Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-s22k5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T07:21:04.934Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Capitalising on the Irish land question: land reform and state banking in Ireland, 1891–1938

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 March 2016

Nathan Foley-Fisher
Affiliation:
Federal Reserve Board, Washington, DC
Eoin McLaughlin*
Affiliation:
University of St Andrews
*
E. McLaughlin, corresponding author: Leverhulme Early Career Fellow, Department of Geography & Sustainable Development, University of St Andrews, North Street, St Andrews, ky16 9al, Fife, Scotland, UK; email: eoin.mclaughlin@st-andrews.ac.uk.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Land reform and its financial arrangements are central elements of modern Irish history. Yet to date, the financial mechanisms underpinning Irish land reform have been overlooked. The article outlines the mechanisms of land reform in Ireland and the importance of land bonds to the process. Advances worth over £127 million were made to tenant farmers to purchase their holdings. These schemes enabled the transfer of over three-quarters of land on the island of Ireland. The article introduces a new database on Irish land bonds listed on the Dublin Stock Exchange from 1891 to 1938. It illustrates the nature of these bonds and presents data on their size, liquidity and market returns. The article finds a high level of state banking in Ireland: large issues of land bonds were held by state-owned savings banks.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © European Association for Banking and Financial History e.V. 2016 

Land reform - the reallocation of property rights and the redistribution of land – is a process that almost all countries have undertaken, in some form or other, during their development (Federico Reference Federico2005). Indeed, land reform continues to be a central component in the World Bank's prescribed policies for developing countries.Footnote 1 Moreover, recent empirical and theoretical studies suggest that reductions in land inequality (i.e. land reform) lead to higher income growth, reductions in poverty and growth in human capital (Besley and Burgess Reference Besley and Burgess2000; Deininger and Squire Reference Deininger and Squire1998; Griffin, Khan and Ickowitz Reference Griffin, Khan and Ickowitz2002; Deininger, Jin and Nagarajan Reference Deininger, Jin and Nagarajan2009; Galor, Moav and Vollrath Reference Galor, Moav and Vollrath2009; Gersback and Siemers Reference Gersback and Siemers2010; Lipton Reference Lipton2009; Vollrath Reference Vollrath2007). However, regardless of the desired outcome, there is no broad consensus on the design for land reform policies.Footnote 2 The study of successful examples of land reform programmes can help answer modern economic and political questions, such as what policy design developing countries should adopt when implementing land reform and what features of the economy help to facilitate the implementation.Footnote 3 For example, Griffin et al. (2002, pp. 309, 321) argue that successful examples of land reform in South East Asia represented a transfer of land ownership title from landlords to cultivating tenants, not landless labourers, but that such examples require large-scale financial investment: in the case of Ireland we find evidence of both.

In this article, we contribute to the debate on the design of land reform by studying the policies adopted towards Ireland at the end of the nineteenth century.Footnote 4 We provide a comprehensive background to explain how state-funded land purchase came to be seen as a ‘final settlement’ to the long-running ‘land war’ and rural unrest in Ireland (Gailey Reference Gailey1987). In particular, we describe the policy features that made the implementation of Irish land reform successful in terms of achieving its goal of peasant-proprietorship.Footnote 5 In a series of policies adopted from 1891 to 1934, the governments of the day achieved the transfer of almost all land ownership from landlords to tenants. Moreover, the series of land reform policies were adopted and implemented with little social or political disruption, although it should be noted that this was a period of significant social and political upheaval.

Land reform was successful in Ireland primarily because the state created a source of credit to purchase land at ‘market’ prices, a feature of land reform that is difficult to replicate in other regions without adequate financial support mechanisms. Central to the success of Ireland's land reform was the use of specifically designed government-guaranteed financial instruments - land bonds. Through these bonds, successive Acts of parliaments (UK, Irish Free State and Northern Ireland) enabled tenant farmers to purchase land from landlords.Footnote 6 Although Ireland was one of the first countries to see government bonds used to implement land reform, bonds were subsequently used in various countries.Footnote 7 However, not all countries had equivalent degrees of success (e.g. King Reference King1977). Why, then, was their use in Ireland so successful?

To further our understanding of land bonds, we introduce a database of Irish land bond prices recorded daily on the Dublin Stock Exchange from 1892, when land bonds were first issued, to 1938, when the Anglo-Irish trade agreement was signed. Our database, presented in Appendix B, is the first systematic effort to collect land bond prices. It fills important lacunas in the understanding of the mechanics of Irish land reform and in the knowledge of long-run Irish interest rates.Footnote 8 More generally, it contributes to the wider literature on returns to government bonds in the early twentieth century (Siegal Reference Siegal1992; Dimon et al. Reference Dimon, Marsh and Staunton2000; Ilmanen Reference Ilmanen2003; Obstfeld and Taylor Reference Obstfeld and Taylor2004; Homer and Sylla Reference Homer and Sylla2005; Ferguson Reference Ferguson2006, Reference Ferguson2008).

We outline the origin of land bonds, their legal structure, where they were traded and who owned them. We argue that a key element to the Irish story is the presence of state banking, whereby the state actively provides financial assistance to a sector adversely affected by globalisation (Verdier Reference Verdier2000). We show that the largest holders of Irish land bonds were institutional state-owned investors, in particular the Post Office Savings Bank that, by 1913, held 44 per cent of land bonds issues. Furthermore, land bonds were a growing share of POSB assets, increasing from almost nothing to 20 per cent of assets between 1898 and 1913.

The rest of our article is structured as follows: Section i describes the development of land purchase schemes in Ireland; Section ii outlines data on land bonds derived from records of the Dublin Stock Exchange; the concept of state banking is discussed in Section iii. Section iv concludes.

I

Government land policy in Ireland evolved significantly during the late nineteenth century in an effort to address the problems associated with the land ownership structure, at that time a central issue in politics and political economy known as the ‘Irish Land Question’.Footnote 9 First, innovations to state land policy aimed to redistribute agricultural income from landlords to tenants. Under the 1881 Land Act the state became an arguably tenant-biased arbitrator in landlord–tenant contracts and universally reduced rents paid by tenants. Second, state land policy shifted to the provision of loans to tenants to purchase their holdings and, from 1870 onwards, the state played an active role as a mortgage provider to the agricultural sector of the Irish economy. To finance these loans, the government guaranteed land bonds that were tradeable in several markets.

The integration of international factor markets in the late nineteenth century is an important contextual element for understanding these policy innovations (O'Rourke and Williamson Reference O'Rourke and Williamson1999). Falling agricultural prices coupled with rising real wages eroded landlord economic and political power. Ireland, as part of the UK, adhered to free trade principles throughout this period and this, together with changing market conditions, made the sale of land increasingly attractive to landlords.Footnote 10

In this section, we provide details on the land purchase schemes, including their size, operation and the various obligations imposed on tenant purchasers. We also set out the contemporaneous private options for land purchase available to prospective Irish tenant farmers as important context to our explanation of the demand for state-sponsored land purchase schemes.

A number of Acts were passed between 1869 and 1934 which enabled tenants to purchase their holdings in Ireland.Footnote 11 In total, as shown in Table 1, these Acts led to advances worth over £127 million to purchase almost 15 million acres on 433,395 holdings in the South and North of Ireland.Footnote 12 However, the amounts advanced varied over the different schemes, and the advances per acre and per holding generally declined over the schemes. By far the largest scheme related to the Land Act of 1903, with over twice as much advanced as the next largest scheme. More generally, pre-partition Land Acts accounted for 77 per cent of the funds advanced on land purchases in Ireland. Of the pre-1920 Acts, the 1903 Act was the most significant with 74 per cent of total funds advanced.

Table 1. Land purchase schemes 1869–1923: advances, acreage and holdings

Note: Excludes all vendor bonuses, advances made under the Labourers (Ireland) Acts, 1906–14, and the Irish Church Act, 1869. Also excludes land improvement investments made by the Land Commission and CDB.

Source: Commission of Inquiry into Banking, Currency and Credit 1938 and authors' calculations.

From 1881 onwards the state land purchase schemes were overseen by the Land Commission.Footnote 13 Initially all land purchase arrangements were negotiated freely between landlords and tenants, with state bodies providing the funds to prospective tenant purchasers. However, the 1903 Land Act introduced an element of compulsion by giving the state the power to force tenants to purchase land.Footnote 14 Subsequent legislation introduced in 1907 compulsory purchase powers for the agencies of state-funded land purchase whereby they had powers to compel landlords to sell their land: this was done for the explicit purpose of transferring land ownership. The introduction of compulsory purchase of land under the Labourers Act and the Evicted Tenants Act was extended to wider land purchase policy in 1909 by the Land Law Act (Kolbert and O’Brien Reference Kolbert and O'Brien1975).Footnote 15

For tenants, the obligations of the schemes varied considerably and are discussed in detail below. Figure 1 is a schema of how land purchase schemes functioned. First, a state body, the Land Commission, acted as an intermediary between tenant farmers and landlords. It sanctioned loans to tenants and paid vendors in either cash or bonds. If cash was paid, the Treasury/Commission for the Reduction of the National Debt issued bonds and raised money from their sale on the stock market. Likewise, if vendors received payment in bonds, they could either keep the bonds and receive dividends or sell them on the market. In general, tenant farmers repaid their loans with regular mortgage payment ‘annuities’ comprising interest and principal repayments to the administrative body responsible for collection (Land Commission).Footnote 16 These annuities were collected into a sinking fund that was used to pay dividends twice yearly and retire some of the outstanding bonds at the discretion of the government.Footnote 17 In the event of a default, a guarantee mechanism was activated whereby annuity payments were made by the guarantee fund, essentially local taxation, and this was intended to cover both interest and annuity cost.

Figure 1. Obligations and liabilities associated with land bonds

Table 2 summarizes the specific tenant obligations associated with each Land Act. Over the period 1870 to 1909, the state gradually increased the portion of the mortgage it was willing to lend from 66 to 100 per cent. Initially, under the 1869 to 1881 Acts, the state did not finance the entire purchase price, and it was the tenant's responsibility to raise the residual capital. However, the evidence suggests that only the wealthier tenants were able to take advantage of this facility. From 1885 onwards, government support of land purchase was more prominent, reflected by the increase in the percentage of the mortgage which the state advanced to tenants. Government bodies from 1885 onwards were issuing loans worth 100 per cent of the purchase price of a given holding. This is significant as it no longer excluded tenants who had insufficient capital, and the state became the primary mortgagee on the land.Footnote 18

Table 2. Initial land purchase contracts for tenants, 1869–1933

a Refers to the percentage of the agreed purchase price which the state would advance under the Act.

b Loan terms (annuity repayment) estimated by contemporaries based on the expected performance of sinking funds.

c 64 half-yearly repayments.

d The 1896 Land Act introduced the concept of decadal reductions on the repayment of annuities.

e Estimated by BPP (1908b) as the time it takes a sinking fund to reach £100 stock.

f Estimated following the methodology outlined by BPP (1908b) as the time it takes a 5 shilling (£0.25) sinking fund, accumulating at rate of 4.50 per cent, to reach £100 stock.

g Estimated following the methodology outlined by BPP (1908b) as the time it takes a 5 shilling (£0.25) sinking fund, accumulating at rate of 4.00 per cent, to reach £100 stock.

