Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-hvd4g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T04:10:28.207Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE PENDULUM SWINGS AGAIN: RECENT DEBATES ON CHINA'S PREWAR ECONOMY

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 July 2009

Niv Horesh
Affiliation:
University of New South Wales E-mail n.horesh@unsw.edu.au
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Extract

The aim of this brief survey is to provide a critical review of studies of China's economic history recently published by prominent Western scholars. It will explore two veins of scholarly debates that underlie Western perceptions of both China's past and its trajectory of future development, and also consider the historic significance of joint-stock enterprise in China as opposed to Britain and Japan.

Type
State of the field
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009

INTRODUCTION

The aim of this brief survey is to provide a critical review of studies of China's economic history recently published by prominent Western scholars. It will explore two veins of scholarly debates that underlie Western perceptions of both China's past and its trajectory of future development, and also consider the historic significance of joint-stock enterprise in China as opposed to Britain and Japan.

A fairly recent vein of debate concerns the performance of the Chinese economy under the late-Qing and KMT rule. Another more “ancient” debate branched off Max Weber's seminal work – published almost a century ago – on the factors that had positioned Europe politically and economically ahead of China from the sixteenth century onward.Footnote 1 The more recent debate began in late 1989 when Thomas Rawski and Loren Brandt published markedly positive estimates of per capita Chinese agricultural productivity growth in the century preceding the second Sino-Japanese War (1937). Rawski and Brandt systematically revised what had been until then a dismal portrayal of living standards in the Chinese hinterland, winning over in the process respected veterans of the discipline such as Ramon Myers. Based on elaborate econometric analyses of land surveys and price data, they concluded that total agricultural output between 1850 and 1937 overtook population gains by up to one percent annually.Footnote 2

Despite Myers's endorsement, these revisionist views have since been contested by numerous other scholars, who point to the failings in Republican agrarian reforms (1912–1949), and who challenge the assumptions that underlie Rawski and Brandt's findings.Footnote 3 In particular, Rawski and Brandt's premise of efficient factor markets at work in early twentieth-century China remains at odds with a fairly large number of recent studies.Footnote 4

Put simply, interpretations of economic realities in prewar China still oscillate between the pessimistic and optimistic. “Pessimists” tend to underscore problems in production relations – lack of land-tenure security, peasant immiserization, and hostage markets.Footnote 5 On the other hand, “optimists” such as Rawski and Brandt identify consistent growth in agricultural productivity fuelled by what they see as the ameliorative effects of China's integration with world factor markets.

“OPTIMISTS” VS. “PESSIMISTS”: THE DETAILS

The problem facing economists and economic historians of both persuasions is that, even after questionable macroeconomic data are “husked”, demographic trends in the prewar era prove elusive. For example, it conventionally had been believed that during the period 1850 to 1873 China witnessed a dramatic hike in mortality rates, mainly due to the afflictions of the Taiping Rebellion (1851–1864). But in an influential article published in 1978, Peter Schran showed that census figures from the mid-nineteenth century should be revised upward by approximately 50 million. This revised statistic, in turn, translates into lower population growth rates in the early twentieth century and – by implication – may well dampen the notion of improving living standards during the Republican era.Footnote 6

At any rate, Schran's article still provides a stern caveat for anybody wishing to make sweeping macro-level generalizations about the Chinese economy. More specifically, his findings suggest that spotty aggregations based on late and post-Imperial observations could easily be misinterpreted when they are applied indiscriminately to a land as regionally diverse as China. Regional variance during the period under review reflected not just different factor endowments, but also the parcelling up of large swathes of China by foreign powers – with Manchuria under Russian and then firmer Japanese control, and Shanghai under British rule, both experiencing rapid industrialization.

A neat convergence of opinion in the complex debate between “optimists” and “pessimists” still seems a long way away. Nonetheless, recognition of primary source shortfalls has recently induced Loren Brandt – arguably the most pronounced “optimist” – to tone down slightly some of his earlier observations:

Despite the marked increase in growth, it is obvious that not all the potential of the Chinese [prewar] economy was tapped, and that a variety of constraints continued to prevent more rapid growth from being achieved … [T]rends are much more difficult to assess [than in the 1990s], but data do not appear to support the view of a long-term deterioration in the distribution of income over the late nineteenth and early twentieth century.Footnote 7

More scholars now recognize that, in order to understand China's prewar economy, it is necessary to disassemble the jigsaw-puzzle image into which it is often lumped. Notably, Mark Elvin advanced the proposition that the Chinese economy in the first half of the twentieth century should be divided into four distinct macro-systems with substantive income disparities – the poor rural hinterland, the bustling treaty-ports, Japanese-managed Manchuria and Taiwan, and the separate pastureland economy of the Northwest.Footnote 8

What is more, newly published work by younger scholars contends with one of the two main arguments underpinning the “optimist” view, calling into question the notion that China's prewar economy enjoyed a higher degree of financial integration than previously thought. Debin Ma, in particular, alludes to the fact that much of Rawski's upbeat assessment of China's overall economic performance derives from the misapplication of Shanghai's urban growth dynamic and cosmopolitan flair to the rest of the country.Footnote 9

The variance of opinion between “optimists” and “pessimists” about the degree of market integration in prewar China echoes, in a sense, a more profound debate over the root cause of European pre-eminence in the early modern era. Why did China's technological, monetary and institutional head start over the West during the tenth through thirteenth centuries dissipate?

THE DEBATE ON THE “GREAT DIVERGENCE”

Until the mid-twentieth century, Western thinkers assumed that economic progress in China had been forestalled owing to supra-structural impediments like the autocratic nature of China's Confucian body politics, the self-professed “amateurism” of its officialdom or the “passivity” of its countrymen.Footnote 10 Ironically, such sweeping cultural judgements seem to be creeping back into the academic discourse through the back door – this time not to explain underdevelopment in the prewar era but to foreshadow the rise of East Asia in the twenty-first century.Footnote 11 PRC historians, on the other hand, have consistently adhered to an inverted Marxian theory, alleging that China's “sprouts of capitalism” had been maliciously trampled by Western imperialist incursions.Footnote 12

Socio-cultural impediments to modernization, such as the low status of merchants, certainly could be found in traditional China. However, more recent scholarship has substantially reshaped our views of the merchant class in the late Qing, pointing to vertical linkages with the gentry and officialdom that were manifest, for example, in the sale of Qing Imperial degrees and in absentee land ownership.Footnote 13 While “Confucianism” often connotes familial prejudice, cronyism and autarkism, these are not necessarily insurmountable obstacles on the road toward economic modernization. This is perhaps why the thrust of most “pessimistic” interpretations of China's early modern economy has shifted, since the 1970s, from the socio-cultural dimension to demographic ones, advancing influential theoretical tropes such as “involution” and “equilibrium trap” to explain underdevelopment.Footnote 14

Nonetheless, a well-rounded account of China's economic performance over the course of the prewar era cannot be produced while ignoring the critical role played by institutions. More research is needed to explain the institutional variance between China and the West; the different vehicles of body politics; the respective balance of power between the private and the public domain; the composition of bureaucracy and its indoctrination; the nature of law enforcement; and the pervasiveness of financial intermediaries.

