INTRODUCTION: OF CULTURE AND COPYRIGHTS
As the digital revolution sweeps the globe, the world's cultural property is rapidly being translated into ones and zeros. Simultaneously, the technologies of the Internet, advanced electronics, telephony, and personal computers are constantly converging—often in completely unexpected ways. Technological growth is first spawned, it seems, through the venue of entertainment (where commercially profitable applications have been most readily discovered). Historically, the initial form of entertainment to be widely digitized was music—through the delivery technology of the compact disk. As both a form of cultural property and a form of entertainment, music has played a central role in the ongoing debate over digital rights in the new era of digital networked environments.1
Most legal scholarship has surrounded audio-visual media, thus including other forms of entertainment goods. See, for example, Graber, Audiovisual Media, 15–76. This analysis describes the concept of cultural diversity, observes the genesis of the commoditization of music, presents the current regulatory regime, and critiques its efficacy as a policy approach in which all the important interests are balanced.
These are currently AOL/Time Warner, Vivendi-Universal, Sony, BMG, EMI, Disney, News Corporation, and Viacom. These corporations own or are linked with distribution outlets through joint ventures, cross-ownership, coproductions, or presales contracts. Economically speaking, then, cultural production and distribution are mostly vertically integrated.
When the eggs of twins fuse in the mother's womb, that fusion produces a chimera. A chimera is a single creature with two sets of DNA. Likewise, the copyright chimera is a single issue with two differing facets. For a unique analysis of the copyright debate, see Lessig, Free Culture, 179.
Note that alternatives, such as “some rights reserved” systems look increasingly well envisioned and pragmatic. See Cultural Commons at: www.culturalcommons.org (accessed January 15, 2006).
THE CONCEPT OF CULTURAL DIVERSITY
Culture
The cultural diversity mise-en-scène is surrounded by considerable confusion. A definition of culture is difficult to ascertain.5
Joost Smiers elegantly demonstrates this in his discussion within Smiers, Arts Under Pressure, 1–12.
See Bernier et al., A UNESCO Convention, 69.
MONDIACULT World Conference, Mexico City, 1982.
Cultural Diversity
Cultural diversity proves to be an even more elusive concept, because every culture and interest group has its own unique definition. Constructive ambiguity in this area is at its apex. We must briefly delve into the definitional depths to structure meaning around the concept.
France, original proponent of the exception culturelle (cultural exception) to the traditional rules of free trade, interprets diversity as differences between national cultures (especially with regard to languages). The polar opposite view is espoused by the United States, in which diversity refers to the free flow of ideas and expressions—a distinctly nation-neutral (and audiovisual sector liberalizing) approach. Both approaches have intrinsic problems.9
The former approach ignores intra-national cultures. The latter approach ignores variations within a given set of cultures in favor of emphasizing the individual right of representation. Albro, “Diversity's Fate in Cultural Policymaking,” 26.
UNESCO (United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization) has struggled to reach consensus among its members on this issue and defines cultural diversity as “the manifold ways in which the cultures of groups and societies find expression.”10
Art. 4, No. 2, UNESCO Convention on Cultural Diversity.
Albro, “Diversity's Fate in Cultural Policymaking,” 26.
Van den Bossche, The Law and Policy, 3–11.
I note here that Orwell's dystopia, 1984, never considered that a world defined by technology is, itself, inherently interactive. Regulatory instruments can have direct control over the impact and boundaries of technological progress.
This alludes to the title of Friedman's book on globalization, The World is Flat.
Friedman, The World is Flat, 5, 10.
This has been illustrated particularly well in Bauer, “Definitional Anxiety,” 27.
Albro, R., “Diversity's Fate in Cultural Policymaking,” 26.
In this article, I approach the concept of cultural diversity within the context of the regulatory framework for musical goods and services. Thus, I acknowledge the dynamic nature of culture and focus on the current international regulatory environment and on an essential vector of cultural identity: cultural commodities. Note that law itself is not static. It is as dynamic as the cultures in which it functions. A dynamic institutional approach to international law is clearly a preferable modus in the trade and culture constellation.18
Frischmann, B. “A Dynamic Institutional Theory,” 808, in which game theory is applied to a systematic approach to international law.
Bernier, “A UNESCO Convention,” 66.
UNESCO, Culture, Trade and Globalization, 40.
For example, see Brown, “Heritage Trouble,” 45.
For example, see Footer and Graber, “Trade Liberalization,” 15.
The link between culture and human rights establishes the international legal pretext on which the concept of cultural diversity is based. The United Nations Universal Declaration on Human Rights (Universal Declaration)23
Adopted by UN General Assembly Resolution 217A (III), December 10, 1948.
Article 27, Universal Declaration on Human Rights. This provision can be viewed online at http://www.un.org/Overview/rights.html (accessed January 15, 2006).
The covenant further stipulates: The steps to be taken by the states parties to the present covenant to achieve the full realization of this right shall include those necessary for the conservation, development, and diffusion of science and culture. The states parties to the present covenant undertake to respect the freedom indispensable for scientific research and creative activity. The states parties to the present covenant recognize the benefits to be derived from the encouragement and development of international contacts and cooperation in the scientific and cultural fields. The rights to enjoy culture, to participate in cultural life, and to benefit from technological and scientific progress form the foundation of article 15. Article 15, The International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights in Craven, International Covenant, 364.
Although these issues may not seem to be matters of human rights, they are of fundamental importance to the principles of equality of treatment, freedom of expression, the right to receive and impart information, and the right to the full development of the human personality…. The right to benefit from scientific progress and its applications is designed to ensure that everyone in society can enjoy advances in this regard, in particular disadvantaged groups. It includes the right of everyone to seek and receive information about such advances resulting from new scientific insights and to have access to any developments, which could enhance their enjoyment of the rights contained in the Covenant.26
Fact Sheet No. 16 (Rev.1). The Committee on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights. This document is available online at http://www.unhchr.ch/html/menu6/2/fs16.htm (accessed January 15, 2006).