Source: Various Land Acts, Irish Land Purchase Finance Report 1908 and authors' calculations.

The higher coverage of the purchase price by the state was coupled with longer loan terms. Initial mortgage loan terms were roughly half those under later Land Acts. The Land Acts from 1903 onwards did not specify a definite term for a loan but instead stated that ‘the purchase annuity shall be paid until the whole of the advance, in respect of which it is payable, is ascertained in manner prescribed by the Treasury to have been repaid’.Footnote 19 In the case of the Free State Acts the Minister for Finance decided ‘the manner and the times’ at which the loan would amortise. In all cases the amortisation of loans was based upon the performance of the sinking fund. The 1903 and 1909 Land Acts issued loans with terms of 68.5 and 66 years. Indeed, it is very likely that the loan term would have been greater than the borrower's life expectancy. Thus, the average tenant purchaser with a mortgage term of 66 or 68.5 years would have bequeathed both the land (farm) and the loan to the next generation.Footnote 20 The loans’ long duration allowed purchasers to amortise the significant principal (see below) through the return to land.

Crucially, the terms were also attractive to vendors (landlords). Loans were set in terms of the number of ‘years purchase’,Footnote 21 essentially the capitalised value of rents.Footnote 22 Under the 1903 Land Act this averaged 22.52 years (BPP 1921b). Thus, on average, landlords received lump sums totalling 22.5 years of rental income whilst farmers paid this sum over 68.5 years. Further incentives for landlords to sell came initially in the form of high bond prices in the late 1890s (see Appendix B) and, when bond prices fell, a £12 million ‘bonus’ distributed amongst all vendors was included in the 1903 Act. In addition, landlords could also avail themselves of the concessional loans on offer. A crucial factor from the vendors’ (landlords’) perspective was that their income had already been cut by rental reductions, thus making landlords more amenable to sell their land. With landlords willing to sell, the only willing purchasers were the existing tenants (Hooker Reference Hooker1938, pp. 50, 67).

As the intermediary between the tenant purchasers and financial markets, the government used its reputation to borrow capital on behalf of the tenant purchasers on favourable terms. The government could offer competitive rates to borrowers and still earn a spread on the cost of capital (the difference between columns 4 and 5 in Table 2). Between 1869 and 1896 land purchase annuities were around 4.5 per cent, competitive with the best available market rates. Some evidence on private mortgages in the early twentieth century suggests that rates charged for mortgages were between 4 and 10 per cent (BPP 1914, paragraph 823). Moreover, the differential between the rates paid and prevailing long-term interest rates decreased under the various Acts. As long-term interest rates increased during the war, the relatively low interest rates paid by those purchasing under the 1903 and 1909 Acts became even more attractive because their fixed rates were well-below market rates.

The loan contracts made no allowance for future price movements. However, as the land purchase contracts were designed, inflation was a boon to farmers whereas prolonged deflation was not. Moreover, the long loan terms created the possibility of embedded risk, as annuities were set without regard to future price trends, which could be risky to the scheme if it adversely affected farmers. Importantly, from the perspective of the governments presiding over the 1903/1909 Acts, these policies had an immediate benefit even if they may have led to future political difficulties. Table 3 attempts to address this by calculating decade average real annuities. Agricultural prices in Ireland were strongly influenced by international market conditions and this is reflected in the real annuity rates. A further difficulty, from the farmers' perspective, turned out to be the adherence to the gold standard during the era of deflation from 1870 to 1896. The abandonment of the gold standard during World War I coupled with increased demand led to greater inflation which significantly reduced annuity commitments. However, post-war deflation, worsened by Britain's resumption of gold at parity in 1925, exacerbated rural problems and real annuities were relatively high during the period 1923–31. The final row in Table 3 reflects the halving of the annuity payment in 1932, discussed below, rather than the slight increase in average prices over the same period.

Table 3. Real and nominal annuities, decade averages

Note: post 1933 included halved annuities.

Sources: Table 2; Kennedy and Solar (Reference Kennedy and Solar2007); Nunan (Reference Nunan1987).

The 1903 Land Act stated that ‘every advance shall be repaid’ and repayment was supposed to be in accordance with the terms outlined in Table 2.Footnote 23 Published from 1911 onwards, Land Commission reports contain annual information on repayments and arrears of loans (see Table 4). For the nine years from 1911–12 to 1919–20, arrears were quite low. This is perhaps surprising, given the nationalist agitation in rural areas, but it lends support to the view that the 1910s were a boom time for Irish farmers due to high prices during World War I. Comparable information for the 1920s is available for a ten-year period from 1928–9 through to 1938–9. Arrears increased significantly, albeit from a very low base, averaging 11 per cent for the pre-independence Acts. However, tenant purchasers in the Irish Free State did not have to fully meet their debt obligations, as the terms of repayment were ‘fundamentally altered’ as a consequence of two events (IPP 1934). First, in 1932, Fianna Fáil carried out its electoral pledge to withhold annuity payments from the British government. Second, the 1933 Land Act permanently reduced all annuity payments by 50 per cent and cleared arrears of defaulting purchasers on the grounds that tenant purchasers were overburdened by their debt.Footnote 24 Despite the halving of annuities, arrears continued to be relatively higher in the 1930s than they had been previously, perhaps a reflection of the Anglo-Irish ‘economic war’ whereby the British government imposed tariffs on Irish produce, primarily livestock, in retaliation for the default on the annuity repayments.

Table 4. Arrears as a share of instalments due (%)

Notes: 1912–12 to 1919–20 are figures for the island of Ireland, 1927–8 to 1938–9 are figures for the Irish Free State.

Sources: Land Commission reports (Irish Free State), 1910–20 and 1927–8 to 1938–9.

The economic effect of cutting annuity payments was to transfer the loan repayment from Irish landowners to the UK taxpayer. The evidence above suggests that the ex-post burden on Irish landowners from repaying the loans derived from the price at which the land was transacted. But this does not mean that the land was over-priced relative to the expected present discounted value of the returns at the time the land was purchased. It is possible that misperceptions of future returns contributed to an ex-post over-pricing of land during the reform. But, without better data on rental rates and the expectations of purchasers about the returns to agricultural productivity, it is not clear whether the land was over-priced contemporaneously.

Without state intervention there would have been no alternative means to purchase land on such a scale for the majority of borrowers. The lending models of contemporary financial institutions, namely Loan Fund Societies, Joint Stock Banks (JSBs) and Raiffeisen (agricultural credit) societies, were based on personal security, with only limited terms available to tenant farmers due to the illiquidity of landed security and the risk of death.Footnote 25 Private individuals who typically used solicitors as intermediaries did offer mortgages, but their availability was not widespread (BPP 1914, paragraph 883). Moreover, evidence from the 1914 report on agricultural credit suggests that only the wealthier farms had access to such mortgages. Curtis (Reference Curtis1980) acknowledges that landlords with large and wealthy estates could easily obtain lines of credit secured by land in the period before 1877, as land was deemed to have been the ‘soundest possible investments’.Footnote 26

As the majority of farms in Ireland were very small, they would not have been able to access private mortgage funding to purchase land. And if they were able to access private funding, the terms would not have been as generous as those of the state.Footnote 27 The 1914 report on agricultural credit compared the situation in Ireland with that on the Continent where mortgaging of smallholdings was more prevalent (BPP 1914, pp. 334–8). Moreover, cooperative building societies were not found in provincial towns in Ireland, although some building societies, most notably the Irish Civil Service Building Society, made loans throughout the island (McLaughlin Reference McLaughlin2013). Furthermore, savings banks did not issue loans and cooperative banks did not make long-term mortgages as they did on the Continent (Colvin and McLaughlin Reference Colvin and McLaughlin2014; McLaughlin Reference McLaughlin2014).

JSBs in Ireland were reluctant to make long-term loans on mortgage security. This was due to a number of complications, including the risk associated with long-term lending, illiquidity of landed assets, and the cost of determining property rights.Footnote 28 Illiquidity of loans backed by land was common at the time, since there was no ability to securitise such loans. This was a challenge to risk management, given the banks’ liability structure and the absence of a central bank with lender of last resort powers.Footnote 29 There was also the problem of sale of land in the event of default, and in Ireland this was a significant deterrent to the entry of the JSBs in the mortgage market. This became obvious in the 1926 banking commission as evidence was shown that the sale of foreclosed land was difficult due to social pressure on buyers (IPP 1926–7, pp. 21–2). Therefore, mortgage assets were practically worthless if a borrower defaulted on loan repayments.

State entry into the mortgage market was a novel approach to solving the lack of credit available to would-be tenant purchasers. Also, the fact that the state offered 100 per cent loan to value made the schemes accessible to all borrowers regardless of credit status.Footnote 30 State mortgage loans seem to have been based on a policy of social entitlement, disregarding the commercial considerations that caused private lenders to hesitate. Figure 2 illustrates the effectiveness of government intervention in the land market. In 1906 only a small share of farmers were owners of their land, but by 1917 a far larger share of Irish farmers were owner-occupiers. In the absence of private alternatives to the attractive terms and accessibility offered by the land purchase schemes, it is unsurprising that there was keen interest from prospective tenant purchasers. Indeed, it appears that the appetite for the generous terms on offer under 1903 Land Act was underestimated, with the Land Commission understaffed and unable to deal with the demand. Initially there were not enough funds available to purchase holdings, which in turn created a backlog of cases; £5 million was made available per annum but demand exceeded this amount (Cosgrove Reference Cosgrove2008, p. 148).

Source: BPP (1908a, 1921a).

Figure 2. Landowners as a percentage of landholdings: 1906 and 1917

Nevertheless, despite their apparent appeal, some contemporary opinion seems to have been hesitant about borrowing funds from ‘London’, believing that a central government might not have been as easily influenced as a local landlord (Cosgrove Reference Cosgrove2008, pp. 162–3). However, it transpired that a democratically elected government could be influenced, as borrowers were also voters. Yet the extent of voter power determines the influence voters have on the elected bodies; the extent of influence of the Irish voters to revise their debt obligations and cancel arrears in a UK legislative assembly would not be the same as the case where the Irish electorate had their own assembly, dominated by Olsonian agrarian interest groups (Olson Reference Olson1982). The same cannot be said of landlords who would have been under no direct political pressure, vis-à-vis an electoral mandate, to reduce rents, although individual landlords may have been sympathetic to a tenant's plight and granted some respite. This is also a key distinction between a public and private lender; private lenders would not have any political obligations to alter loan repayments.Footnote 31 Loans could be renegotiated in order to minimise losses, but private lenders would not be as willing as the state to completely absolve debt obligations, especially on a grand scale.