Research is needed still more to construe late-Imperial China's (1368–1911) relinquishment of monetary and fiscal reins. Here, Akinobu Kuroda has recently carved out a space for scholarly discussion by suggesting that despite proverbial similarities between the two countries, Tokugawa Japan (1603–1868) had already been a much more financially-integrated and better-regulated polity than Qing China (1644–1911). Nowhere was this more evident than in the realm of currency, where by 1835 Japan already had an extensive and fairly stable exchange of subsidiary coinage and high-denomination government-backed fiduciary notes (hansatsu) in circulation, while Chinese commerce was still largely reliant on full-bodied metallic currency or privately issued scrip (qianpiao). Similarly, the establishment of the Bank of Japan in 1871 meant that Japan had a single legal tender (the Yen) over half a century before China did.Footnote 15

If both the Qing dynasty's lack of interest in market regulation and its miscomprehension of Western business practices have been discussed at length in the pertinent literature, its emaciated tax base and minimalist bureaucratic apparatus have not received the attention they deserve.Footnote 16 In the late-Imperial era, for example, local bailiffs reported only about half of all tax revenue to their superiors. By and large, tax revenues dwindled from about 10 percent of total agrarian production during the Ming dynasty (1368–1643) to only about 2 percent in the late-Qing.Footnote 17 The famous nineteenth-century Likin transit duty constituted the sole fiscal innovation throughout the Qing reign, but even this measure resulted from provincial initiative rather than from central government resolve.

In his recent work, Peer Vries emphasized that by the nineteenth century China and Britain possessed qualitatively different government bureaucracies. Although China's population was thirty times bigger, the absolute number of government officials there was no higher than in Britain.Footnote 18 Such global comparisons suggest that population pressures and agrarian production relations alone cannot adequately explain China's technological falling-behind, if only because they did not obstruct the economic take-off of densely inhabited Meiji Japan (1868–1912).

More generally, the British experience indicates that, as of the late sixteenth century, government bureaucracy and a sophisticated credit economy evolved as a means of affirming the concession of property rights by the monarch. Notably, British monarchs tolerated the rise of joint-stock companies because the latter paid the treasury hard currency in return for their Charters, and helped raise tax revenue.

The historic significance of joint-stock enterprise in the East Asian context will be further explored below. Suffice it to say here that through the extensive capital they had raised, the founders of European joint-stock companies achieved as of the sixteenth century a degree of investment security and economies of scale that were quite unparalleled elsewhere in the early modern world. Being the progeny of these early joint-stock companies, privately-owned but publicly-listed British firms continued, as of the mid-nineteenth century, to utilize economies of scale acquired in London's emerging securities market to tap into China's foreign trade and into its fragmented financial services sector.

By then, Parliament had clearly displaced the Crown as the locus of political power in Britain. Representing a broader spectrum of commercial interests, Parliament was not only tolerating joint-stock enterprise but also actively engaged in regulating it, and laying down the legal wherewithal for its exponential growth in the twentieth century. In his recent work, James Taylor has ably flagged the dialectical junctures British joint-stock enterprise had to traverse before it became universally accepted in the twentieth century. The Bubble Act of 1720 curtailed, for example, the growth of joint-stock ventures that were seen as overly speculative, particularly country banks. Later, as British public opinion grew less mistrustful of impersonal corporate entities, entrepreneurial pressure was building bottom-up for the government to permit and regulate share capital in a number of industries. Then, in 1844, the famous Peel Act formally recognized smaller joint-stock banks, but sought to eliminate private bank note issuance in return. Finally, the British corporate law reforms of 1856 allowed all joint-stock companies to apply for limited-liability status irrespective of Royal Charter bestowal.Footnote 19

FROM DEMOGRAPHIC TO INSTITUTIONAL FOCUS

Both “optimists” and “pessimists” seem to agree that Shanghai, with its semicolonial setting and its advantageous location as a gateway to the fertile Yangzi Delta, served as an important catalyst for the modernization of the Chinese economy as from 1842. Yet more work is needed to explain operative differences between expatriate firms in that city and Chinese businesses in other cities that were only nominally (or not at all) subsumed under the British treaty-port boilerplate, and where extra-territorial privileges did not clearly obtain. Needless to say, diverse climates, production relations, geography and factor endowment all significantly account for the division between centre and periphery in Chinese economic historiography. What seems to be lacking in much of the pertinent literature, however, is institutional epistemology.

As a rule of thumb, it would probably make sense to stylize cities like littoral Tianjin or riverside Guangzhou as an extension of Shanghai's treaty-port modern economy despite obvious differences in climate and factor endowment with the Yangzi Delta. With its large British-administered concession area and foreign financial institutions, Hankou was perhaps integrated into the very same economic system despite being situated much further inland. But nominal and fairly remote treaty-ports like Mengzi (Yunnan), or Chongqing (Sichuan) may provide instructive contrasts to the Yangzi Delta economy. In other words, the demarcation between the Chinese “hinterland” and “littoral” economies should be understood not purely in terms of rural backwardness versus urban sophistication, or in terms of distance from the coast, but also as the degree to which local peasants produced agricultural commodities for world markets (the Yangzi Delta being a case in point), and the degree to which factor agents had recourse to treaty-port finance and extra-territorial protection.

Inevitably, such research agenda would be less informed by demographics than by recognition of the significance of evolutionary economic change and path dependency along the lines identified by Douglass North. Drawing heavily on the European and North American experience, North and his co-authors have shown persuasively how government espousal of property rights – through the dissemination of a civil code, patent laws, insurance premia and Royal Charters – is one of the definitive factors behind economic modernization.Footnote 20 Once the private rate of return on research and development was propped up to match the public one in the sixteenth century, Britain could embark on a course whereby imported foodstuffs gradually freed up resources imperative for the Industrial Revolution.