An analytical reading of Article 27, however, reveals that, although some would claim that both copyright and cultural diversity are human rights, the Universal Declaration never mentions the word copyright. We must observe that the Universal Declaration is not a treaty of public international law, but the CESCR includes the text of Article 27 verbatim in its own Article 15(1)(c). The CESCR is a binding international legal instrument.27
However, the issue of whether direct affect is afforded to all articles is tenuous. See Cottier and Schefer, “The Relationship Between World Trade,” 25.
Craven, International Covenant, 364.
Graber, “Copyright and Access,” 76.
Contrast this with the copyright system, whose primary function has been to provide incentives for publication rather than creation. See Ku, “The Creative Destruction of Copyright,” 311–22. In practice, a record label offers performers publicity, but only in exceptional cases does it pay them money. Copyright is irrelevant to musicians because they derive the bulk of their incomes from live performances and merchandising.
Culture can imply two disparate conceptions. The first conception is centered in art and literature. The second conception is centered in lifestyles, basic human rights, value systems, traditions, and beliefs.31
Bernier, “A UNESCO Convention,” 66.
Joseph, Schultz, and Castan, The International Covenant on Civil, 386.
Additional Definitional Concerns
The definition of cultural products has also been subject to considerable debate (especially as the digital environment blurs definitional boundaries) largely because specific linguistic subtleties can drastically alter legal meaning. Industry leaders interpret their goods and services as mere entertainment. This language enables cultural goods and services to be subject to the international trade liberalization rules of the World Trade Organization (WTO). Others have interpreted cultural goods and services as societal achievements. This language would justify special treatment for cultural goods and services.33
UNESCO acknowledges that cultural goods and services are different from other goods and services, and “deserve different and/or exceptional treatment” and that this “requires a differential treatment in international trade agreements and possibly effective regulatory frameworks to redefine cultural policies.” See UNESCO, Culture, Trade and Globalization, 40.
Recently, much has been written about the shift of jargon used within UNESCO and in the greater policy debate—the expansion of the term cultural property to cultural heritage. This shift is a testament to the progress made within the policy spectrum in terms of acknowledging that cultural policies must not only focus on tangible property but also represent the cultural expressions and interests of those intangible traditions such as music, folklore, knowledge, and dances.34
In this study, keep in mind that although the recognition of the value of both tangible and intangible cultural content has successfully commenced, a regulatory framework for its protection has been, thus far, unsuccessful.35We should recognize that the defining, delimiting, and commoditizing of culture (to regulate it) actually destroys its dynamism and evolution. This conundrum is effectively explored in Brown, “Heritage Trouble,” 45.
The various initiatives to support cultural diversity have, at present, all been soft law—nonbinding and programmatic statements that subordinate themselves to the WTO agreements and other binding (dispute settlement/sanction based) international commitments. The past and current absence of a normative interface between trade and culture36
See Germann, “Content Industries and Cultural Diversity.”
However, outside of the covered agreements of the WTO, freedom of expression is protected by The International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights. Article 19 of the covenant affords the right to hold opinions without interference and to express them. Joseph, Schultz, and Castan, The International Covenant on Civil, 386. Also of note is the new UNESCO Convention on Cultural Diversity. The core issue we grapple with is whether copyright rules themselves serve to discourage diversity of expression and representation in the musical arts.
The Ideological Debate: Cultural Diversity versus Copyright
A wave of scholarly sentiment observes that the combination of the international legal framework and the market power of a limited number of leaders in the content industries create a cultural vacuum in which the dispersion of diverse cultural content is endangered. Homogeneity within the cultural messages of the industry not only threatens the quality of content (by solely representing the common denominator), but also causes market censorship through the prolific use of comprehensive marketing strategies (that serve to marginalize and even supplant competitive alternatives).38
Smiers, Arts Under Pressure, 68.
Germann, “Diversité Culturelle,” 99.
Smiers, Arts Under Pressure, 61.
See Macmillan, “Copyright and Freedom of Movement,” 12.
Macmillan, “Copyright and Freedom of Movement,” 12. The debate whether copyright inhibits access is discussed in depth in Graber, “Copyright and Access,” 76.
Other voices penetrate this debate, however, with claims that the current copyright system is essential to the promotion of cultural diversity. Bonnie Richardson, the vice president for Trade and Federal Affairs with the Motion Picture Association of America (MPAA), makes several compelling claims. First, she refutes the claim that American hegemony and cultural diversity are dichotomies.43
Richardson, “Hollywood's Vision,” 111.
Keith Maskus has claimed that strengthened intellectual property regulations IPRs encourage creativity and, as a byproduct, increase economic and cultural welfare. See Maskus, Intellectual Property, 55.
Maskus, Intellectual Property, 113.
The diverse opinions on which path is correct are essentially ideological (and pecuniary interest driven), because the arts “mould our mental framework, our emotional texture, our language, our tonal and visual landscape, our understanding of past and present, our feelings about other people, our sensibility.”46
Smiers, Arts Under Pressure, 11.
Cited in Barber, Jihad vs. McWorld, 82.
The Ideological Underpinnings of Copyright
Although there is the ideological debate surrounding the nature of copyrightable content, there is also an international ideological debate surrounding the instrument of copyright itself. There are two ideological foundations of copyright rules; one has been traditionally embraced by the United States, and the other largely by continental Europe. The conceptual differences are subtle but have resulted in considerable differences in application. The debate “has centred on whether copyright is a natural right of property in authors, or whether copyright is a statutory monopoly designed to balance the competing interests of authors and end users with the ultimate objective of advancing the public good.”48
Lucas, Propriété Littéraire et Artistique, 14.
Graber, “Copyright and Access,” 77.
The common law concept defines copyright narrowly, but includes exceptions and limitations through its fair use doctrine. In the civil law system, the definition of droit d'auteur is broad, and limited exceptions are provided to those rights. These approaches have largely converged through countries' membership in the WTO. See Vaver, D. “Internationalizing Copyright Law.”