II

Bonds issued under the Irish Land Acts were used specifically to finance land purchase in Ireland. They were distinct from other types of UK government debt, allowing scholars an insight into UK Treasury rationale regarding Ireland, the decision of landlords to sell, and also offer a perspective on the motives of traders and holders of these bonds.

The Irish land bonds distinct from Consols. For example, when the ‘Guaranteed £2:15s % stock’ was issued, the prospectus (3 January 1905) highlighted that the stock was ‘to be created under the Irish Land Act, 1903, 3 Edw VII, Ch. 37’.Footnote 32 Also clear from the prospectus was how these bonds were guaranteed: it was stated that the dividends were payable from the Irish Land Purchase Fund and, if that stream of income was insufficient, it would be paid out of the ‘Consolidated Fund of the United Kingdom’.

The fact that these bonds were so clearly identifiable with Ireland affected their performance. For example, a letter to the Postmaster General, written in 1904, suggested that although ‘it [Irish Land Stock] pays better than most of the Government securities. I am told by a Stock Broker that having the words ‘Irish Land’ causes a prejudice against it which must be strengthened by its being boycotted in the Postal Guide [1891 Land stock was not listed as an investment in the postal guide].’Footnote 33 A later broker also noted that ‘there always was a good deal of uncertainty in the mind of the public, and even on the Stock Exchange, as to the real value of the Irish land stocks, and no doubt the uncertainty is even greater in the case of Northern Ireland’.Footnote 34 The stock was even referred to derogatorily as ‘Bog Stock’ in Parliament.Footnote 35 By contrast, in evidence to the Free State banking commission in 1935, G. L. Kennedy, president of the Dublin Stock Exchange, stated that ‘the British Government guarantee of Land Bonds is always a big attraction’ (IPP 1938, evidence Q. 2995).

The following section discusses the technicalities of these bonds and introduce a new database of land bond prices derived from the Dublin Stock Exchange.

From 1891 to 1909, state purchases under the Land Acts were financed by the issue of government-guaranteed land bonds and were not financed out of UK Exchequer funds.Footnote 36 While the idea for transferring ownership, or creating leases-in-perpetuity, dates from Mill's (Reference Mill1848) discussion of the ‘means of abolishing Cottier tenancy’,Footnote 37 the practicalities of following this policy recommendation appeared later. John Edward Vernon, a governor of the Bank of Ireland, was one of the first people to suggest that the government raise money for land purchase through the issue of government-backed bonds. Vernon viewed the fact that there was a large amount of money held on deposit in the JSBs as evidence ‘that there is an element of wealth there which might be tapped and applied to the purposes of the Land Commission’. When Vernon was asked what he considered ‘the effect of bonds of that kind would be upon the general state of Ireland, if held by the people of that country?’ he suggested that it ‘would be very favourable to the stability of the government, and the peace and order of the country’. Vernon also suggested that the issuance of land bonds would restore order to the countryside as the bonds would ‘connect them with the primary security on which they would be charged, viz. the land itself, that is, the land sold to the occupiers’ (BPP 1882, Q. 4191–215).

The issue of guaranteed land bonds enabled funds to be raised to finance land purchase. The initial land bonds were issued with a coupon rate of 2¾ per cent,Footnote 38 increased to 3 per cent under the 1909 ActFootnote 39 and further increased to 4½ per cent under Land Acts in the Irish Free State and Northern Ireland in the 1920s and to 4 per cent under the 1934 Land Act in the Free State.Footnote 40 Under the 1891 and 1896 Acts, vendors (landlords) were paid only in government-guaranteed land stock.Footnote 41 Landlords could then sell these bonds in the market or retain the bonds and receive the bi-annual dividend on the stock,Footnote 42 whereas later Acts paid in cash and/or bonds.

The use of British credit to finance land reform in Ireland was not without reservations. The UK Treasury was reluctant to sanction the bond issues under the Irish Land Acts as they were extremely risky and because these terms, as set out in Table 2, ‘would never be dreamt of in dealings with any other loan body than the state’ (Gailey Reference Gailey1987, p. 84). Furthermore, the bonds issued to finance the 1903 Land Act came shortly after the floatation of the Transvaal loan following the Boer War and although the Treasury agreed to the principle of the 1903 Land Act they ‘did not wish to “scare” the City with the prospect of further borrowing by the state’ (Gailey Reference Gailey1987, p. 191, n. 191). The Treasury though was willing to underwrite the proposals because ‘if there is a really reasonable hope of peace, it will be worth some payment’ (Gailey Reference Gailey1987, pp. 191–2). However, the Treasury was later worried that the increased borrowing for the purposes of Irish land reform might in fact ‘undermine the credibility of the government in the City’ (Gailey Reference Gailey1987, p. 206).

This structure of financing land purchase by the issue of government-backed bonds was not self-sustaining in terms of tenant loan repayments alone. Consols traded below par after 1900, and each subsequent issue of land bonds was sold at a discount; the prospectus of the 1903 land bonds issued in 1905 stated that the minimum sale price was ‘£88:10s’.Footnote 43 Evidence from the Runciman report in 1908 suggests that there was a significant divergence between the prices of Consols and guaranteed land stock (BPP 1908b). This seems to have been caused by the amount of land stock issued between 1903 and 1908, and the fact that there were no new Consol issues after 1902 (BPP 1908c, p. 11). This meant that there was a shortfall in the finances which the Runciman report estimated would be around £20 million over the 68.5 years of the 1903 Act, on the assumption that the market prices were constant (BPP 1908c, p. 7). However, deficiencies in stock issues were to be met from the Irish development grant, probate duty grants and agricultural grants administered under the 1898 Local Government Act.Footnote 44 The fact that the programme was financially unsustainable effectively meant that the purchasers of land under the government land purchase schemes actually received their farms under concessional terms of state subsidy.

However, the lack of inherent sustainability in the programme should not have been a major concern for investors, since the nominal value of the land bonds was a small fraction of the British economy. Based on records from our dataset (discussed below), Figure 3 shows that the outstanding nominal value of British government guaranteed land bonds never rose above 4 per cent of UK GDP. By contrast, Figure 4 shows that at the time that Ireland gained independence, land bonds were worth about 40 per cent of estimated Irish GDP.Footnote 45 Moreover, the newly formed state continued to issue land bonds, with the outstanding nominal amount peaking almost 60 per cent of GDP in the early 1930s, a considerable burden for any developing economy.

Source: Dublin Stock Exchange and authors' calculations (see text).

Figure 3. Nominal value of land bonds as a share of GDP

Source: Dublin Stock Exchange and authors’ calculations (see text).

Figure 4. Nominal value of all land bonds as a share of estimated Irish GDP

From the perspective of the government – UK and subsequently Irish Free State – the benefits of the land reform programmes were perceived to have been primarily political stability as they took place against the backdrop of ‘land war’ and revolution (Anglo-Irish war and subsequent civil war). The 1891–1909 Land Acts were seen as quelling rural agitation; in the case of the Free State the 1923 Land Act was seen as a way to restore order to the Irish countryside. In both instances, the state intervened out of necessity.

The source for our data is the daily records of the Dublin Stock Exchange.Footnote 46 We collected data from 1890 through to 1938, covering the first issuance of bonds under the 1891 Land Act through to the Anglo-Irish trade agreement. In particular, we obtained records of daily closing prices and amounts outstanding for all government-guaranteed debt traded on the Dublin Stock Exchange.Footnote 47 The exchange was open Monday–Friday (and Saturday in some years) excluding public holidays such as Easter and Christmas. The stock exchange was closed from August to December 1914, due to the war, and also briefly due to a financial crisis in 1931 (Thomas Reference Thomas1986, p. 68).Footnote 48

Although London was the pre-eminent financial trading centre of the time, we use Dublin Stock Exchange data because not all land bonds were traded in London (Thomas Reference Thomas1986, p. 170). That said, stock markets in London and Dublin were closely integrated during our period of study. The installation of a direct telegraph connection between Dublin and London in 1850 ensured information lagged at most one day, and the telephone was introduced in 1897.Footnote 49 Therefore, closing prices in Dublin should be reasonably close to those in London throughout our data.Footnote 50

Table 5 lists the securities recorded in our database by order of issuance date. In all, there are six land bonds, six bonds that we term ‘benchmark’ UK sovereign debt and four Irish Free State bonds. The second column in the table reports the coupon associated with each issue, using the ‘average’ coupon for the consolidated stock converted in 1903 from 2.75 per cent to 2.5 per cent.Footnote 51 The first four land bonds, including bonds issued by the Free State in the 1920s, carried British government guarantees, while the last two were issued under the Land Bond Acts of 1933 and 1934 without such a guarantee (BPP 1924, 1924–5a, 1924–5b, 1929–30, 1930–1).Footnote 52 In addition, the land bonds issued under the 1933 and 1934 Acts were the first not to be expressed in sterling but were instead expressed in Free State currency (IPP 1938, paragraph 40, p. 14).Footnote 53

Table 5. Dublin Stock Exchange: sovereign debt

Source: authors’ calculation.

The third and fourth columns in Table 5 report the time window in our database over which the bonds were priced on the Dublin Stock Exchange. The six land bonds remain in the daily record book until the end of 1938, implying coverage of the entire period. Similarly, the large issue of consolidated stock, the 2½ per cent stock, the 2¾ per cent stock and the four Irish Free State bonds cover most of our sample period, making the prices of these bonds useful as benchmark comparators for land bond price movements. The fifth column of the table reports the maximum recorded amount outstanding for each bond, illustrating the large size of the consolidated stock relative to all other bonds traded on the Dublin Stock Exchange. This column also shows how large the inherited burden of land bonds was relative to the size of new issuance for the Irish Free State.

Unfortunately, neither bond trade volumes nor bid-ask spreads are reported in the stock market records. However, since we have relatively high-frequency data, we can create a proxy liquidity measure, reported in the sixth column of the table, by calculating the fraction of days on which trading occurred when the bond was priced in the market. Although this proxy may be computed over subsamples (see Table 6) it cannot be used to infer anything about the liquidity of an issue at a point in time. According to this proxy, land bond liquidity on the Dublin Stock Exchange compared favourably with the majority of Exchequer bonds. In particular, the liquidity of the final British-guaranteed land bond appears on a par with that of the consolidated stock, consistent with the assessment of Thomas (Reference Thomas1986, p. 170) that the sterling guarantee combined with quotation on the London Stock Exchange made this bond ‘always a big attraction’ in the interwar period. As Consols are the longest living and have the largest amount outstanding in our data, it is not surprising that they are found to be highly liquid in our dataset. By contrast, the 2½ per cent and 2¾ per cent stocks are quite illiquid, even relative to the land bonds.