The “institutional formula”, which allowed Britain to escape many of the demographic checks that all other premodern polities had grappled with, was not unique. Much the same dynamics had first occurred in the United Provinces of the Netherlands between the fifteenth and seventeenth centuries, and held out roughly until the Batavian Republic succumbed to mercantilism in the late eighteenth century. In the late nineteenth century, the same dynamics lent the American economy sufficient impetus to succeed Britain.Footnote 21

North captured the essence of European economic “exceptionalism” for what it is worth, but the theoretical construct that he laid down has since been finessed by scholars steeped in Asian and Mediterranean history.Footnote 22 Working largely within the latter category but borrowing extensively from game theory and diverse geo-generic scenarios, Avner Greif, for example, has made a consistent contribution to an emerging model of institutional fluidity and optimal growth.Footnote 23 Though the empiric underpinnings of this model are still fairly raw, some of the key concepts it is advancing have been employed to explain why Shanghai's economic dynamism could not have emerged in the Chinese hinterland before 1842.Footnote 24

A major challenge to this institutional approach is mounted by “California School” historians, who see much the same free market dynamism at work in seventeenth-century East Asia without any industrial turnaround.Footnote 25 They therefore conclude that other factors better explain Europe's economic performance, for example colonial extraction, denser coal deposits, or the competitive nation-state system. Kenneth Pomeranz's pathbreaking book, The Great Divergence, is perhaps the most forceful iteration of “California School” views. Admirably conversant with the economic histories of both continents, Pomeranz marshalled a vast array of secondary-source data to argue that England's ascendancy in the early nineteenth century should be ascribed to “shadow acres” in far-flung colonies, and the proximity of its domestic coal deposits to arterial waterways.Footnote 26 A comprehensive riposte to Pomeranz's main thesis is yet to emerge. Nonetheless, discerning readers of Pomeranz's work are left with one niggling Northian question unanswered: if coal and colonial possessions, as opposed to market dynamics, were the key to England's “freak” departure from Malthusian constraints, why didn't the Iberian economy evolve in quite the same way? After all, it did possess colonies worldwide, was rich in mineral resources, and was not entirely bereft of coal.Footnote 27

The abundance and accessibility of British coal deposits should not deflect scholars' attention from the large-scale exploitation of other sources of energy, which had set Britain apart from the Continental economy long before the nineteenth century: husbandry and chemicals in agriculture, and water-milling in garment manufacturing. In his influential study, David Landes cast these two factors as productivity gainers that paved the way for the Industrial Revolution. Landes then alluded to the ubiquity of financial “paper instruments” and joint-stock companies in Britain as even earlier, and equally significant, portents of rupture with the Continental mould.Footnote 28

Landes's account ought to have been complemented with a more coherent institutional dimension. In that sense, Pomeranz's de-emphasis of divergent institutions between England and China is perhaps disappointing. It is also somewhat surprising since his early work on late-Imperial Shandong had ably highlighted the degree of market disintegration plaguing much of the Chinese hinterland. That interest and currency exchange rates fluctuated wildly from one county to another, but were lower and more stable in foreign-controlled Qingdao, is one resounding symptom of this failure.Footnote 29

Pomeranz's perception of a late eighteenth-century English departure from either European or Chinese growth patterns is filliped, to some extent, by econometric analysis of secular price data presented by Shiue and Keller.Footnote 30 Theirs is a comparative research whose rigour would be truly compelling if it were not for the devil lying in the small detail, as is often the case with Chinese archival sources. In contrast to Northian theory, Shiue and Keller argue that there is no strong evidence to support the existence of a unique European “institutional formula” for economic growth, since markets in China appear no less efficient than in continental Europe right up to the nineteenth century. Yet their regressions do not seem to factor in exchange-rate fluctuations across different European currencies or regional variations in the value of the Chinese tael, and are otherwise characterized by low levels of significance.Footnote 31

A rather different iteration of California School arguments has recently been advanced by Jack Goldstone, as if to address an aspect of the Eurasian divide that Pomeranz's analysis has “written out of the scenario”, that is, science.Footnote 32Pace Goldstone, readily available coal was a necessary but not sufficient factor in the makeup of Britain's Industrial Revolution. He identifies cycles of “crises” and “efflorescence” – implying a per-capita GDP growth rate of up to 1 percent annually – as an attribute common to many Eurasian economies before the nineteenth century, from Golden Age Netherlands in the West to Tokugawa Japan in the East.Footnote 33 He then concludes that what set the British economy apart from the Eurasian norm in the mid-nineteenth century was not merely new sources of energy, but an ardent pursuit of applicable scientific know-how to harness latent resources. Goldstone concedes, however, that the sustainability of what he terms as Britain's peculiar “engine science” and its spread into popular culture was greatly facilitated by commercial law and distinct political institutions.Footnote 34

THE SIGNIFICANCE OF JOINT-STOCK ENTERPRISE

An important tenet propounded by all California School adherents is the notion that the formation of joint-stock companies in Europe cannot be seen as unique.Footnote 35 But while Japanese scholars, for example, have traced the first Chinese joint-stock partnerships as far back as the tenth century, these partnerships often survived in the face of government policy, rather than as a result of it.Footnote 36 Furthermore, as William Scott's early work, for example, might indicate, the sources which point to the occurrence of joint-stock enterprise in late-Imperial China do not come near the degree of legal detail and stakeholding transparency that characterize documents surrounding the establishment of British joint-stock firms from their very inception in the early sixteenth century.Footnote 37 Scott's pioneering work is suggestive of a long continuum of institutional evolution that links publicly-funded trade expeditions to the Baltic and Africa under Elizabethan patronage with the subsequent emergence of the London stock exchange, as well as with the establishment of domestic joint-stock banks and overseas chartered banks later in the Victorian era.Footnote 38

This is not to say that when operating overseas British companies upheld transparency as a value in itself. British banks in Shanghai, for example, took advantage of the amorphous legal setting there to withhold information on banknote circulation volumes whereas, in Hong Kong, they were obliged to disclose this type of information in the colonial government's Blue Book. Put simply, stakeholding transparency allowed British joint-stock companies to mobilize economies of scale. It was practised in London and other places where companies raised capital, but did not necessarily extend beyond where the British legal system obtained.

As indicated above, the British experience seems to suggest that an advanced credit economy is contingent on a mature institutional, corporate and regulatory framework. But it was not until the mid-1910s that homegrown modern financial institutions and a corporate sector germinated in Shanghai, by which time latecomer economies like that of Germany and Japan had already become ascendant industrial powers. Japan's experience can probably shed more light on China's predicament than Britain's because it tells us something about the dynamic of catch-up.