THE CURRENT SYSTEM OF REGULATING MUSICAL CULTURAL CONTENT
The Evolving Concept of Musical Property: “In the
Beginning Was the Word”51 John
1:1, the Holy Bible.
(not the Music)
John 1:1, the Holy Bible.
Cultural content of the musical form has existed before recorded history. The concept, however, that such content is property in a proprietary sense, is relatively modern. Current copyright law protects a composer's proprietary claims over a wide variety of uses of music, including: written representations in notation form, as part of a dramatic or audiovisual work, and when embodied in a recording.52
See 17 U.S.C. §106, from which these rules originate.
In ancient Greece and Rome, the concept of proprietary claims to music did not yet exist. Although little notated Greek music has survived (caused by the papyrus medium),53
Mathiesen, Apollo's Lyre, 12.
Mathiesen, Apollo's Lyre, 13.
The word music derives from the Greek word mousike, which referred to art inspired by muses. See Webster's Third New International Dictionary, 1490.
Lippman, A History of Western Musical Aesthetics, 8. See also Olcott, “Ancient and Modern Notions,” 2.
Plato felt that simplicity was the goal in ideal musical practice. Thus, complex meters, scales, instrumentation, and any types of music that did not engender proper feelings in Athenian citizens were to be avoided. To Plato, music shaped society, its attitudes, and its conduct. Jowett (Trans.), The Republic of Plato, 86.
Grant, The Classical Greeks, 91.
The rationale for this was partly caused by social norms of the day, in which music performance was not appropriate outside the home; it was a profession largely performed by slaves and women. This is evident in that although famous playwrights such as Sophocles and Aristophanes composed music to accompany their works, none of that material was preserved. Note also that it was great scandal that Emperor Nero played the violin—a task not deemed proper for free men. Grant, The Classical Greeks, 91.
Grout and Palisca, A History of Western Music, 14–15.
VerSteeg, “The Roman Law Roots,” 11.
In medieval Europe62
I am referring here to the period of time between the collapse of the Roman Empire and the fifteenth century.
Hughes and Abraham (eds.), The New Oxford History of Music, 107.
This style began solely as monophony but developed slowly into polyphony (first known as organum) as time progressed. Hughes and Abraham (eds.), The New Oxford History of Music, 107.
An example of such regulation included the forbiddance of dissonance in harmonic composition. Note also that such regulation is similar to Plato's ideologies.
Johann Sebastian Bach was a notable leader of one such guild in Germany. The author comically cogitates that Bach's particular guild was well tempered.
An example of the regulations guilds imposed is that only guild members could publicly perform music within the city of the particular guild. Thus, guilds operated similarly to how labor unions operate today. Lowinsky, “Music in the Culture,” 510–11.
Lowinsky, “Music in the Culture,” 510–11.
The process of attaining membership included the requirement of a lengthy apprenticeship. Lowinsky, “Music in the Culture,” 510–11.
For example, the two most famous composers in Medieval Europe, Leonin and Perotin, never signed their works.
During the Renaissance, the philosophy of humanism,71
These new ideas about humanity were espoused by philosophers such as Desiderius Erasmus, Francesco Petrarcha, Niccolo Machiavelli, Rudolphus Agricola, Sir Thomas Moore, and Francis Bacon.
Patterson, Copyright in Historical Perspective, 79.
It was unprecedented for a composer to receive such rights, and Orlando Lassus has been credited with being the “precursor to copyright.” See Carroll, “Whose Music is it Anyway,” 389, who first discovered this fact.
Carroll, “Whose Music is it Anyway,” 389.
Carroll, “Whose Music is it Anyway,” 389.
Thus, in ancient Greece and Rome, music was viewed as separate from words, and treated very differently. Music was given no property rights, and composers were not acknowledged as the source of inspiration. In the Middle Ages, notation was redeveloped; musical composition was considered a viable activity; and music guilds were formed to give exclusive performance rights legal force. The Renaissance brought the innovation of efficient publishing to musical composition. This caused the evolution of the concept of property rights to include published music. The rights granted to publishers helped them compete against other publishers and other geographical market entrants. The common logical theme that runs through the history is that material conditions determining the commoditization of music directly impacted the concept of private property in each era. The legal concept of property was malleable to changes in the material conditions existing at the particular time. This brief historical journey has hardly been without purpose. We should observe a pattern: conceptual changes in the law brought about by the conversion of technological and philosophical stimuli. In the current battle over the future of music in the digital networked environment, it is wise to refer to the battles of the past76
These range from the music industry's fight against player pianos (1908) to the fight against audiocassette tapes (1963).
See Carroll, “Whose Music is it Anyway,” 390.
A Brief Legislative Review of Copyright
The first official copyright legislation began in England, in 1709, with the passing of the Statute of Anne. At that time copyright had nothing to do with music. A product of lobbying by book publishers,78
Namely, the “Conger,” a group of English book publishers.
The rule prevented others from reprinting a book. In 1710, the copy-right was a right to use a particular machine to replicate a particular work. Unlike current copyright regimes, it did not control use at all.
Fourteen years with one optional renewal.
Note that the statute only protected books, maps, and charts and bore little resemblance to the broad copyright regimes of today in both length and scope.
Although, in Great Britain between 1735 and 1737 there were great petitions for extending the term of the rights afforded by the Statute of Anne. The extensions were not granted by Parliament.
Jefferson, “Letter,” 600–01.
17 U.S.C. 102, 2004.
U.S. Copyright Office, “Copyright Basics.”
17 U.S.C. 107-120. However, it has been observed that fair use in America means the right to hire a lawyer. This point is pioneered in Lessig, Free Culture.
Content producers have fettled as the problem of piracy has, once again, been magnified by technological progress.87
As Thomas Cottier has written, “New technologies always have tended to stir social unrest.” Cottier, “The New Global Technology Regime,” 1.
This is elucidated in Graber et al. (eds.), Digital Rights Management.
The Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA) was signed into law by President Clinton on October 28, 1998. Pub. L. No. 105–304, 112 Stat. 2860.