Table 6. Bond returns: summary statistics

Note: N is the number of observations, SD is the standard deviation and LM is the liquidity measure.

Source: authors’ calculations.

Figures 5 and 6 show on the same scale from 1890 until 1938 (i) the prices of land bonds and (ii) UK Consols and Exchequer bonds listed in Table 5. For clarification, these bond prices are shown on separate figures but aligned so that their general evolution can be compared.

Figure 5. Land bonds: last prices

Figure 6. Consols and Exchequer bonds: last prices

The broad movements in the prices of land bonds and UK Consols and Exchequer bonds are similar and are consistent with the major events of the time (Homer and Sylla Reference Homer and Sylla2005, pp. 438–50). Both series steadily decline from the middle of the final decade of the nineteenth century until the early 1920s, partly in response to the war, but mostly due to developments in fiscal and social policy. Prices remained low throughout the 1920s as the government strove to restore sterling's reputation as a strong currency. The sharp upward movement late in 1931 is also well known and attributable to the UK government's decision to abandon the gold standard and the conversion of the massive war loan in 1932 (Homer and Sylla Reference Homer and Sylla2005, p. 451).

Although the broad movements in the price series are similar, some of the more detailed activity in land bond prices is different from that of UK Consols and Exchequer bonds. First, there is more volatility in the land bond prices than in Consols and Exchequer bonds around the time of Irish partition and civil war (1921–3). Second, the movement in land bond prices appears more muted, in particular the large issues of 1903/9 land bonds and the 4.5 per cent land bonds. And, thirdly, while land bonds were at times viewed as unpopular, their prices towards the end of our data suggest that they had become more attractive even than Consols, despite the risk that the bonds might have been called for redemption (Thomas Reference Thomas1986, p. 170). To study this issue carefully, we need to account for individual bond characteristics, such as offered rate and duration, as well as market liquidity and volatility.

Summary statistics of bond returns, presented in Table 6, over the entire period and different subsamples help to clarify these observations.Footnote 54 For each bond, in addition to the number of observations and the average returns in each subsample, we report the standard deviation of returns as a measure of volatility during each period and our liquidity measure (the fraction of days on which trading took place). Average returns are consistently near-zero across bonds and subsamples, as is common in studies of daily returns (Brown and Warner Reference Brown and Warner1985).

During the early subsamples, Consols are by far the most liquid bond and the Exchequer bonds are traded only modestly. Land bonds were traded more frequently than Exchequer bonds and remained relatively liquid during World War I. Moreover, while the liquidity of Consols declined significantly after 1920, some land bonds were traded more frequently towards the end of the period. The analysis by sub-period confirms the overall finding that the 4.5 per cent land bonds were particularly popular during the interwar period. However, there was a decline in liquidity for the other three British government-guaranteed land bonds. This may in part reflect a migration of trading into markets that listed a full set of British securities and were more connected to London traders.Footnote 55

Although land bond returns and UK Consols and Exchequer bond returns display similar volatility over the entire sample, there is considerable variation across subsamples from World War I onwards. To explore this variation further, Figure 7 shows the standard deviation of the weighted average of these returns computed using a rolling window of three years (750 days) around each date on the horizontal axis.Footnote 56

Figure 7. Weighted average bond returns: volatility

According to Figure 7, land bonds and British government bonds experienced similar broad movements in return volatility throughout the sample. However, around the time of the outbreak of World War I, British government bonds became more volatile than land bonds. After appearing to converge during the early 1920s, the two series again diverged during the Great Depression and land bonds remained less volatile than British government bonds for the remainder the period. In addition, the volatility of land bonds remains elevated during the Irish war of independence while the volatility of British government bonds declines. These facts suggest that land bonds were reacting to Irish specific events, perhaps including developments in the value of collateral (Irish land) and the turbulent political events surrounding independence.

III

Verdier (Reference Verdier2000, p. 300), in his study of the rise and fall of state banking in OECD countries, finds that the supply of state banking, or the willingness of states to enter the market, is the result of ‘class politics’. The demand for state banking, he argues, came from groups that were displaced by international competition and felt they needed access to credit (Verdier Reference Verdier2000, p. 294). Verdier acknowledges the existence of state interference in savings markets and argues that there is a need to distinguish between deposit and credit banks because state savings banks, such as the UK Post Office Savings Bank, were established ‘to provide central treasuries with access to individual deposits and which are cheaper than bonds’. Instead, Verdier's definition of state banking is credit-focused, namely ‘banks that are specialized and were founded to meet a strongly felt need for credit by a category of borrowers whose relative borrowing power from the capital market was below their political power’. Verdier (Reference Verdier2000, p. 285) argues that UK savings banks did not constitute state banking as he defines it, namely the ‘allocation of credit by the central government through so-called state banks, which finance their needs by issuing state-guaranteed bonds’.

An important consideration for determining whether state banking took place in Ireland is where exactly the land bonds were held and by whom. Over the period 1860–1917, government securities held in Ireland remained relatively constant at approximately £40 million in 1860 and 1913, although there is some variation between these endpoints as the amount held decreased to a low of £24 million in June 1897.Footnote 57 Also, over this period government securities held in Ireland averaged 110 per cent of deposits held by Irish JSBs. Furthermore, as shown in Figure 8, land bonds made up a sizeable share of government debt held in Ireland, and by December 1913, 47 per cent of government debt held in Ireland was comprised of land bonds. Moreover, the land bonds held in Ireland in 1913 were 62.76 per cent of the market capitalisation of the equities traded on the Dublin stock exchange.Footnote 58 Almost the entire 1891/6 land bond issues were held in Ireland, but a smaller share of the 1903 and 1909 bond issues were held there. However, by 1913, 20 per cent of outstanding land bonds were held in Ireland, the remainder were held in Britain. Evidence from Bank of Ireland returns of the holders of government stock in the Irish Free State shows that the Irish held share was about 5 per cent in the 1920s and 1930s,Footnote 59 with an additional 3–4 per cent held in Northern Ireland.

Source: Dublin Stock Exchange and Annual Banking, Railway, and Shipping Statistics, Ireland.

Figure 8. Outstanding land bonds held in Ireland

Offer argues that the British government found it difficult to float land bonds and that savings banks and later national insurance funds were the main purchasers of land bonds. UK savings banks, unlike savings banks in Europe or the US, did not lend for commercial purposes but instead acted like money market mutual funds and invested in government securities (McLaughlin Reference McLaughlin2014). The responsibility for the investments was in the hands of the Chancellor of the Exchequer and the National Debt Commissioners. Offer (Reference Offer1983, pp. 133–4) states that in the Edwardian period government borrowing was ‘kept in reserve for a naval or political emergency’ with the notable exception of Irish land reform. There is strong evidence to suggest that these bonds were purchased by other state financial institutions, namely the Post Office Savings Bank and Trustee Savings Bank, as outlined in Figure 9.Footnote 60 Later records show that the POSB held a considerable share of land bonds in the 1920s and 1930s, with its holdings ranging from 44 to 50 per cent of outstanding land bonds.Footnote 61 Yet, not only were land bonds held by POSB a large share of total issues, but land bonds were also a growing share of POSB assets as indicated in Figure 10.

Source: Dublin Stock Exchange, Postmaster General reports and Annual National Debt (savings banks and friendly societies) funds.

Figure 9. Outstanding land bonds held by institutional investors

Source: Postmaster General reports.

Figure 10. Land bond share of POSB assets, 1898–1916 (%)

Given that Verdier describes state banking as the issue of state bonds, it is quite clear that state banking did take place in the UK (especially Ireland) because, as illustrated heretofore, UK land purchase schemes in Ireland were financed by the issue of guaranteed bonds and were managed by a state agency: the Land Commission. In addition, UK Savings Bank Funds were used to purchase land bonds because, as highlighted by the savings bank committee in 1858 (BPP 1857–8), government securities purchased by savings banks were not always Consols. The situation was clarified by the 1893 Savings Bank Act, when government stock was defined and importantly included ‘Guaranteed Land Stock’, and it is this guaranteed land stock that is central to this study.Footnote 62

Thus, from the discussion above, it is clear that Ireland was indeed a recipient of state banking but was this due to the ‘class politics’ motivation that Verdier suggested? State land purchase policies were direct responses to social agitation in the 1870s and 1880s that were pursued along class lines. Bad harvests in the late 1870s that coincided with the ‘grain invasion’, an increase in grain exports from granaries in the New World, and rising competition in traditional Irish export markets (Solow Reference Solow1971; Koning Reference Koning1994; O'Rourke 1997), effectively meant that Irish agricultural producers experienced a sustained reduction in farming income. Although it did not address the root causes of these problems, an umbrella coalition of interest groups called the Land League campaigned for rent reductions and promoted social agitation against landlords.Footnote 63 The Land League was attractive to those who viewed the payment of rent as the immediate cause of their problems as it promised a reduction in rents and aimed to achieve owner-occupancy of farms (Comerford Reference Comerford1985, p. 247).

Government reaction to Land League agitation was primarily to introduce new land law legislation.Footnote 64 The 1881 Land Act was essentially a rent control Act, with judicially determined lower rents and a Land Commission established by the Act to mediate in landlord–tenant contractual disputes. The aim of the Act was to grant the tenants a ‘fair rent’, but the policy seems to have been to reduce rents regardless of their level.Footnote 65

One of the most significant aspects of the 1881 Act was that it brought land purchase schemes to greater prominence than previously. The legislation made facilities available for tenants to buy land from landlords. However, land purchase schemes failed to attract much support in their initial phases, probably due to a view that judicial rent reductions may have been less costly to implement than expanded land purchase schemes. Future land purchases saw tenants purchase their holdings with the purchase price set in terms of judicially reduced rents.

As illustrated in Table 2, subsequent legislation was specifically designed to encourage greater transfer of ownership from landlords to their tenants. Most notably, the institution created under the 1881 Land Act to mediate rent disputes, the Land Commission, was transformed into an institution that supervised the sale of land.Footnote 66

Koning (Reference Koning1994, p. 32) argues that there were five possible options for agrarian groups (landlords and farmers) to respond to the deteriorated agricultural environment of the late nineteenth century: (i) curb the rise of farm wages; (ii) prevent the fall of domestic prices by introducing tariffs; (iii) shift into new export outlets where competitive advantages still remained; (iv) if tenants, shift the burden onto the owners of land by demanding rent reductions; and (v) if land owners, sell land to tenants at high prices despite the falling profitability of agriculture.