Alexander Gerschenkron's famous thesis suggested that in nineteenth-century latecomer economies like Germany's, where securities markets had lagged far behind London, state-backed banks were crucial to industrialization because only they could mobilize savings on a mass scale and channel them to investment in machinery and railroads. In less urbanized countries like Russia, where bank branch networks were thin on the ground, the central government was thought of as the only one capable of mobilizing funds on similar scale.Footnote 39

Perhaps under the influence of Gerschenkronian theory, most scholars have until recently attributed Japan's prewar industrial miracle precisely to the fact that, unlike Russia, it quickly turned into a bank-centred economy. In other words, the Japanese economy during the first half of the last century was cast as the fief of powerful state-backed pyramidal groups (zaibatsu), each financing its manufacturing firms through preferential access to affiliate bank loans.Footnote 40 However, in their newly published work Miwa and Ramseyer have persuasively shown that industrial firms in prewar Japan grew, in the first instance, through stock offering on the Tokyo and Osaka stock exchanges, not through bank credit. Based on an impressive compilation of panel data, Miwa and Ramseyer contend that between 1919 and 1936 Japanese manufacturing firms rarely exhibited a ratio of bank debt to liabilities of over 10 percent. Moreover, they present evidence suggesting that much of the stock in Japanese industrial firms was held diffusely by unrelated investors, rather than by zaibatsu banks or family circles.Footnote 41

Miwa and Ramseyer's work places joint-stock companies right at the heart of economic growth epistemology, and their findings about Japan can by no means be lost on China specialists – not least because of the cultural, demographic, technological (but not institutional) proximity between the two countries in the late nineteenth century. A detailed analysis is beyond the scope of this survey but it is nevertheless instructive to consider that by 1900 the value of Japanese stocks traded in Osaka and Tokyo had been roughly four times that of the Shanghai stock exchange at the time, even though the Shanghai stock exchange listed Western-run companies almost exclusively, and was suffused with the aura of extraterritorial protection.Footnote 42

The other striking difference between the Japanese and Chinese securities markets before the turn of the last century lies in the fact that Japan's market helped finance the buildup of Japan's extensive railway networks and seminal industry, whereas China's was weighted heavily toward foreign banking and insurance companies. In the 1870s, railways were being built in both China and Japan, but within three decades Japan achieved a commanding lead in absolute railway mileage and, of course, in terms of the ratio of mileage to population and land size. Until 1890, two systems of railways operated in Japan side by side: a government-owned one and, equally importantly, one operated by joint-stock companies able to mobilize funds on domestic securities markets. For the impoverished early-Meiji government to defray the construction of the whole railway network would have been fiscally ruinous. In that sense, joint-stock finance was crucial to Japan's early modernization effort. The late-imperial Chinese court preferred, on balance, to borrow overseas at a higher cost, and contract railway construction out to foreigners if only to avert the onset of autonomous domestic enterprise.Footnote 43

The relatively small size of China's domestic securities market through the later part of the nineteenth century has much wider implications. This issue is clearly relevant to the nature of China's modernization effort in the long term, as Bowen and Rose have argued.Footnote 44 After almost three decades of reform in the PRC, private enterprise and private property rights are still lamely framed within the legal system. Established with much fanfare in 1990, the Shanghai and Shenzhen domestic bourses rarely float private firms. PRC taxation policy similarly disadvantages SMEs without intimate political connections in favour of state-owned conglomerates and foreign ventures. Yet, the PRC's double-digit growth figures over these three decades of reform cannot but raise the question whether a strong securities market would still be vital to economic growth in a twenty-first-century context. It remains to be seen whether we are witnessing a new and uniquely Chinese development model in the making – one where historical observations are not of great value – or whether the China boom is about to run out of steam unless meaningful reform of the financial sector is initiated soon.

CONCLUSIONS

This survey suggests that recent studies of China's prewar economy have made the pendulum swing again. The “optimist” literature of the late 1980s nearly displaced conventional wisdom. This literature portrayed China's prewar economy as fairly vibrant and well integrated with world markets. But it is now being increasingly called into question by scholars more attuned to the yawning gap between commercialized Shanghai and the smaller treaty-ports, on the one hand, and China's rural hinterland on the other; and, furthermore, the gap between the steady growth of joint-stock enterprise and the sweeping economic reforms of Meiji Japan and the fiscal stagnancy and lack of investor confidence in late-Qing and early-Republican China.

In pointing to new groundbreaking work, this survey has also identified a shift from a demographical to an institutional focus in recent studies of the economic divergence between late-imperial China and early modern Britain (and Japan). Viewed from a purely temporal perspective, the differences between British and Chinese business organization may not seem compelling. Even if joint-stock enterprise was finally enshrined in Britain through limited-liability laws in the 1860s, the first Chinese limited firms were in existence in Shanghai already by the 1890s.

The crucial point to remember, however, is that what may seem like a fairly thin difference begot, in fact, one of the fundamental causes for European economic supremacy in the early modern age. This insight should become eminently clear once “California School” scholars have recognized the long continuum linking the establishment of Europe's early joint-stock trading companies (sixteenth to seventeenth centuries) with the emergence of non-chartered joint-stock companies (eighteenth century) and the consummation of limited liability and equity finance concepts by state regulators late in the nineteenth century.Footnote 45

Put baldly, this survey suggests that the occurrence (or absence) of joint-stock formations in China's long history is of secondary importance. What does matter is the unwillingness (or inability) of China's late-Imperial bureaucracy to enforce such arrangements as those, which underpinned non-kin equity ownership in Europe and later in Japan. Overwhelmed by the efficacy of Western technology in the treaty-ports, the Qing Court was convinced that drawing private capital to a government-led industrialization effort was the only way to catch up with the West. But the resultant mixed enterprise (guandu-shangban) failed precisely because the Qing embraced the veneer rather than the substance of private property rights. The point was made eminently clear by Feuerwerker well before the advent of “optimist” literature, and since then has been revalidated by extensive studies such as that of Kirby or Faure.Footnote 46 In retrospect, the considerable contribution Rawski and Brandt's work made to our understanding of China's prewar economy derives from their introduction of elaborate quantitative methodology into the debate and from foregrounding the significance of market integration to China's economic modernization.

The implications of the debates surveyed above are quite clearly relevant to scholars of contemporary China too. This is not least because favourably revising Chinese economic performance before 1949 derogates from the legitimacy that Mainland historians bestow on CCP rule. Similarly, favourable reassessment of Chinese standards of living in the seventeenth century may deflect scholars' attention from the great institutional divergence between China and West leading up to the twentieth century. Ultimately, a better understanding of the historic linkages between private property rights, securities markets, joint-stock enterprise and sustainable economic growth (or the lack thereof) may help scholars assess China's chances of maintaining its breakneck development pace into the next decade of the twenty-first century in the face of what appears to be an ominous global financial crisis.