The WIPO Internet Treaties were signed into force by more than 60 countries at the Diplomatic Conference in Geneva, December 1996.
Dodes, “Beyond Napster,” 10.
Berne Convention for the Protection of Literary and Artistic Works, revised at Paris on July 24, 1971.
It has been noted that this shift away from WIPO as the primary negotiating forum has made it less likely that developing countries will make concessions in the field of intellectual property law without first obtaining corresponding gains in market access for their more traditional exports. See Cottier, “The Prospects for Intellectual Property,” 414.
Annex 1C of the Marrakesh Agreement, establishing the World Trade Organization, signed in Marrakesh, Morocco, on April 15, 1994.
With the notable exception of the provisions of the Berne Convention on moral rights (Article 6bis).
The most important copyright-related case brought before the WTO dispute settlement system to date has been United States—Section 110(5) of the United States Copyright Act, in which the so-called business and home-style exemptions were deemed inconsistent with TRIPS Article 13. Other cases have included Japan—Measures Concerning Sound Recordings (WT/DS/28/1) and (WT/DS/42/1), EC—Enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights for Motion Pictures and Television Programs (WT/DS124/1), and EC—Measures Affecting the Grant of Copyright and Neighboring Rights (WT/DS115/1). These are listed and explained in greater depth in Footer and Graber, “Trade Liberalization,” 18.
Other agreements within the WTO legal framework, such as GATS and TRIMS, also contain provisions that influence (or have the potential to influence) the cultural industries.
Note that Bonnie Richardson of the MPAA claims that comprehensive copyright infringement protection is a requirement of promoting cultural diversity. See Richardson, “Hollywood's Vision,” 12.
A Critical Analysis of Applicable Trade Agreements
TRIPS was enacted as a flexible means by which each member's intellectual property rules could be enforced.101
Goldstein, International Copyright, 47.
1. In respect of a fixation of their performance on a phonogram, performers shall have the possibility of preventing the following acts when undertaken without their authorization: the fixation of their unfixed performance and the reproduction of such fixation. Performers shall also have the possibility of preventing the following acts when undertaken without their authorization: the broadcasting by wireless means and the communication to the public of their live performance.
2. Producers of phonograms shall enjoy the right to authorize or prohibit the direct or indirect reproduction of their phonograms.102
Article 14, TRIPS (emphasis added).
Thus, it is noteworthy in this study that free online music sharing is generally prohibited under the TRIPS agreement.
The two problems with TRIPS as an effective means of international copyright regulation relate mostly to its theory of national sovereignty and its enforcement mechanism (however, other weaknesses have certainly been observed).
Article 1 of the TRIPS Agreement sets out the “Nature and Scope of Obligations” under the Agreement as follows:
1. Members shall give effect to the provisions of this Agreement. Members may, but shall not be obliged to, implement in their domestic law more extensive protection than is required by this Agreement, provided that such protection does not contravene the provisions of this Agreement. Members shall be free to determine the appropriate method of implementing the provisions of this Agreement within their own legal system and practice.
3. Members shall accord the treatment provided for in this Agreement to the nationals of other Members.103
Art. 1, TRIPS. See also Art. 1, note 1, TRIPS (emphasis added).
Article 3 of the TRIPS Agreement specifies how member nations must treat other member nations who allegedly violate the hosting country's specific copyright laws:104
Note, however, that some limited exceptions may apply under Article 3, such as those exceptions that were already laid down in the Berne Convention, certain retaliatory measures available under Article 6, et al.
1. Each Member shall accord to the nationals of other Members treatment no less favorable than that it accords to its own nationals with regard to the protection of intellectual property…. In respect of performers, producers of phonograms and broadcasting organizations, this obligation only applies in respect of the rights provided under this Agreement… .105
Art. 3, TRIPS.
Article 4 of TRIPS specifies that any “advantage, favor, privilege or immunity granted by a Member to the nationals of any other country shall be accorded immediately and unconditionally to the nationals of all other Members.”106
Art. 4, TRIPS.
Drexl, Entwicklungsmöglichkeiten des Urheberrechts, 10–11.
Scully, Beyond Napster, 321.
TRIPS also propounds the territoriality principle.109
The territoriality principle responds to two needs. The first is the need for national sovereignty. Most countries are more willing to agree to the terms of treaties when they are able to retain control over the violations that occur within their borders. The second principle is the promotion of international commerce through certainty in investment-backed expectations. Countries will be less likely to engage in international business if they are subject to stricter copyright laws than they would be in their own or another more lax country's jurisdiction. Goldstein, International Copyright: Principles, Law, and Practice, 63.
Goldstein, International Copyright: Principles, Law, and Practice, 64. Note that Goldstein labels TRIPS a backward looking agreement.
D'Amoto and Long (eds.), International Intellectual Property Law, 231.
For example, see Eugui, “Issues on the Relationship.”
Dreier, TRIPS and the Enforcement, 249.
Part III of TRIPS governs the enforcement of substantive rights. The framers of the Agreement tried to balance the need for unrestricted trade in goods and services with effective means for protecting against intellectual property violations.115
Dreier, TRIPS and the Enforcement, 255-257.
Article 41, TRIPS.
It is understood that this Part does not create any obligation to put in place a judicial system for the enforcement of intellectual property rights distinct from that for the enforcement of laws in general, nor does it affect the capacity of Members to enforce their laws in general. Nothing in this Part creates any obligation with respect to the distribution of resources as between enforcement of intellectual property rights and the enforcement of the law in general.117
Article 41, TRIPS (emphasis added).
In the copyright context, if countries are not actively policing the copyright infringement occurring within their boundaries, the basic legal provisions will have no force.118
Some countries have no copyright protections (like many countries in the Middle East), and others only have minimal protections (like Malaysia and Indonesia).
RIAA, “RIAA Praises Administration for its Stand.”
Middle East Institute, “Can Trade Be a Lever for Reforms?”