Tenant farmers in Ireland initially choose to pursue (iv) but, as has been shown heretofore, (v) became the option of choice at the behest of the government. At no point were options (i) to (iii) pursued.

IV

This article analyses a land reform programme that successful reached its policy goal of land ownership transfers. Irish land reform witnessed the widespread transfer of land ownership from landlords to sitting tenants and the land transfer programme was enabled by large-scale financial investment underwritten by the British government. Without the creation of a source of credit that enabled most sitting tenants to purchase land at ‘market’ prices from incumbent landlords the scheme would not have been as successful.

A key finding of this article is the importance of state banking in implementing land reform in Ireland. Without the issue of land bonds and the simultaneous purchase of these securities by the UK savings bank funds, land reform would have ground to a halt. This is an interesting facet of land reform policy in Ireland that could be extended to other countries wishing to undertake land reform. A key stumbling block in this regard is noted by Riedinger (Reference Riedinger1995) in the case of the Philippines in the 1990s, namely that the World Bank's Articles of Association do not enable it ‘to finance compensation payments for the transfer of existing assets’ and a general unwillingness by foreign donors to fund land purchases (Riedinger Reference Riedinger1995, pp. 122, 174, 280). In the case of the Philippines, international donors were reluctant to finance the programme because of concerns over the implementation of land reform and the credibility of government support for the programme (Riedinger Reference Riedinger1995, p. 204). This contrasts strongly with the Irish case, primarily because the ‘international donor’ did in fact design and implement the reform programme.

Could land ownership transfers in Ireland have been achieved without the provision of large-scale financial investment by the British state? A possible counterfactual can be observed in contemporary developments in the English land market. As with Ireland, land inequality in England was quite high in the nineteenth century, as evidence from the 1873 census of land ownership attests, and the land question remained a factor in contemporary political debate up until World War I (Sturmey Reference Sturmey1955; Thompson Reference Thompson1957, Reference Thompson1965 and Reference Thompson2007; Lindert Reference Lindert1987; Beckett and Turner Reference Beckett and Turner2007; Cragoe and Readman Reference Cragoe and Readman2010). The close connection between developments in Ireland and England is highlighted by Lindert, who states that ‘the Irish ferment in turn challenged the legitimacy of landed property in England itself’; however, the government-funded land reforms were not witnessed in England. Without direct state assistance in England and Wales, there was a ‘revolution in land ownership’ observable over the period 1890 to 1938, through the transfer of land from established landlord aristocrats to tenants and nouveau riche, most notably in the aftermath of World War I (Thompson Reference Thompson1957, 2007; Beckett and Turner Reference Beckett and Turner2007). Sturmey's account of the rise in owner-farming in England and Wales, shows that the share of owner-occupiers rose from 13 per cent to 36.6 per cent between 1909 and 1927 and that this ‘revolution’ that took place without government support. In fact, many tenants purchased their holdings either from their own savings or bought land on mortgage. The factors contributing to this revolution were similar to those in Ireland, changing market conditions affecting rents and changes in taxation in the 1910s and 1920s (Lindert Reference Lindert1987, p. 37). Therefore in the case of Ireland, could markets have been allowed to take their course or could landlords have been incentivised to sell through taxation schemes? First, as Sturmey (Reference Sturmey1955, p. 246) notes, ‘inducements’ to sell land had increased in England, but at the same time these inducements made it difficult to sell, dovetailing with the decline of the non-economic advantages of landownership and the fear, or anticipation, of hostile land legislation (Thompson Reference Thompson1957, pp. 305–6). Another major difficulty implementing this approach to achieve ownership transfers in Ireland is the market failures in the credit market outlined in Section i. As Sturmey (Reference Sturmey1955, p. 250) indicates, credit difficulties, especially in the early 1910s, acted as a brake on land purchases in England and, as Beckett and Turner (Reference Beckett and Turner2007, p. 279) note, there were calls for state assistance to help tenant farmers purchase their land. The same difficulties would have been evident in Ireland as it is uncertain who other than the state would offer mortgages to tenant farmers to purchase holdings. So perhaps if the land purchase schemes were not implemented in Ireland, there might have been half the number of peasant proprietors as under the land purchase scheme, i.e. 36 per cent instead of 75 per cent. A more in-depth study of counterfactuals may help illuminate the importance, or not, of land purchase schemes.

The study of land reform in Ireland suggests avenues for future research. A greater understanding of land reform in Ireland is desirable. Substantial amounts of capital were invested in Ireland for the purpose of asset redistribution from landlords to tenants. Although cross-national empirical research suggests a link between land inequality and economic growth, there is a stronger link between investment and growth: there are limits to asset redistribution and more benefit could be gained from creating new assets (Deininger and Squire Reference Deininger and Squire1998). It is not possible to address this question here and further work would be desirable in this direction: did land reform lead to increases in economic growth and could the money have been invested in other areas (à la Gerschenkron Reference Gerschenkron1962)? Also, given that asset redistribution resulted in greater landlord liquidity, how were these funds used? Were they consumed, redirected towards industry, such as in Taiwan and Korea, or exported?

Moreover, land reform was a common experience throughout Europe and the rest of the world. Further comparative work would help elucidate common themes and trends. Although the Irish land purchase schemes were not replicated within the United Kingdom, they bear remarkable resemblance to the financial underpinnings of serf emancipation in Russia and further measures of land reform in Russia. As in Ireland, Russian gentry were not expropriated when serfs were emancipated; instead serfs bought land from the gentry.Footnote 67 Contemporaries were aware of these similarities and there are some notable examples, such as Lenin (Reference Lenin1914, 1972) and Ely (Reference Ely1916), but this is an avenue that could be explored further.Footnote 68

Land reform, purchase and ownership are central issues to modern Irish history, yet despite this significance there has been little or no study of the economic or financial implications of the Land Acts in operation. Leading historians have accepted the 1903 Land Act as a ‘solution’ to the ‘land question’ despite the fact that land reform measures continued thereafter. However, debate amongst economic historians as to the short-, medium- and long-run efficiency of land reform is contested (Crotty Reference Crotty1966; Guinnane and Miller Reference Guinnane and Miller1997; Turner Reference Turner1996). Even though the land purchase schemes described in this article were one of the most important tools used to address the land question, the land bonds used to implement the schemes have heretofore been overlooked. The database presented in here is the first systematic effort to collect land bond prices and the data included in the Appendix fill an important lacuna in the understanding of land purchase schemes and also of long-run Irish interest rates. The prices of Irish land bonds presented in this article and in the Appendix are an important source for the greater understanding of developments in Irish history and Irish land reform in the early twentieth century. In particular, price levels of bonds indicate why the 1890 Land Act was initially so successful and why land sales fell as bond prices fell. The study of land bond prices and their relationship with price movements of agricultural commodities, particularly livestock and beef prices, would also be a useful venture. Moreover, while the major movements in these price series are consistent with broader fundamentals, we anticipate that higher-frequency movements offer a measurable interpretation of key developments in the early economic and political history of the Irish Free State.Footnote 69

APPENDIX A: THE 1870 LAND ACT

Precedents for state-funded land purchase were established by significant Acts passed in 1869 and 1870. The Irish Church Act of 1869, primarily an Act which disestablished the Church of Ireland as a state-sponsored church in Ireland, contained clauses enabling tenants on church lands to purchase their holdings with the aid of state-financed mortgages.Footnote 70 The 1870 Land Act also included land purchase clauses, whereby the state would advance money for the purchase of a tenant's holding.Footnote 71 However, neither of these Acts had a high uptake in terms of land purchase, and of the two the 1869 Act saw the greater number of tenant purchases (Lyons Reference Lyons1971, p. 146).

The primary aim of the 1870 Act was to reform the existing law governing landlord–tenant contracts. The 1870 Land Act was influenced by a perception that agricultural investment in Ireland was impeded by an inadequate definition of property rights. The case of the prosperity of farms in the northern counties of Ulster was used as an example of the benefits of reform, as it was believed that Ulster's prosperity was caused by what was known as the ‘Ulster custom’. The Ulster custom consisted of what were known as the ‘three F's’. As Kennedy and Solar (Reference Kennedy, Solar, Kennedy and Ollerenshaw2012, p. 174) note:

These extra-legal rights varied from estate to estate, but often carried the presumption that a sitting tenant could expect renewal of a lease, once it had expired; that rents would be ‘fair’, meaning essentially lower than the competitive or rack-rent; and that on vacating a holding he or she had the right to sell the value of the unexpired lease to the incoming tenant. The last could be valuable, amounting on some farms to ten times or more the annual rent paid to the landlord, suggesting that actual rents were well below the competitive rent level.

There was a common impression that the perceived prosperity of Ulster farming, small tillage farming, was based on the ‘Ulster custom’. Vaughan (Reference Vaughan1994, p. 82) has suggested that perhaps contemporaries were not able to distinguish between a flax boom, caused by market dislocations resulting from the American Civil War (the so-called ‘Cotton Famine’), and the customs prevailing in Ulster. Support for Vaughan's argument comes from the general report of the 1871 census where it was stated that ‘in that province [Ulster], however, throughout almost its entire extent, the cultivation of flax is connected with the one manufacture – that of linen – deserving to be called great’ (BPP 1876, p. 7).

The 1870 Land Act attempted to formalise informal traditional customs in Ulster. One of the main assumptions of the Acts was that the tenancy system in Ireland was an impediment to agricultural investment as tenants were unwilling to invest in agricultural improvements because of a fear that such investment would lead to either rent increases or arbitrary eviction. Solow (Reference Solow1971) and Vaughan (Reference Vaughan1994) have argued that this scenario did not exist, and that tenancies were relatively secure before the 1880s (McLaughlin Reference McLaughlin2009). The evidence on evictions also suggests that there was a low probability of eviction in post-famine Ireland. Thus, suggesting that the 1870 Land Act was misguided at best.

APPENDIX B: ANNUAL LAND BOND PRICES

Table A1. Land bonds: weighted average prices and current yields

Footnotes

1 For example, in May 2010 the World Bank approved $12.1 m funding for a cadastre and land registration programme in FYR Macedonia (worldbank.org). The World Bank also has an Annual Conference on Land and Poverty that is devoted to best practice in land reform (www.worldbank.org/en/events/2014/08/06/landconference2015).

2 Lipton (Reference Lipton2009) outlines several possible land reforms including classic land reform (land redistribution with/without ceilings on land holdings), tenancy reforms, collectivisation/decollectivisation and market-based reforms. The literature has attempted to address the problem of policy design for over 50 years: Office of National Statistics (2009); UN (1951); World Bank (1973); Binswanger, Deininger and Feder (Reference Binswanger, Deininger and Feder1993); Deininger (Reference Deininger2003).