Footnotes

1 Weber's influential treatise The Religion of China was first published in German in 1922.

2 Rawski Reference Rawski1989, pp. 329–37; Brandt Reference Brandt1989, pp. 133–34, 179–180; Myers Reference Myers1991; for a quintessential “pessimist” work, see Ash Reference Ash1976.

3 See, e.g., Esherick Reference Esherick1991; Little Reference Little1992; Rozelle Reference Rozelle1992.

4 Fox Reference Fox1994, e.g, explicitly argues against the notion of fast-equilibrating inter-provincial labour and commodity markets that Brandt and Rawski propose for early twentieth-century China. Though broadly in the same church as Rawski, Wright too observed that Chinese factor markets did not function well in the hinterland (Wright Reference Wright2000). In her newly published monumental work, Lillian Li (Reference Li2007, pp. 196–220) clearly observes a considerable decline in intra-provincial market integration across North China from the eighteenth to the nineteenth century.

5 See Perkins Reference Perkins1969; Lippit Reference Lippit1978; Huang Reference Huang1990; Wiens Reference Wiens1992. For middle-ground assessments – see Riskin Reference Riskin1978; So Reference So1986; Perdue Reference Perdue1987.

6 For a comprehensive discussion – see Schran Reference Schran1978, p. 642. Schran gives a set of four alternative estimates for 1850–1953. These range between 430 and 435 million people for 1850, and between 574.2 and 582.6 million for 1953. Accordingly, Schran infers that there had been a population rise of about 50 million people between 1913–1953, or an annual population growth rate of 0.3%. Notwithstanding war fatalities, this figure is still lower than the 0.7% inferred by previous estimates.

7 Brandt Reference Brandt, Wakeman and Edmonds2000, p. 29. On the malleability of quantitative data sources – see also Rozelle Reference Rozelle1992.

8 Elvin Reference Elvin1981, pp. 254–55; based on extensive fieldwork in Sichuan, Skinner (Reference Skinner1993, p. 40) pointed to another facet of micro-variation in prewar China: some local markets in the same marketing area used different weights and measurements right until the 1950s.

10 For representative arguments see Weber Reference Weber and Gert1951; Wittfogel Reference Wittfogel1957, pp. 101–03; Balazs Reference Balazs1964, pp. 28–32; Balazs and Wittfogel, in particular, view the rapacity of state organs as the main brake on urban regeneration and mechanization.

11 Since Mao's legacy has lost much of its appeal on the Mainland, Chinese and other social scientists have mobilized Confucius onto the CCP reformist bandwagon to explain China's pursuit of economic prominence in the twenty-first century, see De Bary Reference De Bary1991, pp. 103–09.

12 For an overview of PRC theoretical trends in economic history see Zelin Reference Zelin1998.

13 Cf. Chang Reference Chang1962, pp. 149–95; Chan Reference Chan1977, pp. 187–95.

14 See Elvin Reference Elvin1973, pp. 285–316; Huang Reference Huang1990, passim. See also Perkins Reference Perkins1969.

15 See Kuroda Reference Kuroda2006; on the rapidly growing degree of integration in prewar Japan's financial markets, see also Tsurumi Reference Tsurumi, Eiji and Satoru2002; Ishii Reference Ishii2007; Mitchener and Ohnuki Reference Mitchener and Ohnuki2008; cf. Sugihara Reference Sugihara2007, p. 128. It should be noted that Sugihara's main thesis is not entirely institutional in nature; he sees more similarity in the long run between the Chinese and Japanese experiences than between Japan and the West.

16 Low taxation and self-sufficiency were implicit in Ming and Qing neo-Confucian indoctrination. See Wong Reference Wong1997, p. 102; cf. Skinner Reference Skinner1993, p. 11.

17 Kiser and Tong Reference Kiser and Xiaoxi1992, p. 311; cf. Wagel Reference Wagel1980, pp. 329–25.

18 Vries Reference Vries2003, pp. 27–28.

19 Taylor Reference Taylor2006; on joint-stock banks, see also Cameron Reference Cameron, Crisp, Patrick and Tilly1967, pp. 27–29.

20 North and Thomas Reference North and Thomas1973, pp. 154–57.

21 On the Netherlands see North and Thomas Reference North and Thomas1973, pp. 132–42; see also De Vries Reference De Vries1976, pp. 116–28, 251–52; Mokyr Reference Mokyr1976, pp. 83–132, 221–30; on the US see Davis and North Reference Davis and North1971, pp. 105–34.

22 For a survey of current trends in Asian economic history see Van der Eng Reference Van der Eng2004.

25 For work broadly associated with the “California School” see Wong Reference Wong1997; Li Reference Li1998; Frank Reference Frank1998; Pomeranz Reference Pomeranz2000; Hobson Reference Hobson2004.

26 Pomeranz Reference Pomeranz2000, pp. 66–68, 281–83.

27 On retarded industrialization in Spain despite the inflow of colonial bullion see, e.g., Tortella Reference Tortella and Herr2000, pp. 73–114; see also Broadberry and Gupta Reference Broadberry and Gupta2006.

28 Landes Reference Landes2003, pp. 41–42, 74–77, 98–99.

29 Pomeranz Reference Pomeranz1993, pp. 30–40; on exorbitant interest rates in late-Imperial China see also Isett Reference Isett2007, pp. 266–73. Interestingly, Isett posits “California School” scholars as over-emphasizing the importance of institutions in modern economic development (pp. 299–304) whereas Northian scholars would probably argue the opposite.

30 Shiue and Keller Reference Shiue and Keller2004; cf. Shiue Reference Shiue2002.

31 See Shiue and Keller 2004, Data Appendix pp. 32–37, Table 3.

32 For this critique of Pomeranz's Great Divergence see Elvin Reference Elvin2001.

33 Goldstone Reference Goldstone2002, pp. 339–53.

34 Goldstone Reference Goldstone2002, p. 374; the “engine science” is a concept that radically departs from Goldstone's earlier analytical framework which was essentially culturalist. See, e.g., Goldstone Reference Goldstone1996; on the diverging trajectories of scientific exploration between Europe and China see also Elvin Reference Elvin2004.