The Trade Act of 1974 mandates that the Office of the U.S. Trade Representative identify annually those countries that either deny adequate and effective protection for IPR, or deny fair and equitable market access for persons that rely on intellectual property protection. Section 182 is commonly referred to as the “Special 301” provision of the Trade Act. The system places countries into a hierarchy of categories, with the ranking of Priority Foreign Country reserved for the worst situations: (1) Priority Foreign Country, (2) Priority Watch List, or (3) Watch List. Placement of a trading partner on the Priority Watch List or Watch List indicates that particular problems exist in that country with respect to IPR protection, enforcement, or market access for persons relying on intellectual property. 19 U.S.C. 2411(a)(1), 2000.
Office of the United States Trade Representative (USTR). 2005 Special 301 Report. http://www.ustr.gov/assets/Document_Library/Reports_Publications/2005/2005_Special_301/asset_upload_file195_7636.pdf (accessed 15 January 15, 2006).
Harvard Asia Quarterly, “Intellectual Property in China.”
Under the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), the WTO instrument that governs trade in cultural services, prolonged debate, and negotiations have yielded inconsequential results. On one hand, the United States (supported by media interests who dominate the United States' international exports) has pushed for free-trade principles to apply to cultural goods and services. This stance is consistent with both WTO goals of trade liberalization and freedom of expression goals. On the other hand, a majority of members have not wanted to take on legally binding GATS obligations because that would undermine their domestic cultural policies. Thus, most members have viewed cultural goods and services as special types of commodities, because “cultural patrimony can be seen as a crucial component of the identity and self-understanding of a nation.”124
Sauvé and Steinfatt, “Towards Multilateral Rules,” 16–20.
Imbalances in the global economy, certain weaknesses in the TRIPS Agreement,125
The critique, while accurate, is not entirely fair because the TRIPS Agreement remains incomplete as an instrument of international trade regulation. The need for further negotiations and the globalization of markets has made substantial updating a necessity. See Gervais, The TRIPS Agreement, 370.
Certainly, then, the intellectual property regime is not quite the heroic halcyon portrayed by the RIAA and MPAA, and the like.
Drahos and Braithwaite, Information Feudalism, 17.
Review of the Important Judicial Decisions in the United States
Lawsuits have also defined the legal copyright constellation. The most important ones, in the context of the music industry caused by the increased uncertainty of the digital environment, have come from the United States.128
The topics considered by these cases touch many areas of the law and include constitutional law, fair use, DCMA enforcement, and electronic publishing rights
Constitutional law questions were raised in Eldred v. Ashcroft.129
537 U.S. 186 (2003).
U.S. Const. art. I, §8 (8).
There have been two seminal fair-use cases. The first (and most heavily cited) case was Sony Corp. v. Universal City Studios (Betamax).131
464 U.S. 417 (1984).
Sony Corp. v. Universal City Studios, 420.
Because this decision was reached, the Digital Millennium Copyright Act has come into effect. It further limits the application of the fair use doctrine in situations where copyright holders use technology (DRM systems) to protect their content.
180 F.3d 1072 (9th Cir. 1999).
RIAA v. Diamond Multimedia Systems, 180 F.3d 1072 (9th Cir. 1999).
Distributors of peer-to-peer (P2P) file sharing software have been subject to the sternest scrutiny by U.S. courts. In A & M v. Napster, it was held that contributory and vicarious copyright infringement was present in file sharing software where the company operated a centralized database, had knowledge of infringing activity, and provided a current site and central index of files in the system.136
239 F.3d.at 1017 (9th Cir. 2001).
380 F.3d 1154 (2005), vacated and remanded from 259 F.Supp.2d 1029 (C.D. Cal. 2003), aff'd, 380 F.3d 1154 (9th Cir. 2004).
MGM v. Grokster, 545 U.S. ___ (2005).
GartnerG2, “Copyright and Digital Media,” 24.
The DMCA has birthed its own series of important cases; deriving mainly from its controversial anti-circumvention provisions. In Universal Studies v. Reimerdes, the issue was whether the DMCA's anticircumvention provisions are constitutional.140
273 F.3d 429 (2nd Cir. 2001).
Universal Studies v. Reimerdes, 273 F.3d 429 (2nd Cir. 2001).
2000 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 1889 (2000).
See U.S. v. ElcomSoft, Felten v. RIAA, Chamberlain v. Skylink, Blizzard v. BNETD, Lexmark v. Static Control, RIAA v. Verizon, Sony Music Entertainment v. Does 1-40, Elektra Entertainment Group Inc. v. Does 1-6, and CoStar Group, Inc. V. LoopNet for the most recent interpretive evolutions in the area of DMCA circumvention.
With regard to electronic publishing rights, there have been two important cases. New York Times v. Tasini dealt with whether periodical publishers have the right to license and republish articles in electronic databases.144
533 U.S. 483 (2001).
Thus, if the contract does not specifically enumerate a right to publish in the format, the publisher does not have that right.
283 F.3d 490 (2nd Cir. 2002).
These cases illustrate the current legal landscape surrounding the digital copyright system.147
It is important to note that this survey has excluded the thousands of copyright infringement lawsuits that have been brought before private citizens by the music industry. Among these lawsuits, the RIAA has sued a 12-year-old-girl from New York and a deceased grandmother from West Virginia. These suits certainly bring into question the logic and methodology of copyright enforcement, as well as the viability of current digital music business models.
In the context of how this imbalance affects content, it is ironic to note that even Rupert Murdoch, head of the large cultural conglomerate News Corp., believes that maintaining cultural diversity is important—albeit for a profit-driven rationale. See Shawcross, Murdoch, 426.
A Chimerical Debate
At the philosophical heart of the notion that cultural diversity is to be embraced worldwide is the view that cultural goods are not mere consumer goods; they express a vision of the world and the most complete identity of individuals and peoples.149
Germann, “Diversité Culturelle,” 99.
TMC = SPA = TMC (Trade Mark and Copyright = Stars, Print & Advertisement = Total Mono Culture) as formulated in the article, Germann, “Diversité Culturelle,” 99.
Richardson, “Hollywood's Vision,” 111.
MPAA, Speech by Jack Valenti.