3 The Irish example is cited by Lipton (Reference Lipton2009) in his survey of land reform in developing countries.

4 Land reform is a central issue in modern Irish history, with the land question playing a key role in the development of Irish national and political identity:  Boyce (Reference Boyce2005); Dooley (Reference Dooley2004); Lyons (Reference Lyons1971).

5 In this article, we do not address the long-term effects, or the welfare implications, of land reform in Ireland. For a survey of that literature, see Crotty (Reference Crotty1966); Solow (Reference Solow1971); Meenan (Reference Meenan1970); Kennedy et al. (Reference Kennedy, Giblin and McHugh1988); Turner (Reference Turner1996); Ó Gráda (Reference Ó Gráda1997).

6 Financing Irish land reform by bond has generally been overlooked due to the misperception that the sales were financed directly by state money (Lyons Reference Lyons1971, p. 214; Ferriter Reference Ferriter2004, p. 368). Moreover, land bonds are also hugely important in a British context, because, as Offer argues, by ‘mortgaging government credit to the policy of land purchase in Ireland’ it restricted policies such as education reform in Britain (Offer Reference Offer1983, p. 134).

7 For example, land securities were issued in South Korea to finance land reform in the 1950s (Jeon and Kim Reference Jeon and Kim2000, p. 254).

8 The lack of completeness in the history of Irish interest rates is evident in Homer and Sylla (2005, pp. 537–8), where Irish government bond yields are not reported until 1952. Although pre-independence issues were referred to as ‘stock’, as noted by Homer and Sylla (2005, p. 181), ‘bonds were and are called stocks’.

9 See Appendix A for a discussion of the motivations and development of land policy under the 1870 Land Act. This section draws on the work of McLaughlin (Reference McLaughlin2009).

10 See McLaughlin (Reference McLaughlin2015) for context.

11 There were also a number of Acts which provided loans for buildings and permanent improvements on holdings (Bailey Reference Bailey1917; Sheehan Reference Sheehan1993).

12 The island of Ireland has almost 21 million acres of land.

13 Two other bodies also facilitated land purchase, the Congested Districts Board (CDB) established by the 1891 Land Act and the Estates Commissioners established by the 1903 Land Act.

14 3 Edw. 7 c. 37, section 19.

15 Compulsory purchase powers were a constant feature of land purchase legislation in post-partition Ireland (Dooley Reference Dooley2004; Rumpf and Hepburn Reference Rumpf and Hepburn1977).

16 According to a contemporaneous lecturer in land law, ‘the money is secured by what is practically a first mortgage of the tenant's holding, with a provision for re-payment of the debt by instalments’ (Walker Reference Walker1908, p. 140).

17 The performance of the land purchase account and sinking fund was published annually from 1906 until 1976: see BPP (1906) and BPP (1976–7).

18 Stipulations in the Acts restricted the amount that other mortgagees, namely private mortgage lenders, could place on the land (3 Edw. 7 c. 37, section 54.2).

19 3 Edw. 7 c. 37, section 45.2.

20 The percentage of the Irish population that was over the age of 35 in 1901 and 1911 was 34 per cent and 38 per cent respectively. According to British life tables, 35-year-old males would have been expected to live another 31 and 32 years in 1901 and 1911 respectively: ONS (2009).

21 Prices could be agreed directly between landlords and tenants, where terms were negotiated between landlord and tenant and sanctioned by the Land Commission as long as the agreed price fell within the ‘zones’ of the Act. Landlords could also sell whole estates to the Land Commission or CDB, but in this case the price was based on a valuation of the estate. The former was the preferred method of sale.

22 After the1881 Land Act the Land Commission acted as a court to settle rental disputes between landlords and tenants. The Act created statutory tenancies for a period of 15 years during which time landlords were not permitted to increase rents or arbitrarily evict tenants. After the 15 years had passed either landlord or tenant could apply to have rents revised. There were a number of procedures through which tenants and landlords could arbitrate rents through the land commission, and from 1881 to 1911 first statutory term reductions resulted in a 20 per cent reduction in rents on 377,400 holdings and second statutory term reductions of a further 19.5 per cent reduction in rents on 139,094 holdings (Cosgrove Reference Cosgrove2008, p. 147; Hooker Reference Hooker1938, pp. 44–5; Thom's 1912, p. 776).

23 3 Edw. 7 c. 37, section 45.1.

24 38/1933 [Éire], sections 12–27.

25 Modern-day microfinance institutions who utilise collateral substitutes based on personal security also do not lend for land acquisition (Lipton Reference Lipton2009, p. 166).

26 Guinnane and Miller argue that the 1903 and 1909 Land Acts reduced the capitalisation of mortgage land for purchasers compared with the traditional ‘tenant right’. However, they do not elaborate on who mortgage providers were as they clearly show that JSBs did not engage in mortgage lending (Guinnane and Miller Reference Guinnane and Miller1997, table 3, pp. 603, 605–6).

27 A mortgage advertisement for J. A. O'Suillivan, Insurance, Mortgage and Investments office appeared in Thom's (1881, p. 39) for ‘£10,000 and upwards on fee-simple landed properties’ with interest ranging between ‘four to four and a half percent’. Advances were made on ‘on fee-simple landed properties … Mortgages of life interests, Reversions, Leasehold, and other approved Security’. Although one advertisement is not representative of all mortgage lenders, this advertisement gives an indication of the services that mortgage providers offered.

28 Registration of deeds and titles was not kept in an orderly fashion and it is reported that it would take days and weeks to search for specific deeds and titles, i.e. a high cost. This cost could be reflected in a high opportunity cost if the individuals performed the search themselves, or in the form of a direct cost if they hired a solicitor to do the search (BPP 1914).

29 The Bank of Ireland was ostensibly a central bank and could have acted as a lender of last resort, but its role in the collapse of the Munster Bank suggests that it was not a willing lender of last resort (Ó Gráda Reference Ó Gráda, Dickson and Gráda2003, Reference Ó Gráda2012).

30 This characteristic brings to mind the US in the early 2000s where subprime borrowers were offered mortgages with loan to value ratios of 100 per cent in 2005 and 2006 (Mayer et al. Reference Mayer, Pence and Sherlund2009, table 2); in the Irish case this meant that all borrowers were treated as ‘subprime’.

31 For example, tenant farmers in England who bought land on mortgage were forced to sell their farms during the Depression in the 1930s as they had contracted mortgages in times of ‘high land and product prices’ and experienced distress when opposite conditions prevailed (Sturmey 1953, pp. 263–4).

32 National Archives, Kew, ‘2¾ per cent Guaranteed Stock’, NSC 12/96.

33 26 August 1904, Charles John Sugrue to PMG, National Archives, Kew, ‘2¾% Guaranteed Stock’, NSC 12/96.

34 Note Jones to Bewley, 1 May 1930, National Archives, Kew, ‘Northern Ireland 4½% Land Bonds’ T/ 160/459/8.

35 William Moore, a Unionist MP for Antrim North, stated that land bonds, which he termed ‘Bog Stock’, were not popular with timid investors and were being issued at a discount to landowners, who could only sell them in the market for a further discount. Hansard, 23 July 1909.

36 This is a key distinction between the limited Highland land reforms in Scotland and those in Ireland, as Scottish Crofter Acts were imitations of the 1881 Land Act and did not extend land purchase schemes as did the 1891 and 1903 Land Acts (Cameron Reference Cameron1996, pp. 37–8).

37 The preface to the seventh edition written in 1871 stated that ‘for an analogous reason, all notice of the alteration made in the Land Laws of Ireland by the recent Act, is deferred until experience shall have had time to pronounce on the operation of that well-meant attempt to deal with the greatest evil in the economic institutions of that country’ (Mill Reference Mill1871).

38 54 & 55 Vict. c. 48, section 1, and 3 Edw. 7  c. 37, section 28.

39 9 Edw. 7 c. 42, section 1.

40 42/1923 [Éire], sections 1, 2, 9 and 30; 15 & 16 Geo. 5 c. 34 [UK], sections 1 and 3; 38/1933  [Éire]; 11/1934 [Éire], section 6.

41 54 & 55 Vict. c. 48, section 1.

42 The 1903 Act allowed for payment in cash, raised through the sale of stock, because the market price for the bonds was typically below par after 1900. In addition, the Act introduced a land purchase aid fund of £12 million to be distributed to landlords ostensibly to cover legal costs involved in sales, but widely perceived as an inducement to encourage landlords to sell.

43 National Archives, Kew, ‘2¾% Guaranteed Stock’, NSC 12/96. The average issue price of stock under the 1903 Land Act was £88.71  (BPP 1908b). So, for example, each £100 issue would be sold for £90, used to fund land purchase. But the tenant farmer only received a loan for £90 and thus the expected repayment implied a deficit of 10 per cent (ignoring the small interest spread), which had to be met by some external source of finance, namely taxpayers.

44 3 Edw. 7 c. 37, section 38.

45 Given that no annual Irish GDP series exists, the GDP denominator in Figure 4 is estimated from Maddison data using the 1913 share of the Irish economy in the UK economy. Also, as Northern Ireland was included in the land purchase schemes it is also included in the denominator (Cullen Reference Cullen2007; Maddison Reference Maddison2001, Reference Maddison2003).

46 Dublin Stock Exchange, BI 3/32 to BI 3/79, National Archives of Ireland, Dublin.

47 The Dublin Stock Exchange was formally established in 1799. Regional exchanges formed later in the nineteenth century: Cork in 1886 and Belfast in 1897 (Thomas Reference Thomas1986, pp. 55, 151, 223).

48 See Foley-Fisher and McLaughlin Reference Foley-Fisher and McLaughlin2014 for more details on the construction of the database.

49 The telegraph connection was temporarily lost in 1914, but the telephone remained operational (Thomas Reference Thomas1986, p. 92).

50 The president of the Dublin Stock Exchange stated in evidence to the Banking Commission in June 1935 that the Dublin market price was the ‘middle London price’ (IPP 1938, Minutes of evidence Q3113).

51 The 1903 conversion of the consolidated stock had been planned from the National Debt (Conversion) Act of 1888.

52 The latter two land bonds were guaranteed by the Irish government, which also inherited responsibility for collecting annuities to repay the previous four land bonds. These government guarantees made the bonds de facto sovereign debt, even though land bonds were typically issued by the body responsible for overseeing the land purchase scheme (Land Commission).

53 From independence onwards, bonds issued by the Free State government take precedence over imperial funds, as evidenced by the placement of Free State government funds above British funds on the daily stock exchange listings. Also, the British treasury in 1920 wanted to transfer the register of government debt held by the Bank of Ireland from Dublin to Belfast. However, an agreement was reached whereby only the holdings of Northern Irish bondholders were transferred to Belfast; Dublin kept its existing stock holdings but no new UK issues featured on the Dublin market (Thomas Reference Thomas1986, p. 130).