35 This notion is largely based on William Rowe's magisterial study of Hankou and Madeleine Zelin's work on the Furong Salt Yard in Sichuan. These two scholars have pointed to the occurrence of joint-stock enterprise in early modern China, but whether their respective case studies truly substantiated non-kin participation in stock-holding is open to question. See Rowe Reference Rowe1984, pp. 72–73; Zelin Reference Zelin1988; on kinship networks in Chinese enterprise see also Faure Reference Faure2006, pp. 42–43, 53.

36 See, e.g., Shiba Reference Shiba1968, pp. 117–20, 458–61.

37 William Scott's monumental work The Constitution and Finance of English, Scottish and Irish Joint-Stock Companies to 1720 (3 vols.) was first published in Reference Scott1912.

38 On chartered overseas trading companies as precursors of the Western corporate model, see Carlos and Nicholas Reference Carlos and Nicholas1988. On the evolution of the London stock exchange, see Michie Reference Michie1999, pp. 15–36.

39 See Gerschenkron Reference Gerschenkron1966.

40 See for example Mosk Reference Mosk2001, pp. 90–93, 199–201.

41 Miwa and and Ramseyer 2002. There is a fairly large (yet regrettably mutually exclusive) body of work supporting the view that Japanese stock ownership was fairly diffuse before the First World War: see e.g. Chakepaichayon Reference Chakepaichayon1982, particularly pp. 77–78; Rajan and Zingales Reference Rajan and Zingales2003, pp. 12–14, 38–41; Suzuki et al. Reference Suzuki, Yoichi and Kazuo2005; Ishii Reference Ishii2007, pp. 250–52. For the more conventional view of family-based control of the Meiji-era corporate economy, see e.g., Morck and Nakamura Reference Morck, Nakamura and Morck2005. However, even Morck and Nakamura concede (pp. 394–98) that key zaibatsu like Nissan, which had pioneered industrial ventures in early twentieth-century Japan, relied heavily on diffuse stock-exchange finance.

42 Comparative data gleaned from Miwa and Ramseyer Reference Miwa and Ramseyer2002; on the Shanghai stock exchange, see Thomas Reference Thomas2001, p. 72, Table 4.1. Yen-Tael currency conversion was based on the 1903 figure in Hsiao Reference Hsiao1974, p. 191.

44 Bowen and Rose Reference Bowen1998. Cf. volume edited by Oi and Waldre Reference Oi and Waldre1999.

45 This institutional continuum has been explained cogently by Rosenberg and Birdzell Reference Rosenberg and Birdzell1985, pp. 189–210, and Alborn Reference Alborn1998, pp. 257–60. It stretched from Western Europe to its former colonies, coalescing into “managerial capitalism” in the US by the early twentieth century. Alfred Chandler has shown, in turn, that the formation of salaried corporate management in the US during the early twentieth century had been closely linked to the consistent inflow of British and Scottish accounting skills as from the 1880s. See Chandler Reference Chandler1977, pp. 464–65.

46 Feuerwerker Reference Feuerwerker1958, pp. 16–28; Kirby Reference Kirby1995; Faure Reference Faure2006; see also Goetzmann and Köll Reference Goetzmann and Köll2004, pp. 13–19. Studies documenting closely-related attributes of the Chinese early modern economy are wide ranging and on the rise. These include articles on deliberate opaqueness in Chinese accounting practices to avoid State interference see, e.g., Gardella Reference Gardella1992; or on the massive flight of Chinese private capital to safe havens in the treaty-ports see, e.g., Ma Reference Ma2004.