Lawrence Lessig notes in Free Culture that the maximum fine for such an offence (as a first offender), under U.S. law, is $1,000 and the potential liability for the illegal download of a 10-song CD is $1,500,000 (this is true in the state of California). Lessig, Free Culture, Chapter 11.
This label is attributed to Lessig, in Free Culture.
IMPLICATIONS OF CURRENT SYSTEM: A CASE STUDY
To analyze whether the current copyright system serves to support or stifle innovation and the diversity of cultural offerings, we turn to several “real-life” situations within the current system to ascertain how the system operates in practice.
Example #1. Darkness Amidst Satellite Radio
Satellite radio is the most recent innovation to shake the music world. Consumers have benefited from CD-quality digital broadcasts as well as largely commercial-free programming (because it is a subscription service). Subscribers have frequently time-shifted their programming so that they could make use of the service that they have paid for at times that were convenient. The RIAA has recently objected.155
Yahoo! News. “Record Labels, Satellite Radio.”
Yahoo! News. “Record Labels, Satellite Radio.”
Yahoo! News. “Record Labels, Satellite Radio.”
Example #2. The Copyright Fire Spreads to Campgrounds
Permission is increasingly required for the most mundane and innocent of endeavors. Campers have, for generations, been able to tell stories and sing tunes like “Row, Row, Row Your Boat” around a campfire without asking for permission. American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers (ASCAP), the performance rights body that licenses copyrighted works for nondramatic public performances believes it is entitled to determine the terms for such performances. ASCAP reasoned that because hotels, restaurants, and resorts must pay for the right to perform recorded music, summer camps should be required to pay for licenses, too.158
Bollier, Brand Name Bullies, Part 1.1.
Bollier, Brand Name Bullies, Part 1.1.
Bollier, Brand Name Bullies, Part 1.1. After the general public became aware that the Girl Scouts were now being asked to pay fees associated with singing songs, ASCAP waffled and removed the obligation.
Example #3. The Rebirth of the Library of Alexandria?
California Internet search engine firm Google, Inc., embarked on an ambitious project to scan and catalog books from the Harvard, Stanford, and University of Michigan libraries for the goal of easier public diffusion of knowledge.161
Wyatt, E. “Google Alters Plans for Copyrighted Books.” New York Times, August 12, 2005.
Note that the historical Library of Alexandria itself was more restrictive than the Google initiative. For example, the library charged a deposit fee to lend out its volumes. It is interesting to note that Ptolemy the Third also asked the librarian of the Library of Athens to lend him the official papyri of the works of Aeschylus, Sophocles, and Euripides to have them copied and then returned. Ptolemy the Third paid a deposit of 15 talents to be returned when the books were given back. However, he realized that the books were worth more than 15 talents, so he kept the originals and sent back copies to the Athens Library. See External Egypt, “Library of Alexandria.” Also of note is the new Library of Alexandria, an impressive structure called the “Bibliotheca Alexandrina.” One of its initiatives is to archive all known web pages. http://www.bibalex.org (accessed January 20, 2006).
The Google library project will transform the way we do research and scholarship. For the first time, everyone will be able to search the written record of human knowledge. It also allows libraries to create a digital archive that preserves this material for all time. Only libraries are tasked by the public with the responsibility of archiving all the world's written works. No other entity can take on this responsibility. This is a tremendously important public policy discussion. In the future, most research and learning is going to take place in a digital world. Material that does not exist in digital form will effectively disappear. We need to decide whether we are going to allow the development of new technology to be used as a tool to restrict the public's access to knowledge, or if we are going to ensure that people can find these works and that they will be preserved for future generations.163
University of Michigan. “Statement on Google” (emphasis added).
In August 2005, the project was abruptly canceled; Google stopped their efforts caused by fears of copyright infringement lawsuits by the publishing industry.164
Google's fears have just been realized in a class-action copyright infringement suit. See Wyatt, Writers Sue Google, Accusing it of Copyright Infringement. New York Times, September 21, 2005.
For an explanation of this phenomenon, see Boyle, “The Second Enclosure.”
These real examples show that whether consumers will be able to listen to their satellite radio broadcasts the way they want, campers can express themselves musically around campfires, and innovative companies can compile the next Library of Alexandria directly depends on whether the international copyright regime can succeed at not only protecting their investments but also protecting innovative expression and cultural diversity.
PRAGMATIC ASSESSMENT
To adequately assess the copyright system in light of cultural diversity goals, we must piece together our informational triptych of history, law, and case study of the current system (with the former sections of analysis providing a contextual and analytical framework). In the following text, I aim to distill thousands of possible arguments down into several benefits and harms the system presents. The analysis is viewed through the lenses of preservation and protection of global musical diversity and cultural expressions.
The current international copyright regime arguably benefits the diversity of musical cultural content in several ways. First, it helps the western world discover the musical genres of developing and least developed countries. Protecting the investments of the cultural conglomerates allows for them to scour the globe for musical talent and either develop, record, market, and sell the artist within the world music genre or use the regional sound as samples for incorporation into western musical compilations.166
The latter practice many have referred to as the misappropriation of indigenous culture. See Rifkin, The Age of Access, 248.
Maskus, K. Intellectual Property Rights, 55. See also, Cowen, T. Creative Destruction, 24–33.
The United States, however, leads the world in the production of entertainment and high technology products protected by copyright laws.
International Intellectual Property Alliance (IIPA), “IIPA Celebrates the 10th Anniversary.”
Copyright can also serve to dismantle diversity. This is accomplished several ways. By giving monopoly rights over content to an ever-decreasing and ever-consolidating group of cultural conglomerates, those companies can consume the market by pushing independent music labels, self-produced artists, and others out of the market for recorded music. Technological progress presents itself as a double-edged sword in this arena. On the one hand, it provides independent artists the ability to record, edit, produce and distribute their works for incredibly affordable prices. On the other hand, technological progress has provided the impetus for increased regulatory protections of copyrighted works, which makes independent artists' competition—the big labels—even richer, more powerful, and more competitive.170
To explore the economics of this system, see Rosen, “The Economics of Superstars,” 845–58.
Pepper, “Making Their Own Breaks.”
Note also that, in the field of visual art, new mediums of expression are now illegal. See Wired, “Artists Just Wana.”
Copyright is appearing increasingly incapable of accomplishing what it attempts to accomplish—both domestically (within the United States as the largest exporter of cultural content) and internationally. It attempts, as Martin Kretschmer writes, “to balance the interests of creators, investors and consumers and regulate the industry all in one conceptual and legislative effort.”173
Kretschmer, Intellectual Property in Music, 21.
Smiers, Arts Under Pressure, 207.
Preliminary Conclusions
The current copyright regime has enumerated benefits that should be retained, but it exhibits more banes than blessings in the context of promoting and sustaining cultural diversity in musical commodities
While discovering rural musicians may help small numbers of them become recognized internationally, musical diversity is destroyed when the world's cornucopia of music is mixed and edited by handful of media interests. Although it may be beneficial for the world to have access to American cultural goods, it is not beneficial, in cultural diversity terms, for the world to be awash in the culture of only one nation. Further, although a harmonization of national intellectual property laws into negotiated instruments-in-progress like TRIPS may eventually serve the public good, such a system is ineffective without strict international enforcement. The current legal regime of copyright (both regionally in the United States and as implemented internationally in negotiated agreements) is unable to provide a predicable, enforceable, harmonized, and balanced international market for cultural commodities amid the wide proliferation of digital and network technologies. The historical analysis we have explored has shown that, in new eras, new legal philosophies are born. Our case study (comprised of three out of an existent multiplicity of real examples) shows how the current copyright regime can hurt innovation, creativity, and diversity—the very fundamentals that it was ostensibly created to service.
Thus, I assert that the current copyright regime hurts cultural diversity through its observed impact on innovators, artists, consumers, and inextricable ties to oligopoly interests. Some prominent legal scholars have expressed the same sentiment. Rosemary Coombe noted, “Laws of intellectual property privilege mono-logic forms against dialogic practice and create significant power differentials between social actors engaged in hegemonic struggle.”175
Coombe, “The Cultural Life of Intellectual Properties,” 86.
Litman, Digital Copyright, 80.
Clearly we have entered a new era—the era of the digital music revolution. There are new material circumstances that simply were not present in former eras. Digital reproduction has rendered copies of music distortion free; the World Wide Web has connected music fans (and their collections); physical music media has been relegated to secondary importance in light of customizable playlists and digital music players with ever-doubling storage capacities; and affordable digital music studios have democratized music production. Just as past technological breakthroughs have spawned new regulatory policies,177
Examples of this have been illustrated throughout this paper. From the Renaissance era shift (caused by the technology of the printing press) in the legal conception of music as personal property to the legal evolution of the television industry regulations (caused by the advent of cable technology), technological innovation has consistently necessitated legal revision and innovation.
Smiers, Arts Under Pressure, 226.
It is clear that not only do copyright rules need to adjust to balance both consumer and artist interests with the interests of the producers, but copyright also must broadly reform its communication policy179
See Wu, “Copyright's Communications Policy,” 1.
Current Work on the Protection and Preservation of Cultural Diversity
After two years of negotiations, UNESCO adopted the Convention on Cultural Diversity on the October, 20, 2005. Countries vacillated over whether the convention would be applied or interpreted in detrimental ways. The United States, for example, fretted about its affect on the progressive liberalization of the audiovisual sector. When the convention came down to a vote, all members, except for the United States and Israel, expressed their assent. This near unanimity can be interpreted several ways. First, it is reasonable to notice that international instruments that pass with such uniform assent rarely impose great responsibilities or binding commitments on the signatory members. Second, notice the ideological rift between the majority (152) of members who did not vote against the convention and the minority (2) who did. The opposition voiced several arguments. Paragraph 2 of Article 8 (measures to protect cultural expressions) states, “parties may take all appropriate measures to protect and preserve cultural expression in situations referred to in paragraph 1 in a manner consistent with the provisions of this Convention.” The United States feared that this might be misinterpreted and serve as a basis for impermissible new trade barriers that are related to cultural expressions. The argument continues by attacking the provisions as vague and contending that the scope of the convention is ambiguous. In Section III the Convention attempts to define concepts like cultural diversity, cultural activities, and the like. For example, cultural expressions are defined as “those expressions that result from the creativity of individuals, groups and societies, and that have cultural content.”180
UNESCO, Convention, Art. 4.3.
For a more in-depth critique of this issue, see Brouder, “The UNESCO Convention.”
A recognition of the need to dynamically mitigate imbalances in the current regulatory regime is positive. However, it has been noted that UNESCO's focus on the survival of diverse cultures may serve to drown out cultural dissent—the only means by which cultures are redefined and membership within them is negotiated. Sunder, “Cultural Dissent,” 498.
The relationship between the UNESCO Convention and WTO law, especially from the perspective of Switzerland, is further discussed in Graber, “Volkerrechtliche Rahmenbedingungen,” 28 et seq.
Ameliorative Ideas and Expected Developments
The current challenge is to allow content to be diversely produced and accessed without undermining the investments made within the cultural industries.184
Note that despite music industry claims that digital file sharing has caused the declines in their sales in the past years (1994–2003), year-end 2004 statistics released by RIAA show an increase (4.4%) in their total retail units shipped. This statistic refers to analog sales. Sales of digital music have exploded with the emergence of online music stores such as Apple's iTunes Music Store. We may fairly conclude that, at the very least, the digital environment cannot be causally linked to declines in the U.S. music industry. For statistics released by the RIAA, see RIAA, “Facts and Figures.”
This phenomenon may be attributable to the public choice theory (i.e., when the majority is unconcerned with the per capita losses they suffer, the vote-maximizing political decision-makers will ignore the interests of the many and support the interests of the vocal, well-organized, or well-funded few).
The industry's rationale is best summed up by Jack Valenti's famous slogan, “If you cannot protect what you own, you don't own anything.”