54 The seven periods correspond to an ex-ante expectation of variation in financial market behaviour towards land bonds: (1) Jan 1890 – Aug 1903: pre-Land Act of 1903; (2) Aug 1903 – Jul 1914: pre-World War I; (3) Jul 1914 – Nov 1918: World War I; (4) Nov 1918 – Dec 1921: war of independence; (5) Dec 1921 – Sept 1929: post-Irish independence; (6) Sept 1929 – Dec 1931: Great Depression; (7) Jan 1932 – Dec 1938: post-Great Depression.

55 E.g. see Thomas (Reference Thomas1986).

56 The weights are the outstanding nominal value of each bond in the category. Since Consols have a large outstanding nominal value, the ‘British government bond’ series is de facto that of Consols. A similar figure is obtained when using one-year or five-year windows.

57 Annual Banking, Railway, and Shipping Statistics, Ireland, 1860–1917.

58 Data on the market capitalisation of equities is from Grossman et al. (Reference Grossman, Lyons, O'Rourke and Ursu2014).

59 Assessment of stocks on the Dublin register, AC/22/63, Bank of England Archive.

60 There is evidence of a wide array of government departments investing in various types of government securities (BPP 1910).

61 Commissioners for the Reduction of the National Debt files, C69/1 and C69/2, Bank of England archive; Post Office Savings Bank, Post75 Acc98/54, Post Office Archive.

62 56 & 57 Vict. c. 69.

63 Irish historiography is still somewhat divided on the issue regarding landlord–tenant relations. E.g. Crotty (Reference Crotty1966); Donnelly (Reference Donnelly1975); Solow (Reference Solow1971); Vaughan (Reference Vaughan1994); Turner (Reference Turner1996); Hoppen (Reference Hoppen1999).

64 44 & 45 Vict. c. 49.

65 Donnelly (Reference Donnelly1975, pp. 297–8) shows how rent reductions took place not because rents were high but due to agitation for reductions. By 1900 aggregate rents were reduced by 22% in the first statutory term and 22.15% in the second statutory term (Thom's 1902).

66 In Northern Ireland, the Land Commission ceased to exist after 1935 but continued its existence in Southern Ireland until 1999.

67 Agreements for the price of land were either negotiated voluntary between peasants and landlords (pomeshchik) or imposed by landlords on peasants. The government in turn financed 80 per cent of the value of the land. The pomeshchik received land bonds with a coupon of 5 per cent whilst tenants repaid a 6 per cent annuity (known as a redemption) over 49 years. By 1881, 84.7 per cent of the former serfs were landowners. In 1906 redemption payments were reduced by 50 per cent and were completely abolished by 1907 (Gerschenkron Reference Gerschenkron, Habakkuk and Postan1965).

68 Lenin ([1914] 1972) noted that ‘the Liberals have imposed upon him [the Irish peasant] a system of land purchase at a “fair” price! He has paid, and will continue to pay for many years, millions upon millions to the British landlords as a reward for their having robbed him for centuries and reduced him to a state of chronic starvation. The British liberal bourgeois has made the Irish peasant thank the landlord for this in hard cash …’

69 Empirical research on Irish land bonds complements existing studies of other Irish financial markets. Given the rural nature of the Irish economy, studies of land bonds use distinctly ‘Irish’ traded securities, similar to recent studies of historical Irish equity markets including Hickson and Turner (Reference Hickson and Turner2008) and Grossman et al. (Reference Grossman, Lyons, O'Rourke and Ursu2014).

70 32 & 33 Vict. c. 42, paragraphs 52–4.

71 The primary purpose of the 1870 Land Act was not to introduce land purchase schemes; this was an afterthought included in the Act. It is commonly known as the ‘Bright clause’, named after John Bright at whose behest provisions for land purchase were included in the Act (33 & 34 Vict. c. 46, part ii).

References

Sources

Bank of England ArchiveGoogle Scholar
The National Archives, KewGoogle Scholar
The National Archives of Ireland, DublinGoogle Scholar
Post Office ArchiveGoogle Scholar
Land Commission reports (Irish Free State)Google Scholar
Annual Banking, Railway, and Shipping Statistics, IrelandGoogle Scholar
Postmaster General reportsGoogle Scholar
Annual National Debt (savings banks and friendly societies) fundsGoogle Scholar
Irish Church Act, 1869 (32 & 33 Vict. c. 42)Google Scholar
Landlord and Tenant (Ireland) Act, 1870 (33 & 34 Vict. c. 46)Google Scholar
Land Law (Ireland) Act, 1881 (44 & 45 Vict. c. 49)Google Scholar
Purchase of Land (Ireland) Act, 1891 (54 & 55 Vict. c. 48)Google Scholar
Savings Bank Act, 1893 (56 & 57 Vict. c. 69)Google Scholar
Irish Land Act, 1903 (3 Edw. 7 c. 37)Google Scholar
Irish Land Act, 1909 (9 Edw. 7 c. 42)Google Scholar
Land Act, 42/1923 [Éire]Google Scholar
Northern Ireland Land Act, 1925 (15 & 16 Geo. 5 c. 34) [UK]Google Scholar
Land Act, 38/1933 [Éire]Google Scholar
Land Bond Act, 11/1934 [Éire]Google Scholar

