerges From New Deal Politics.” Northwestern University Law Review, 90(4): 27.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1971. “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1): 321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2011. “Smarter Regulation: Remarks from Cass Sunstein, Administrator, Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs.” Administrative Law Review, 63(Jan: 713).Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2017. “Cost-Benefit Analysis and Arbitrariness Review.” Harvard Environmental Law Review, 41(1): 141.Google Scholar
Tozzi, Jim. 2011. “OIRA’S Formative Years: The Historical Record of Centralized Regulatory Review Preceding OIRA’S Founding.” Administrative Law Review, 63: 3769.Google Scholar
Weidenbaum, Murray. 1997. “Regulatory Process Reform: From Ford to Clinton.” Regulation, 11(Jan): 2026.Google Scholar
Weidenbaum, Murray. 2004. Business and Government in the Global Marketplace, 7th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson/Prentice Hall.Google Scholar

Cases Cited

Humphrey’s Executor v. United States, 295 U.S. 602, 625 (1935).Google Scholar
Entergy Corp. v. Riverkeeper, Inc., 556 U.S. 208 (2009).Google Scholar
Michigan v. Envtl. Prot. Agency, 576 U.S. ___ (2015).Google Scholar
Sierra Club v. Costle. 657 F.2d 298 15 ERC 2137, 211 U.S.App.D.C. 336, 11; Envtl. L. Rep. 20,455 1981.Google Scholar

Laws Cited

Council on Wage and Price Stability Act of 1974, Pub. L. No. 93-387. (1974).Google Scholar
Council on Wage and Price Stability Act Amendments of 1975, Pub. L. No. 94-78 (1975).Google Scholar
Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980 Pub. L. No. 96-354 (1980).Google Scholar
Paperwork Reduction Act of 1980 Pub. L. No. 96-511, 94 (1980).Google Scholar
Paperwork Reduction Act of 1980, 44 U.S.C. §§ 3501-3520 (1982).Google Scholar