Because a sui generis protection for multimedia works, at this time, seems neither necessary nor desirable. See Aplin, Copyright Law, 252–54.
Some have supported abolishing copyright altogether, in favor of a radical recasting of the players in the international organizations responsible for trade in cultural products. The new organization would be termed the World Localization Organization (WLO) and would replace the WTO for cultural commerce. See Hines, “Localization,” 130.
For a cutting-edge analysis of DRMs, see Graber et al. (eds.), Digital Rights Management.
See the proposal made in Eckersley, “Virtual Markets for Virtual Goods.”
DRM systems, or self-enforcing digital controls on the use of content, have become a means by which the cultural industries can preserve control over their content and distribute digital content over the Internet at the same time. These systems promise zero infringement by the end users of the digital products. Presumably, these systems could ensure that, in the digital realm, copyrights are fully honored. However, there are potential pitfalls. First, the history of computer programming reveals that every code can be broken, and every digital lock hacked.191
This week, the band Switchfoot released their latest album. It is encumbered by copy-restrictive technology from its label, Sony. The CD cannot be transferred to portable music players—like Apple's iPod. To appease their angry fans, the band itself has linked to open-source program CDex's download page with instructions on disabling the protection and ripping the files to MP3. See Slashdot, “Artist Suggesting Ways.” The band has commented, “It is heartbreaking to see our blood, sweat, and tears over the past 2 years blurred by the confusion and frustration surrounding this new technology.” This quote is from their web site: www.switchfoot.com (January 15, 2006).
Note that, to date, Apple's DRM, FairPlay, has met with considerable initial success. However, the technology has been cracked by industry rival RealNetworks http://arstechnica.com/news/posts/1081206124.html (January 15, 2006). DRMs also can fail technologically in the absence of hacking. For example, in January 2005 there was a catastrophic failure of the Valve DRM server used to verify the registration keys for players of the popular game Half-Life 2. Although the game was the players' property and the players wished merely to play them on their own computers, the failure of a network service rendered their property worthless.
The U.S. Congress is currently considering ending proprietary DRMs. To review the debate over this, see http://www.enn.ie/news.html?code=9598058/ (January 15, 2006). Of course, the development of an open information and communications technology ecosystem would be the ideal scenario. See Berkman Center, “Roadmap for Open ICT.”
VMRS systems, or state-funded (virtual market) remuneration schemes, have also been proposed by scholars in the field. These schemes generally promise to strike a balance between industry and consumer interests for digital media products. By creating a virtual market for digital information goods, such a system would appease the industry by paying them from government coffers (some proposals have based the amount and choice of beneficiaries on consumer voting systems) and the consumers by decriminalizing access of copyrighted digital material. Here, there are also potential pitfalls. First, there is the problem of assessing who gets how much. This distributional factor is not a small question, and could undermine such a system. Second, the philosophical question arises as to whether the state should directly subsidize the arts in this way. Third, VMRS may result in government censorship. (If governments have direct financial control over artists, they may excessively control the arts.) Fourth, virtual market models would certainly disrupt existing economic structures for cultural production and distribution—thus impacting national economies. In the United States, for example, the copyright industries account for more than 5% of gross domestic product (GDP).194
Further, VMRS has serious implications regarding privacy rights. Such a system would require a central database of the cultural and informational preferences of whole societies at large, which is problematic on both philosophical and pragmatic levels. These examples exhibit some alternatives to the course of implanting the traditional copyright paradigm into the digital world. Although they exhibit creative innovation and promise, they also reveal that there is much work to be done to engineer an enforceable and harmonized international intellectual property regime to tackle the digital networked environment.The near future brings exciting technological possibilities for consumers in terms of experiencing cultural content—especially music. Among the inevitable innovations, one in particular has the potential to fundamentally change the music industry. This innovation is the distribution of digital recorded music via mobile telephone networks.195
The Motorola Corporation, in cooperation with the Apple Corporation, has pioneered this technological convergence. See www.motorola.com/rokr and www.apple.com/itunes/mobile (accessed January 15, 2006). This technology is in its infancy, and its expansion—especially with regards to mobile phone network convergence—will have an impact on both the market and the regulatory landscape for musical goods.
SUMMARY OF FINDINGS
Just as the advent of printed music changed how people thought of musical goods, digitization has sparked a change in how people think of digital musical goods. In the former era printed music sparked the inclusion of music into the foray of personal property. Regulatory regimes adapted and reflected this change of valuation. In the current era, digitized music has sparked ever-increasing claims over musical property and ever-increasing consumer use restrictions. This study has briefly reviewed whether such regulatory strategy has stimulated or stifled diversity in the musical marketplace of ideas and expression. A review of the law has noted the inconsistencies and results of the current copyright regime. A review of several real-life stories illustrates how the legal and economic copyright climate affects some players. Taken together, these factors show that the current international copyright regime yields a command and control methodology inconsistent with the current needs brought about by globalization and the acknowledgment of the importance of culture.196
The most credible framework-level modality for dynamically adjusting the system to account for this paradigm shift appears to be a remodelling of TRIPS, using a holistic approach in balancing interests and tightening the global mechanism for its enforcement.
CONCLUSION
The chimerical debate over copyright in the digital networked environment yields many rationales and challenges for adjusting the current system. In the adjustment process, only if the goal of promoting cultural diversity takes a heightened role can a true balancing of interests be reached. The debate over the preferable legislative tools for that balancing continues. With rapid convergence and technological growth as the two-dimensional reality of the digital age, smart legislators will seek measures that not only meet the needs of corporate interests (necessary for ongoing technological innovation and cultural development), but also strive to promote cultural diversity among cultural industry goods (necessary for long-term sustainability of cultural markets and human rights). What a sweet sound that would be for citizens and consumers of all cultures!
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
At various points in its development, this article benefited from critiques by Alexander Bauer, Thomas Cottier, and Christoph Beat Graber. I am extremely grateful for the time and assistance they offered me. Any errors of fact or interpretation are my own.