References

Bailey, W. F. (1917). The Irish Land Acts: A Short Sketch of Their History and Development. Dublin: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.Google Scholar
Beckett, J. and Turner, M. (2007). End of the Old Order? F. M. L. Thompson, the Land Question, and the burden of ownership in England, c. 1880–c. 1925. Agricultural History Review, 55, pp. 269–88.Google Scholar
Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2000). Land reform, poverty reduction, and growth: evidence from India. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, pp. 389430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binswanger, H. P., Deininger, K. and Feder, G. (1993). Power, distortions, revolt, and reform in agricultural land relations. World Bank Policy Research Working Papers, WPS 1163.Google Scholar
Boyce, D. G. (2005). Nineteenth Century Ireland: The Search for Stability. Dublin: Gill and Macmillan.Google Scholar
BPP (1857–8). Report from the select committee on savings banks. HC 441.Google Scholar
BPP (1876). Census of Ireland, 1871, part iii, general report. HC [C 1377], lxxxi, 1.Google Scholar
BPP (1882). First report from the Select Committee of the House of Lords on Land Law (Ireland); together with the proceedings of the committee, minutes of evidence, and appendix. HL (249), xi, 1.Google Scholar
BPP (1906). Irish Land Purchase Fund. Accounts, 1903–1905. Accounts of receipts and payments by the Commissioners for the Reduction of the National Debt in respect of the capital and income of the Irish Land Purchase Fund from 1st November 1903 to 31st March 1905, together with the report of the Comptroller and Auditor-General thereon. HC (134).Google Scholar
BPP (1908a). Agricultural statistics of Ireland, with detailed report on agriculture for 1906. HC [Cd 3791].Google Scholar
BPP (1908b). Guaranteed 2 ¾ per cent stock. HC (285).Google Scholar
BPP (1908c). Report of the departmental committee appointed to enquire into Irish land purchase finance in connection with the provision of funds required for the purposes of the Irish Land Act, 1903. HC [Cd 4005], xxiii, 267.Google Scholar
BPP (1910). Government department statistics. HC (155).Google Scholar
BPP (1914). Report of the departmental committee on agricultural credit in Ireland. HC 13 (Cd 7375), 1.Google Scholar
BPP (1921a). Agricultural statistics of Ireland with detailed report for 1917 (Statistics). HC [Cmd 1316].Google Scholar
BPP (1921b). Report of the estates commissioners for the year ending 31st March 1920. HC, xiv, 661.Google Scholar
BPP (1924). Memorandum explaining financial resolution (land purchase (loan guarantee)). HC [Cmd 2175], xviii, 67.Google Scholar
BPP (1924–5a). Copy of Treasury minute dated 24th July 1925, guaranteeing the payment of the principal of, and interest on, certain land bonds to be issued by the government of the Irish Free State. HC (152).Google Scholar
BPP (1924–5b). Irish Free State land purchase (loan guarantee). Memorandum explaining financial resolution. HC [Cmd 2286].Google Scholar
BPP (1929–30). Copy of Treasury minute dated 30th July 1930, under section 1 (4) of the Irish Free State Land Purchase (Loan Guarantee) Act, 1924. HC (180).Google Scholar
BPP (1930–1). Copy of Treasury minute dated 2nd July 1931, under section 1 (4) of the Irish Free State Land Purchase (Loan Guarantee) Act, 1924. HC (122).Google Scholar
BPP (1976–7). Irish Land Purchase Fund account 1975–6. Account of receipts and payments by the national debt commissioners, and statements of liabilities outstanding, in respect of the Irish Land Purchase Fund, for the year ended 31st March 1976; together with the report of the comptroller and auditor general thereon. HC (234).Google Scholar
Brown, S. J. and Warner, J. B. (1985). Using daily stock returns: the case of event studies. Journal of Financial Economics 14, pp. 331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, E. (1996). Land for the People? The British Government and the Scottish Highlands, c. 1880–1925. East Lothian: Tuckwell Press.Google Scholar
Colvin, C. L. and McLaughlin, E. (2014). Raiffeisenism abroad: why did German cooperative banking fail in Ireland but prosper in the Netherlands? Economic History Review, 67, pp. 492516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Comerford, R. V. (1985). The Fenians in Context. Dublin: Wolfhound.Google Scholar
Cosgrove, P. J. (2008). The Wyndham Land Act 1903: the final solution to the Irish land question? PhD thesis, NUI Maynooth Department of History.Google Scholar
Cragoe, M. and Readman, P. (eds.) (2010). The Land Question in Britain, 1750–1950. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crotty, R. D. (1966). Irish Agricultural Production. Cork: Cork University Press.Google Scholar
Cullen, L. M. (2007). The context and development of historical national accounts in Ireland. Irish Economic and Social History, 37, pp. 7584.Google Scholar
Curtis, L. P. (1980). Incumbered wealth: landed indebtedness in post-famine Ireland. American Historical Review, 85, pp. 332–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deininger, K. (2003). Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction: A World Bank Policy Research Report. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Deininger, K., Jin, S. and Nagarajan, H. K. (2009). Land reforms, poverty reduction, and economic growth: evidence from India. Journal of Development Studies, 45, pp. 496521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deininger, K. and Squire, L. (1998). New ways of looking at old issues: inequality and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 57, pp 259–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimon, E., Marsh, P. and Staunton, M. (2000). Risk and return in the 20th and 21st centuries. Business Strategy Review, 11, pp. 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donnelly, J. S. (1975). The Land and the People of Nineteenth Century Cork. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Dooley, T. (2004). The Land for the People: The Land Question in Independent Ireland. Dublin: University College Dublin Press.Google Scholar
Ely, R. T. (1916). Russian land reform. American Economic Review, 6, pp. 61–8.Google Scholar
Federico, G. (2005). Feeding the World: An Economic History of Agriculture, 1800–2000. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ferguson, N. (2006). Political risk and the international bond market between the 1848 revolution and the outbreak of the First World War. Economic History Review, 59, pp. 70112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferguson, N. (2008). Learning from history? Financial markets and the approach of world wars. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, pp. 431–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferriter, D. (2004). The Transformation of Ireland, 1900–2000. London: Profile Books.Google Scholar
Foley-Fisher, N. and McLaughlin, E. (2014). Irish land bonds: 1891–1938. EABH Papers 14–01.Google Scholar
Gailey, A. (1987). Ireland and the Death of Kindness: The Experience of Constructive Unionism 1890–1905. Cork: Cork University Press.Google Scholar
Galor, O., Moav, O. and Vollrath, D. (2009). Inequality in land ownership, the emergence of human-capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Review of Economic Studies, 76, pp. 143–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gersback, H. and Siemers, L.-H. R. (2010). Land reform and economic development. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 14, pp. 527–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic backwardness in historical perspective. In Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective: A Book of Essays. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, pp. 530.Google Scholar
Gerschenkron, A. (1965). Agrarian policies and industrialisation: Russia 1861–1917. In Habakkuk, H. J. and Postan, M. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, vol. vi, part ii, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Griffin, K., Khan, A. R. and Ickowitz, A. (2002). Poverty and the distribution of land. Journal of Agrarian Change, 2, pp. 279330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, R. S., Lyons, R. C., O'Rourke, K. and Ursu, M. A. (2014). A monthly stock exchange index for Ireland, 1864–1930. European Review of Economic History, 18, pp. 248276.Google Scholar
Guinnane, T. W. and Miller, R. I. (1997). The limits to land reform: the Land Acts in Ireland, 1870–1909. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 45, pp. 591612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hickson, C. R. and Turner, J. D. (2008). Pre- and post-Famine indices of Irish equity prices. European Review of Economic History 12, pp. 338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homer, S. and Sylla, R. (2005). A History of Interest Rates, 4th edn.Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Hooker, E. R. (1938). Readjustments of Agricultural Tenure in Ireland. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Hoppen, K. T. (1999), Ireland since 1800: Conflict and Conformity, 2nd edn.London: Longman.Google Scholar
Ilmanen, A. (2003). Expected returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Portfolio Management, 29, pp. 727.Google Scholar
IPP (1926–7). Banking Commission, 1926; First interim report on Banking and currency; Second interim report, agricultural credit, third interim report, business credit and fourth interim report public finance; Final reports of the Banking Commission, R33/1, R33/2, R33/3.Google Scholar
IPP (1934). Report of the Irish Land Commissioners, for the year from 1st April 1933 to 31st March (p. 1471) L1/8.Google Scholar
IPP (1938). Report of the Commission of Inquiry into Banking, Currency and Credit, p. 2628, R. 63, xxxi.Google Scholar
Jeon, Y.-D. and Kim, Y.-Y. (2000), Land reform, income distribution, and agricultural production in Korea. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 48, pp. 253–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, K. A., Giblin, T. and McHugh, D. (1988). The Economic Development of Ireland in the Twentieth Century. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Kennedy, L. and Solar, P. (2012). The rural economy, 1780–1914. In Kennedy, L. and Ollerenshaw, P. (eds.), Ulster since 1600. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, L. and Solar, P. M. (2007). Irish Agriculture: A Price History. Dublin: Irish Academic Press.Google Scholar
King, R. (1977). Land Reform: A World Survey. London: G. Bell and Sons.Google Scholar
Kolbert, C. F. and O'Brien, T. (1975). Land reform in Ireland: a legal history of the Irish land problem and its settlement. University of Cambridge Department of Land Economy, Occasional Paper no. 3.Google Scholar
Koning, N. (1994). The Failure of Agrarian Capitalism. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lenin, V. I. ([1914] 1972). British Liberals and Ireland. In Lenin Collected Works, 12 March 1914. Moscow.Google Scholar
Lindert, P. (1987). Who owned Victorian England? The debate over landed wealth and inequality. Agricultural History, 61, pp. 2551.Google Scholar
Lipton, M. (2009). Land Reform in Developing Countries: Property Rights and Property Wrongs. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lyons, F. S. L. (1971). Ireland since the Famine. Glasgow: Collins.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (2001). The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. Paris: OECD.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddison, A. (2003). The World Economy: Historical Statistics. Paris: OECD.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, C., Pence, K. and Sherlund, S. M. (2009). The rise in mortgage defaults. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23, pp. 2750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLaughlin, E. (2009). Microfinance institutions in nineteenth century Ireland (2 vols.). PhD thesis, Department of History, National University of Ireland, Maynooth.Google Scholar
McLaughlin, E. (2013). A note on mutual savings and loan societies in nineteenth-century Ireland. Irish Economic and Social History, 40, pp. 4868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLaughlin, E. (2014). Profligacy in the encouragement of thrift: savings banks in Ireland, 1817–1914. Business History, 56, pp. 569–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McLaughlin, E. (2015). Competing forms of cooperation. Agricultural History Review, 63, pp. 81112.Google Scholar
Meenan, J. (1970). The Irish Economy since 1922. Liverpool: Liverpool University Press.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1848). Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy. 1st edn.London: Longmans.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1871). Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy, 7th edn (people's edition). London: Longmans.Google Scholar
Nunan, D. B. (1987). Price trends of agricultural land in Ireland 1901–1986. Irish Journal of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology, 12, pp. 5177.Google Scholar
Ó Gráda, C. (1997). A Rocky Road: The Irish Economy since the 1920s. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Ó Gráda, C. (2003). Moral hazard and quasi-central banking: should the Munster Bank have been saved? In Dickson, D. and Gráda, C. Ó (eds.), Refiguring Ireland: Essays in Honour of L. M. Cullen. Dublin: Lilliput Press.Google Scholar
Ó Gráda, C. (2012). The last major Irish bank failure before 2008. Financial History Review, 19, 119217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obstfeld, M. and Taylor, A. M. (2004). Global Capital Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offer, A. (1983). Empire and social reform: British overseas investment and domestic politics, 1908–1914. Historical Journal, 26, pp. 119–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Office OF National Statistics (2009). Decennial Life Tables. Period Expectations of Life from English Life Tables, nos. 1 to 16 (Excel sheet 56Kb) Release date 25 Jun 09; downloaded from ons.gov.uk 15.5.2012.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1982). The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation and Social Rigidities. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
O'rourke, K. (1997). The European grain invasion, 1870–1913. Journal of Economic History, 57, pp. 775801.Google Scholar
O'Rourke, K. H. and Williamson, J. G. (1999). Globalisation and History. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riedinger, J. M. (1995). Agrarian Reform in the Philippines: Democratic Transitions and Redistributive Reform. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Rumpf, E. and Hepburn, A. C. (1977). Nationalism and Socialism in Twentieth Century Ireland. Liverpool: Liverpool University Press.Google Scholar
Sheehan, J. T. (1993). Land purchase policy in Ireland, 1917–23: from the Irish convention to the 1923 Land Act. Master's thesis, National University of Ireland, St Patrick's College, Maynooth.Google Scholar
Siegal, J. (1992). The equity premium: stock and bond returns since 1802. Financial Analysts Journal, 48, pp. 2838.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, B. L. (1971). The Land Question and the Irish Economy, 1870–1903. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sturmey, S. G. (1955). Owner-farming in England and Wales, 1900 to 1950. The Manchester School, 23, pp. 245268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, W. A. (1986). The Stock Exchange of Ireland. Liverpool: Francis Cairns.Google Scholar
Thom's Directory (1881). Dublin: Thom's.Google Scholar
Thom's Directory (1902). Dublin: Thom's.Google Scholar
Thom's Directory (1912). Dublin: Thom's.Google Scholar
Thompson, F. M. L. (1957). The land market in the nineteenth century. Oxford Economic Papers, 9, pp. 285308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, F. M. L. (1965). Land and politics in England in the nineteenth century. Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 15, pp. 2344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, M. (2007). The land market, 1880–1925: a reappraisal reappraised. Agricultural History Review, 55, pp 289300.Google Scholar
Turner, M. (1996). After the Famine. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
United Nations (UN) (1951). Land Reform: Defects in Agrarian Structure as Obstacles to Economic Development. Washington, DC: United Nations.Google Scholar
Vaughan, W. E. (1994). Landlords and Tenants in Mid-Victorian Ireland. Oxford: Clarendon Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verdier, D. (2000). The rise and fall of state banking in OECD countries. Comparative Political Studies, 33, pp. 283318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vollrath, D. (2007). Land distribution and international agricultural productivity. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 89, pp. 202–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, R. A. (1908). Irish land as security, part i. Journal of the Institute of Bankers in Ireland, 10.Google Scholar
World Bank (1973). Land Reform. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Land purchase schemes 1869–1923: advances, acreage and holdings

Figure 1

Figure 1. Obligations and liabilities associated with land bonds

Figure 2

Table 2. Initial land purchase contracts for tenants, 1869–1933

Figure 3

Table 3. Real and nominal annuities, decade averages

Figure 4

Table 4. Arrears as a share of instalments due (%)

Figure 5

Figure 2. Landowners as a percentage of landholdings: 1906 and 1917

Source: BPP (1908a, 1921a).
Figure 6

Figure 3. Nominal value of land bonds as a share of GDP

Source: Dublin Stock Exchange and authors' calculations (see text).
Figure 7

Figure 4. Nominal value of all land bonds as a share of estimated Irish GDP

Source: Dublin Stock Exchange and authors’ calculations (see text).
Figure 8

Table 5. Dublin Stock Exchange: sovereign debt

Figure 9

Table 6. Bond returns: summary statistics

Figure 10

Figure 5. Land bonds: last prices

Figure 11

Figure 6. Consols and Exchequer bonds: last prices

Figure 12

Figure 7. Weighted average bond returns: volatility

Figure 13

Figure 8. Outstanding land bonds held in Ireland

Source: Dublin Stock Exchange and Annual Banking, Railway, and Shipping Statistics, Ireland.
Figure 14

Figure 9. Outstanding land bonds held by institutional investors

Source: Dublin Stock Exchange, Postmaster General reports and Annual National Debt (savings banks and friendly societies) funds.
Figure 15

Figure 10. Land bond share of POSB assets, 1898–1916 (%)

Source: Postmaster General reports.
Figure 16

Table A1. Land bonds: weighted average prices and current yields