Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dkgms Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T23:10:17.421Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Status and the demand for visible goods: experimental evidence on conspicuous consumption

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

David Clingingsmith*
Affiliation:
Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University, 11119 Bellflower Road, Cleveland, OH 44106, USA
Roman M. Sheremeta
Affiliation:
Weatherhead School of Management, Case Western Reserve University, 11119 Bellflower Road, Cleveland, OH 44106, USA Economic Science Institute, Chapman University, One University Drive, Orange, CA 92866, USA

Abstract

Some economists argue that consumption of publicly visible goods is driven by social status. Making a causal inference about this claim is difficult with observational data. We conduct an experiment in which we vary both whether a purchase of a physical product is publicly visible or kept private and whether the income used for purchase is linked to social status or randomly assigned. Making consumption choices visible leads to a large increase in demand when income is linked to status, but not otherwise. We investigate the characteristics that mediate this effect and estimate its impact on welfare.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2017 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9556-x) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Andreoni, J, & Bernheim, BD (2009). Social image and the 50–50 norm: A theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects. Econometrica, 77, 16071636. 10.3982/ECTA7384Google Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Petrie, R (2004). Public goods experiments without confidentiality: A glimpse into fund-raising. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 16051623. 10.1016/S0047-2727(03)00040-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ariely, D, Bracha, A, & Meier, S (2009). Doing good or doing well? Image motivation and monetary incentives in behaving prosocially. American Economic Review, 90, 544555. 10.1257/aer.99.1.544CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bagwell, LS, & Bernheim, BD (1996). Veblen effects in a theory of conspicuous consumption. American Economic Review, 86, 349373.Google Scholar
Benabou, R, & Tirole, J (2006). Incentives and prosocial behavior. American Economic Review, 99, 544555.Google Scholar
Benjamin, DJ, Heffetz, O, Kimball, MS, & Rees-Jones, A (2012). What do you think would make you happier? What do you think you would choose?. American Economic Review, 102, 20832110. 10.1257/aer.102.5.2083CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bracha, A, & Vesterlund, L (2017). Mixed signals: Charity reporting when donations signal generosity and income. Games and Economic Behavior, 104, 2442. 10.1016/j.geb.2017.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, TN, Masters, WA, & Sheremeta, RM (2010). Entry into winner-take-all and proportional-prize contests: An experimental study. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 604611. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.05.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charles, KK, Hurst, E, & Roussanov, N (2009). Conspicuous consumption and race. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 425467. 10.1162/qjec.2009.124.2.425CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, Masclet, D, & Villeval, MC (2013). The dark side of competition for status. Management Science, 60, 3855. 10.1287/mnsc.2013.1747CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Rabin, M (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 817869. 10.1162/003355302760193904CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, V, & Sobel, J (1982). Strategic information transmission. Econometrica, 50, 14311452. 10.2307/1913390CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, R, & Gneezy, U (2009). Gender differences in preferences. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 448474. 10.1257/jel.47.2.448CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dechenaux, E, Kovenock, D, & Sheremeta, RM (2015). A survey of experimental research on contests, all-pay auctions and tournaments. Experimental Economics, 18, 609669. 10.1007/s10683-014-9421-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dohmen, T, & Falk, A (2011). Performance pay and multidimensional sorting: Productivity, preferences, and gender. American Economic Review, 101, 556590. 10.1257/aer.101.2.556CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duesenberry, J (1949). Income, saving, and the theory of consumer behavior, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Feltovich, N, Harbaugh, R, & To, T (2002). Too cool for school? Signaling and countersignalling. RAND Journal of Economics, 33, 630649. 10.2307/3087478CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, RH (1999). Luxury fever: Money and happiness in an era of excess, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Frank, RH (2008). Should public policy respond to positional externalities?. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 17771786. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2008.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 2542. 10.1257/089533005775196732CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, EL, Gottlieb, JD, & Ziv, O (2016). Unhappy cities. Journal of Labor Economics, 34, 129182. 10.1086/684044CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Glazer, A, & Konrad, KA (1996). A signaling explanation for charity. American Economic Review, 86, 10191028.Google Scholar
Grinblatt, M, Keloharju, M, & Ikäheimo, S (2008). Social influence and consumption: Evidence from the automobile purchases of neighbors. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90, 735753. 10.1162/rest.90.4.735CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heffetz, O (2011). A test of conspicuous consumption: Visibility and income elasticities. Review of Economics and Statistics, 93, 11011117. 10.1162/REST_a_00116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heffetz, O, Frank, R Bisin, A, Jackson, M, & Benhabib, J (2011). Preferences for Status: Evidence and Economic Implications. Handbook of Social Economics, Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Holt, CA, & Laury, SK (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92, 16441655. 10.1257/000282802762024700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopkins, E, & Kornienko, T (2004). Running to keep in the same place: Consumer choice as a game of status. American Economic Review, 94, 10851107. 10.1257/0002828042002705CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huberman, BA, Loch, CH, & Önçüler, A (2004). Status as a valued resource. Social Psychology Quarterly, 67, 103114. 10.1177/019027250406700109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D, Diener, E, & Schwarz, N (1999). Well-being: The foundations of hedonic psychology, New York: Russell Sage Found.Google Scholar
Karlan, D, & McConnell, MA (2014). Hey look at me: The effect of giving circles on giving. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 106, 402412. 10.1016/j.jebo.2014.06.013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kimball, M.S., & Willis, R. (2006). Utility and happiness. Unpublished Manuscript.Google Scholar
Kosfeld, M, & Neckermann, S (2011). Getting more work for nothing? Symbolic awards and worker performance. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 3, 8699.Google Scholar
Kuhn, P, Kooreman, P, Soetevent, A, & Kapteyn, A (2011). The effects of lottery prizes on winners and their neighbors: Evidence from the Dutch postcode lottery. American Economic Review, 101, 22262247. 10.1257/aer.101.5.2226CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leibenstein, H (1950). Bandwagon, snob, and Veblen effects in the theory of consumers’ demand. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64, 183207. 10.2307/1882692CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Niederle, M, & Vesterlund, L (2007). Do women shy away from competition? Do men compete too much?. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122, 10671101. 10.1162/qjec.122.3.1067CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pan, XS, & Houser, D (2011). Competition for trophies triggers male generosity. PLoS ONE, 6(4), e18050 10.1371/journal.pone.0018050CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ravina, E. (2007). Habit formation and keeping up with the Joneses: Evidence from micro data. Working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Royston, P, & Altman, DG (1994). Regression using fractional polynomials of continuous covariates: Parsimonious parametric modelling. Applied Statistics, 43, 429467. 10.2307/2986270CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samek, AS, & Sheremeta, RM (2014). Recognizing contributors: An experiment on public goods. Experimental Economics, 17, 673690. 10.1007/s10683-013-9389-1Google Scholar
Samek, AS, & Sheremeta, RM (2017). Selective recognition: How to recognize donors to increase charitable giving. Economic Inquiry, 55, 14891496. 10.1111/ecin.12448CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seltzer, N. (2009). 1,014 GRE practice questions. Princeton Review.Google Scholar
Sheremeta, R.M. (2016). Impulsive behavior in competition: Testing theories of overbidding in rent-seeking contests. Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sivanathan, N, & Pettit, NC (2010). Protecting the self through consumption: Status goods as affirmational commodities. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 46, 564570. 10.1016/j.jesp.2010.01.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A. (1776). The Wealth of Nations. Reprint 1976. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Soetevent, A (2005). Anonymity in giving in a natural context—a field experiment in 30 churches. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 23012323. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.11.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, M (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87, 355374. 10.2307/1882010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of the leisure class: An economic study in the evolution of institutions. Reprint 2009. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Clingingsmith and Sheremeta supplementary material

Appendices A and B
Download Clingingsmith and Sheremeta supplementary material(File)
File 51.1 KB