References

REFERENCES

Alborn 1998 Alborn, Timothy L.Conceiving Companies: Joint-Stock Politics in Victorian England. London: Routledge, 1998.Google Scholar
Ash 1976 Ash, Robert. Land Tenure in Pre-Revolutionary China: Kiangsu Province in the 1920s and 1930s [Research Notes and Studies No. 1]. London: University of London, School of Oriental and African Studies, Contemporary China Institute, 1976.Google Scholar
Balazs 1964 Balazs, Etienne. Chinese Civilization and Bureaucracy. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1964.Google Scholar
Bowen and Rose 1998 Bowen, J.Ray and David C. Rose. “On the Absence of Privately Owned, Publicly Traded Corporations in China: The Kirby Puzzle.” Journal of Asian Studies 57:2 (1998), pp. 442–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandt 1989 Brandt, Loren. Commercialization and Agricultural Development: Central and Eastern China, 1870–1937. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Brandt 2000 Brandt, Loren. “Reflections on China's Late Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Century.” In Reappraising Republican China, ed. Wakeman, Frederic and Edmonds, Richard L.. New York: Oxford University Press, 2000, pp. 2854.Google Scholar
Broadberry and Gupta 2006 Broadberry, Stephen and Gupta, Bishnupriya. “The Early Modern Great Divergence: Wages, Prices and Economic Development in Europe and Asia, 1500–1800.” Economic History Review 59:1 (2006), pp. 231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron 1967 Cameron, Rondo. “England, 1750–1844.” In Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialization: A Study in Comparative Economic History, ed. Crisp, Olga, Patrick, Hugh T. and Tilly, Richard. New York: Oxford University Press, 1967, pp. 1559.Google Scholar
Carlos and Nicholas 1988 Carlos, Ann M. and Nicholas, Stephen. “‘Giants of an Earlier Capitalism’: The Chartered Trading Companies as Modern Multinationals.” Business History Review 62 (1988), pp. 398419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakepaichayon 1982 Chakepaichayon, Vichian. Meiji shoki no kaisha kigyō (2) – 81 sha no teikan bunseki 明治初期の会社企業 (2) – 81 社の定款分析 [Joint-Stock Companies in the Early Meiji Era (2): An Analysis of 81 Articles of Corporations]. Ōsaka daigaku keizaigaku 32:1 (1982), pp. 6687.Google Scholar
Chan 1977 Chan, Wellington K. K.Merchants, Mandarins, and Modern Enterprise in Late Ch'ing China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Chandler 1977 Chandler, Alfred D.The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Chang 1962 Chang, Chung-li. The Income of the Chinese Gentry. Seattle: University of Washington Press, 1962.Google Scholar
Davis and North 1971 Davis, Lance E. and North, Douglass C.. Institutional Change and American Economic Growth. London: Cambridge University Press, 1971.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Bary 1991 De Bary, William T.The Trouble with Confucianism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1991.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Vries 1976 De Vries, Jan. Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Elvin 1973 Elvin, Mark. The Pattern of the Chinese Past. London: Eyre Methuen, 1973.Google Scholar
Elvin 1981 Elvin, Mark. “Making Progress Pay – a Basic Problem in China's Early Economic Modernization.” In Symposium on the History of the Republic of China, vol. 3 (Northern Expedition and Period of Political Tutelage). Taipei, Taiwan: Compilation Committee of the Symposium on the History of the Republic of China, pp. 254–86.Google Scholar
Elvin 2001 Elvin, Mark. Book Review. China Quarterly 167 (2001), pp. 754–58.Google Scholar
Elvin 2004 Elvin, Mark. “Some Reflections on the Use of ‘Styles of Scientific Thinking’ to Disaggregate and Sharpen Comparisons Between China and Europe from Song to Mid-Qing Times (960–1850 CE).” History of Technology 25 (2004), pp. 53103.Google Scholar
Esherick 1991 Esherick, Joseph. Book Review. Journal of Economic History 51:2 (1991), pp. 501–03.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faure 2006 Faure, David. China and Capitalism: A History Business Enterprise in Modern China. Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Fox 1994 Fox, Josephine J.Access to Work in Republican China: Technology, Patronage and Industrial Conflict. Unpublished PhD dissertation. Australian National University.Google Scholar
Frank 1998 Frank, Andre Gunder. ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feuerwerker 1958 Feuerwerker, Albert. China's Early Industrialization: Sheng Hsuan-huai (1844–1916) and the Mandarin Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardella 1992 Gardella, Robert. “Squaring Accounts: Commercial Bookkeeping Methods and Capitalist Rationalism in Late Qing and Republican China.” Journal of Asian Studies 51:2 (1992), pp. 317–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschenkron 1966 Gerschenkron, Alexander. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: a Book of Essays. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1966.Google Scholar
Goetzmann and Köll 2004 Goetzmann, William N., and Köll, Elisabeth. “The History of Corporate Ownership in China: State Patronage, Company Legislation, and the Issue of Control.” Yale International Centre for Finance Working Paper no. 4–29.Google Scholar
Goldstone 1996 Goldstone, Jack A.Gender, Work and Culture: Why the Industrial Revolution Came Early to England but Late to China.” Sociological Perspectives 39:1 (1996), pp. 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstone 2002 Goldstone, Jack A.Efflorescences and Economic Growth in World History: Rethinking ‘The Rise of the West’ and the Industrial Revolution.” Journal of World History 13:2 (2002), pp. 323–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif 2005 Greif, Avner. “Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade.” In Handbook of New Institutional Economics, ed. Ménard, Claude and Shirley, Mary M.. New York: Springer, 2005, pp. 727–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobson 2004 Hobson, John M.The Eastern Origins of Western Civilisation. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horesh 2007 Horesh, Niv. “The Bund and Beyond: Rethinking the Sino-Foreign Financial Grid in Prewar Shanghai.” The China Review 7:1 (2007), pp. 126.Google Scholar
Hsiao 1974 Hsiao, Liang-lin. China's Foreign Trade Statistics, 18641949. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1974.Google Scholar
Huang 1990 Huang, Philip C.The Peasant Family and Rural Development in the Yangzi Delta, 1350–1988. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isett 2007 Isett, Christopher M.State, Peasant, and Merchant in Qing Manchuria, 1644–1862. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2007.Google Scholar
Ishii 2007 Ishii, Kanji 石井寛治. Keizai hatten to ryōgaeshō kin'yū 経済発展と両替商金融 [Economic Development and Finance of Moneychangers]. Tokyo: Yūhikaku, 2007.Google Scholar
Kirby 1995 Kirby, William C.China Unincorporated: Company Law and Business Enterprise in Twentieth-Century China.” Journal of Asian Studies 54:1 (1995), pp. 4363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiser and Tong 1992 Kiser, Edgar and Xiaoxi, Tong. “Determinants of the Amount and Type of Corruption in State Fiscal Bureaucracies: an Analysis of Late Imperial China.” Comparative Political Studies 25:3 (1992), pp. 300–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuroda 2006 Kuroda, Akinobu. “Too Commercialised to Synchronise Currencies: Monetary Peasant Economy in Late Imperial China in Comparison with Contemporary Japan.” Proceedings of the XIV International Economic History Congress. Helsinki 2006. Available for download at http://www.helsinki.fi/iehc2006/papers3/Kuroda.pdf (accessed 6 October 2008).Google Scholar
Landes 2003 Landes, David S.Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present [new edition]. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2003.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li 1998 Li, Bozhong. Agricultural Development in Jiangnan, 1620–1850. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li 2007 Li, Lillian M.Fighting Famine in North China: State, Market, and Environmental Decline, 1690s–1990s. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lippit 1978 Lippit, Victor D.The Development of Underdevelopment in China.” Modern China 4:3 (1978), pp. 251328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little 1992 Little, Daniel. Book Review. Economic Development and Cultural Change 40:2 (1992), pp. 425–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ma 2004 Ma, Debin. “Growth, Institutions and Knowledge: a Review and Reflection on the Historiography of Eighteenth–Twentieth Century China.” Australian Economic History Review 44:3 (2004), pp. 259–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ma 2008 Ma, Debin. “Economic Growth in the Lower Yangzi Region of China in 1911–1937: a Quantitative and Historical Analysis.” Journal of Economic History 68:2 (2008), pp. 355–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michie 1999 Michie, Ranald C.The London Stock Exchange: a History. New York: Oxford University Press, 1999.Google Scholar
