Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-wdhn8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T09:01:39.608Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Worker-firm relational contracts in the time of shutdowns: experimental evidence

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Sera Linardi*
Affiliation:
University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh, USA
Colin Camerer*
Affiliation:
California Institute of Technology, Pasadena, USA

Abstract

Exogeneous disruptions in labor demand have become more frequent in recent times. The COVID-19 pandemic has resulted in millions of workers being repeatedly laid off and rehired according to local public health conditions. This may be bad news for market efficiency. Typical employment relations—which resemble non-enforceable (implicit) contracts—rely on reciprocity (Brown et al. in Econometrica 72:747–780, 2004), and hence could be harmed when workers’ efforts no longer guarantee reemployment in the next period. In this paper we extend the BFF paradigm to include a per-period probability (0%, 10%, 50%) of publicly observable “shutdown”, where a specific firm cannot contract with any workers for several periods. A Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium exists in which these shutdowns destabilize relationships, but do not harm efficiency. Our experiment shows that, remarkably, market efficiency can be maintained even with very frequent stochastic shutdowns. However, the dynamic of relational contracts changes from one where a worker finds stable employment to one where she juggles multiple employers, laying the burden of maintaining productivity upon workers and worsening worker-side inequality.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2021 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Supplementary information The online version contains supplementary material available at (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-020-09697-1).

The authors would like to thank the following individuals for their excellent research assistance: Erin Carbone, Xiaohong Wang, Jinyong Jeong, Taisuke Imai, Devdeepta Bose. We thank the referees, editors, and participants at seminars for their very useful feedback. We acknowledge the financial support from Behavioral and Neuroeconomics Discovery Fund (via MacArthur Foundation) and grant administration assistance of Tiffany Kim and Alisha Cunniff.

References

Amuedo-Dorantes, C (2000). Work transitions into and out of involuntary temporary employment in a segmented market: Evidence from Spain. ILR Review, 53, 309325. 10.1177/001979390005300207CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, SP, Goeree, JK, & Holt, CA (2001). Minimum-effort coordination games: Stochastic potential and logit equilibrium. Games and Economic Behavior, 34, 177199. 10.1006/game.2000.0800CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J (1988). Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 37, 291304. 10.1016/0047-2727(88)90043-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Croson, R (2008). Partners versus strangers: Random rematching in public goods experiments. Handbook of Experimental Economics Results, 1, 776783. 10.1016/S1574-0722(07)00082-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azariadis, C (1975). Implicit contracts and underemployment equilibria. Journal of Political Economy, 83, 11831202. 10.1086/260388CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, AV, & Duflo, E (2000). Reputation effects and the limits of contracting: A study of the Indian software industry. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 9891017. 10.1162/003355300554962CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barlevy, G (2002). The sullying effect of recessions. The Review of Economic Studies, 69, 6596. 10.1111/1467-937X.00198CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartling, B., Fehr, E., Huffman, D., & Netzer, N. (2018). “The causal effect of trust,” University of Zurich, Department of Economics, working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernard, M, Fanning, J, & Yuksel, S (2018). Finding cooperators: Sorting through repeated interaction. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 147, 7694. 10.1016/j.jebo.2017.11.016CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, Cooper, DJ, & Weber, RA (2014). Legitimacy, communication, and leadership in the turnaround game. Management Science, 61, 26272645. 10.1287/mnsc.2014.2021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, M, Falk, A, & Fehr, E (2004). Relational contracts and the nature of market interactions. Econometrica, 72, 747780. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2004.00511.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cajner, T., Crane, L. D., Decker, R. A., Grigsby, J., Hamins-Puertolas, A., Hurst, E., Kurz, C., & Yildirmaz, A. (2020). “The US labor market during the beginning of the pandemic recession,” Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, CF (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Chaudhuri, A (2018). Belief heterogeneity and the restart effect in a public goods game. Games, 9, 96 10.3390/g9040096CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chevalier, J, & Ellison, G (1997). Risk taking by mutual funds as a response to incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 11671200. 10.1086/516389CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, R (1996). Partners and strangers revisited. Economics Letters, 53, 2532. 10.1016/S0165-1765(97)82136-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, SJ, & Haltiwanger, J (1992). Gross job creation, gross job destruction, and employment reallocation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 819863. 10.2307/2118365CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Tella, R, MacCulloch, RJ, & Oswald, AJ (2001). Preferences over inflation and unemployment: Evidence from surveys of happiness. American Economic Review, 91, 335341. 10.1257/aer.91.1.335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eisenberg, P, & Lazarsfeld, PF (1938). The psychological effects of unemployment. Psychological Bulletin, 35, 358 10.1037/h0063426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Zehnder, C. (2009). “Reputation and credit market formation: How relational incentives and legal contract enforcement interact,” University of Zurich, Department of Economics, working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fréchette, GR (2012). Session-effects in the laboratory. Experimental Economics, 15, 485498. 10.1007/s10683-011-9309-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrera, J., & Shady, G. D. R. (2005). “Labor Market Transitions in Peru,” Technical report, Ibero-America Institute for Economic Research.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D, & Krueger, AB (2006). Developments in the measurement of subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20, 324. 10.1257/089533006776526030CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazear, EP, Shaw, KL, & Stanton, C (2016). Making do with less: Working harder during recessions. Journal of Labor Economics, 34, 333360. 10.1086/682406CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linardi, S, & McConnell, MA (2011). No excuses for good behavior: Volunteering and the social environment. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 445454. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.06.020CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindbeck, A, & Snower, DJ (2001). Insiders versus outsiders. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 165188. 10.1257/jep.15.1.165CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, RE, Clark, AE, Georgellis, Y, & Diener, E (2004). Unemployment alters the set point for life satisfaction. Psychological Science, 15, 813. 10.1111/j.0963-7214.2004.01501002.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Macchiavello, R, & Morjaria, A (2015). The value of relationships: Evidence from a supply shock to Kenyan rose exports. American Economic Review, 105, 2911–45 10.1257/aer.20120141CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palfrey, TR, & Prisbrey, JE (1997). Anomalous behavior in public goods experiments: How much and why?. The American Economic Review, 87, 829846.Google Scholar
Paul, KI, & Moser, K (2009). Unemployment impairs mental health: Meta-analyses. Journal of Vocational Behavior, 74, 264282. 10.1016/j.jvb.2009.01.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Renner, E, & Tyran, J-R (2004). Price rigidity in customer markets. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55, 575593. 10.1016/j.jebo.2003.11.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rute Cardoso, A, & Portela, M (2009). Micro foundations for wage flexibility: Wage insurance at the firm level. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 111, 2950. 10.1111/j.1467-9442.2008.01553.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Huyck, JB, Battalio, RC, & Beil, RO (1990). Tacit coordination games, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure. The American Economic Review, 80, 234248.Google Scholar
Van Huyck, JB, Battalio, RC, & Beil, RO (1991). Strategic uncertainty, equilibrium selection, and coordination failure in average opinion games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 885910. 10.2307/2937932CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, OE, Wachter, ML, & Harris, JE (1975). Understanding the employment relation: The analysis of idiosyncratic exchange. The Bell Journal of Economics, 6, 250278. 10.2307/3003224CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Linardi and Camerer supplementary material

Appendix
Download Linardi and Camerer supplementary material(File)
File 402.4 KB