Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-f9bf7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-14T18:59:16.622Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Learning to respect property by refashioning theft into trade

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Erik O. Kimbrough*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics (AE1), School of Business and Economics, Maastricht University, P.O. Box 616, 6200 MD Maastricht, The Netherlands
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Agent-based simulations and human-subject experiments explore the emergence of respect for property in a specialization and exchange economy with costless theft. Software agents, driven by reciprocity and hill-climbing heuristics and parameterized to replicate humans when property is exogenously protected, are employed to predict human behavior when property can be freely appropriated. Agents do not predict human behavior in a new set of experiments because subjects innovate, constructing a property convention of “mutual taking” in 5 out of the 6 experimental sessions that allows exchange to crowd out theft. When the same convention is made available to agents, they adopt it and again replicate human behavior. Property emerges as a social convention that exploits the capacity for reciprocity to sustain trade.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NC
This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Noncommercial License (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/2.0), which permits any noncommercial use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author(s) and source are credited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s) 2010

Footnotes

Data, simulation code, and CSW experiment instructions available upon request. All simulations, data analysis, and figures were performed or created in R: A language and Environment for Statistical Computing (R Development Core Team 2010) with assistance from various contributed packages including: Bengtsson (2003), Berkelaar et al. (2008), Henningsen (2008), Neuwirth (2007), and Warnes et al. (2008).

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:10.1007/s10683-010-9258-0) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Arifovic, J., & Ledyard, J. O. (2004). Scaling up learning models in public good games. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 6, 203238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, W. B. (1991). Designing economic agents that act like human agents: a behavioral approach to bounded rationality. The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 81(2), 353359.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1997). The complexity of cooperation: agent-based models of competition and collaboration. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bengtsson, H. (2003). The R.oo package—object-oriented programming with references using standard R code. In Hornik, K., Leisch, F., & Zeilis, A. (Eds.), Proceedings of the 3rd international workshop on distributed statistical computing. Vienna, Austria.Google Scholar
Bentham, J. (1802). The theory of legislation. London: Kegan Paul. C.K. Ogden (Ed.) (1931).Google Scholar
Berkelaar, M. et al. (2008). lpSolve: interface to Lp_solve v. 5.5 to solve linear/integer programs. R package version 5.6.4.Google Scholar
Bernhard, H., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). