Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-wdhn8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-17T00:18:37.165Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Nice to you, nicer to me: Does self-serving generosity diminish the reciprocal response?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Daniel Woods*
Affiliation:
Purdue University, Krannert School of Management, West Lafayette, IN, USA
Maroš Servátka*
Affiliation:
Macquarie Graduate School of Management, Sydney, Australia University of Economics, Bratislava, Slovakia

Abstract

Reciprocity has been shown to be sensitive to perceived intentions, however, not much is known about the intensity of reciprocal responses to the precise nature of those intentions. For example, a person can strategically appear to be kind while being self-serving or can be selflessly (genuinely) kind. Do these two intentions elicit different reciprocal reactions? We propose a conjecture that self-serving but generous actions diminish the positively reciprocal response, compared to selfless generous actions. We classify actions that increase a recipient’s maximum payoff, but by less than the giver’s maximum payoff, as being self-serving generous actions, while classifying actions that increase a recipient’s maximum payoff by more than the giver’s as selfless generous actions. We hypothesize that selfless generous actions are considered more generous than self-serving generous actions, and that self-serving generous actions will therefore result in a diminished reciprocal response. We test this conjecture using two novel experimental designs. We find some evidence that subjects perceive self-serving generous actions as being less generous than selfless generous actions, but no empirical support for our conjecture on the diminished reciprocal response.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2018 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-018-9561-8) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

If you’re helping someone and expecting something in return, you’re doing business not kindness.

Unknown.

References

Andreoni, J, Harbaugh, W, & Vesterlund, L (2003). The carrot or the stick: Rewards, punishments, and cooperation. American Economic Review, 93(3), 893902. 10.1257/000282803322157142CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Miller, J (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for Altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737753. 10.1111/1468-0262.00302CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardsley, N (2008). Dictator game giving: Altruism or artefact?. Experimental Economics, 11(2), 122133. 10.1007/s10683-007-9172-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J, Dickhaut, J, & McCabe, K (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122142. 10.1006/game.1995.1027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blount, S (1995). When social outcomes aren’t fair: The effect of causal attributions on preferences. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 63(2), 131144. 10.1006/obhd.1995.1068CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, GE, & Ockenfels, A (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166193. 10.1257/aer.90.1.166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, & Charness, G (2011). The strategy versus the direct-response method: A first survey of experimental comparisons. Experimental Economics, 14, 375398. 10.1007/s10683-011-9272-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruni, L, Corazzini, L, & Stanca, L (2009). Testing theories of reciprocity: Do motivations matter?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 71(2), 233245. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.04.009Google Scholar
Camerer, CF (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cappelen, AW, Nielsen, UH, Sørensen, , Tungodden, B, & Tyran, J-R (2013). Give and take in dictator games. Economic Letters, 118(2), 280283. 10.1016/j.econlet.2012.10.030CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, GB (2004). Attribution and reciprocity in an experimental labor market. Journal of Labor Economics, 22(3), 665688. 10.1086/383111CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Dufwenberg, M (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74(6), 15791601. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00719.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaudhuri, A (2008). Experiments in economics: Playing fair with money, London: Routledge 10.4324/9780203884799CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC (2004). How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46, 260281. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00119-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, & Deck, CA (2005). On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43(3), 623635. 10.1093/ei/cbi043CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, & Deck, CA (2006). Assigning intentions when actions are unobservable: The impact of trembling in the trust game. Southern Economic Journal, 73(2), 307314. 10.2307/20111893Google Scholar
Cox, JC, Friedman, D, & Gjerstad, S (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59(1), 1745. 10.1016/j.geb.2006.05.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, Friedman, D, & Sadiraj, V (2008). Revealed Altruism. Econometrica, 76(1), 3169. 10.1111/j.0012-9682.2008.00817.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C., List, J., Price, M., Sadiraj, V., & Samek, A. (2016). Moral costs and rational choice: Theory and experimental evidence. Working paper 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, Sadiraj, K, & Sadiraj, V (2008). Implications of trust, fear, and reciprocity for modelling economic behavior. Experimental Economics, 11(1), 124. 10.1007/s10683-006-9156-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, Servátka, M, & Vadovič, R (2010). Saliency of outside options in the lost wallet game. Experimental Economics, 13(1), 6674. 10.1007/s10683-009-9229-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, Servátka, M, & Vadovič, R (2017). Status quo effects in fairness games: Reciprocal responses to acts of commission vs. acts of omission. Experimental Economics, 20, 118. 10.1007/s10683-016-9477-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M, & Gneezy, U (2000). Measuring beliefs in an experimental lost wallet game. Games and Economic Behavior, 30(2), 163182. 10.1006/game.1999.0715CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M, & Kirchsteiger, G (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), 268298. 10.1016/j.geb.2003.06.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M, Servátka, M, & Vadovič, R (2017). Honesty and informal agreements. Games and Economic Behavior, 102(2017), 269285. 10.1016/j.geb.2016.12.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A, Fehr, E, & Fischbacher, U (2008). Testing theories of fairness—Intentions matter. Games and Economic Behavior, 62(1), 287303. 10.1016/j.geb.2007.06.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A, & Fischbacher, U (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54(2), 293315. 10.1016/j.geb.2005.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & Gächter, S (2000). Fairness and retaliation: The economics of reciprocity. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159181. 10.1257/jep.14.3.159CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & Schmidt, KM (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817868. 10.1162/003355399556151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, Schmidt, KM Kolm, S, & Ythier, JM (2006). The economics of fairness, reciprocity and Altruism—Experimental evidence and new theories. Handbook of the economics of giving, Altruism and reciprocity, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaechter, S, & Renner, E (2010). The effects of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(3), 364377. 10.1007/s10683-010-9246-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U, Güth, W, & Verboven, F (2000). Presents or investments? An experimental analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 21(5), 481493. 10.1016/S0167-4870(00)00015-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114125. 10.1007/s40881-015-0004-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinz, J., & Nicklisch, A. (2015). Reciprocity models revisited: Intention factors and reference value. Hamburg Wiso Working Paper Series 2015/25.Google Scholar
Johnson, ND, & Mislin, AA (2011). Trust games: A meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 32, 865889. 10.1016/j.joep.2011.05.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kritikos, A, & Bolle, F (2004). Approaching fair behavior: Distributional and reciprocal preferences. Research on Economic Inequality, 11, 149181. 10.1016/S1049-2585(04)11008-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Likert, R (1932). A technique for the measurement of attitudes. Archives of Psychology, 22(140), 555.Google Scholar
McCabe, K, Rigdon, M, & Smith, V (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 52, 267275. 10.1016/S0167-2681(03)00003-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offerman, T (2002). Hurting hurts more than helping helps. European Economic Review, 46(8), 14231437. 10.1016/S0014-2921(01)00176-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. American Economic Review, 83(5), 12811302.Google Scholar
Schlag, K, Tremewan, J, & van der Weele, J (2015). A penny for your thoughts: A survey of methods for eliciting beliefs. Experimental Economics, 18(3), 457490. 10.1007/s10683-014-9416-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sebald, A (2010). Attribution and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 68(1), 339352. 10.1016/j.geb.2009.07.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R, & Sauermann, H (1967). Die Strategiemethode zur Erforshung des eingeschränkt rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments. Beiträge zur experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung, Tübingen: Mohr 136168.Google Scholar
Servátka, M, & Vadovič, R (2009). Unequal outside options in the lost wallet game. Economics Bulletin, 29(4), 28702883.Google Scholar
Sobel, J. (2005). Interdependent preferences and reciprocity. Journal of Economic Literature, 43, 392436.e.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woods, D. (2013). Does self-serving generosity diminish reciprocal behaviour. (M.Com.), University of Canterbury, Christchurch.Google Scholar
Woods, D, & Servátka, M (2016). Testing psychological forward induction and the updating of beliefs in the lost wallet game. Journal of Economic Psychology, 56, 116125. 10.1016/j.joep.2016.06.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Woods and Servátka supplementary material

Woods and Servátka supplementary material
Download Woods and Servátka supplementary material(File)
File 148 KB