Minami 1994 Minami, Ryoshin. The Economic Development of China: a Comparison with the Japanese Experience. London: Macmillan, 1994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchener and Ohnuki 2008 Mitchener, Kris J. and Ohnuki, Mari. “Institutions, Competition, and Capital Market Integration in Japan.” NBER Working Paper 14090.Google Scholar
Miwa and Ramseyer 2002 Miwa, Yoshiro and Ramseyer, J. Mark. “Banks and Economic Growth: Implications from Japanese History.” Journal of Law and Economics 45 (2002), pp. 127–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr 1976 Mokyr, Joel. Industrialization in the Low Countries, 1795–1850. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Morck and Nakamura 2005 Morck, Randall K. and Nakamura, Masao. “A Frog in a Well Knows Nothing of the Ocean: A History of Corporate Ownership in Japan.” In A History of Corporate Governance Around the World: Family Business Groups to Professional Managers, ed. Morck, Randall K.. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2005, pp. 367465.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mosk 2001 Mosk, Carl. Japanese Industrial History: Technology, Urbanization, and Economic Growth. New York: M. E. Sharpe, 2001.Google Scholar
Myers 1991 Myers, Ramon H.How Did the Modern Chinese Economy Develop? A Review Article.” Journal of Asian Studies 50:3 (1991), pp. 604–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nobutaka 1954 Nobutaka, Ike. “The Pattern of Railway Development in Japan.” The Far Eastern Quarterly 14:1 (1954), pp. 217–29.Google Scholar
Noda 1980 Noda, Masaho 野田正穂. Nihon shōken shijō seiritsu 日本証券市場成立史 [History of the Japanese Securities Markets]. Tokyo: Yūhikaku, 1980.Google Scholar
North 1973 North, Douglass C. and Thomas, Robert. The Rise of the Western World: a New Economic History. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1973.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oi and Waldre 1999 Oi, Jean C. and Waldre, Andrew G., eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perdue 1987 Perdue, Peter C.Exhausting the Earth: State and Peasant in Hunan, 1500–1850. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Perkins 1969 Perkins, Dwight H.Agricultural Development in China. Chicago: Aldine, 1969.Google Scholar
Pomeranz 1993 Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Making of a Hinterland: State, Society, and Economy in Inland North China, 1853–1937. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pomeranz 2000 Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: Europe, China and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rajan and Zingales 2003 Rajan, Raghuram G. and Zingales, Luigi. “The Great Reversals: The Politics of Financial Development in the Twentieth Century.” Journal of Financial Economics 69:1 (2003), pp. 550.Google Scholar
Rawski 1989 Rawski, Thomas G.Economic Growth in Prewar China. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Riskin 1978 Riskin, Carl. “The Symposium on China's Economic History: Discussion and Comments.” Modern China 4:3 (1978), pp. 359–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg and Birdzell, Jr., 1985 Rosenberg, Nathan and Birdzell, L. E. Jr.How the West Grew Rich: the Economic Transformation of the Industrial World. New York: Basic Books, 1985.Google Scholar
Rowe 1984 Rowe, William T.Hankow: Commerce and Society in a Chinese City, 1796–1889. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Rozelle 1992 Rozelle, Scott. “Contemporary Reflections on Development in Republican China.” Republican China 18:1 (1992), pp. 122–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schran 1978 Schran, Peter. “China's Demographic Evolution 1850–1953 Reconsidered.” The China Quarterly 75 (1978), pp. 639–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott 1912 Scott, William R.The Constitution and Finance of English, Scottish and Irish Joint-Stock Companies to 1720 [3 vols.]. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1912.Google Scholar
Shiba 1968 Shiba, Yoshinobu. Sōdai shōgyōshi kenkyū 宋代商業史研究 [The Mercantile History of the Song Dynasty]. Tokyo: Kazama shobō, 1968.Google Scholar
Shiue 2002 Shiue, Carol H. 2002. “Transport Costs and the Geography of Arbitrage in Eighteenth-Century China.” American Economic Review 92:5 (2002), pp. 1406–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shiue and Keller 2004 Shiue, Carol H. and Keller, Wolfgang. “Markets in China and Europe on the Eve of the Industrial Revolution.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 10778, pp. 145.Google Scholar
Skinner 1993 Skinner, G. William. Marketing and Social Structure in Rural China. Ann Arbor, MI: Association for Asian Studies, 1993.Google Scholar
So 1986 So, Alvin Y.The South China Silk District: Local Historical Transformation and World-System Theory. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Sugihara 2007 Sugihara, Kaoru. “Labour-Intensive Industrialisation in Global History.” Australian Economic History Review 47:2 (2007), pp. 121–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suzuki et al. 2005 Suzuki, Tsuneo 鈴木恒夫, Yoichi, Kobayakawa 小早川洋一 and Kazuo, Wada 和田一夫. Meiji 31 nenji ni okeru menshi bōseki kaisha kabunushi meibo no bunseki 明治 31 年時における綿糸紡績会社株主名簿の分析 [An Analysis of Shareholders' Lists for 60 Cotton Spinning Companies in 1898]. University of Tokyo, Centre for International Research on the Japanese Economy. Discussion Paper J-129.Google Scholar
Taylor 2006 Taylor, James. Creating Capitalism: Joint-Stock Enterprise in British Politics and Culture, 1800–1870. Rochester, NY: Royal Historical Society/Boydell Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Thomas 2001 Thomas, W. A.Western Capitalism in China: a History of the Shanghai Stock Exchange. Aldershot, UK: Ashgate, 2001.Google Scholar
Tsurumi 2002 Tsurumi, Masayoshi 靎見誠良. “Kindai no kahei shin'yō” 近代の貨幣信用 [Early Modern Currency and Credit]. In Ryūtsū keizaishi 流通経済史 [History of Circulating Currencies and Goods], ed. Eiji, Sakurai 桜井英治 and Satoru, Nakanishi 中西聡. Tokyo: Yamakawa, 2002, pp. 470513.Google Scholar
Tortella 2000 Tortella, Gabriel. The Development of Modern Spain: An Economic History of the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. Trans. from the Spanish by Herr, Valerie J.. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Van der Eng 2004 Van der Eng, Pierre. “Economic History of Asia: Comparative Perspectives.” Australian Economic History Review 44:3 (2004), pp. 215–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vries 2003 Vries, Peer. “Via Peking Back to Manchester: Britain, the Industrial Revolution, and China.” Studies in Overseas History 4 (2003), pp. 1109.Google Scholar
Wagel 1980 Wagel, Srinivas R.Finance in China. New York: Garland [1914], Reprint 1980.Google Scholar
Weber 1951 Weber, Max. The Religion of China: Confucianism and Taoism. Trans. from the German by Gert, Hans H.. New York: Macmillan [1922], 1951.Google Scholar
Wiens 1992 Wiens, Thomas B.Trends in the Late Qing and Republican Rural Economy: Reality or Illusion?” Republican China 18:1 (1992), pp. 6376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittfogel 1957 Wittfogel, Karl August. Oriental Despotism: a Comparative Study of Total Power. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1957.Google Scholar
Wong 1997 Wong, R. Bin. China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1997.Google Scholar
Wright 2000 Wright, Tim. “Distant Thunder: The Regional Economies of Southwest China and the Impact of the Great Depression.” Modern Asian Studies 34:3 (2000), pp. 697738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zelin 1988 Zelin, Madeleine. “Capital Accumulation and Investment Strategies in Early Modern China: the Case of the Furong Salt Yard.” Late Imperial China 9:1 (1988), pp. 79122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zelin 1998 Zelin, Madeleine. “Critique of Scholarship on Chinese Business in the People's Republic of China and Taiwan.” Chinese Studies in History 31:3–4 (1998), pp. 95105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar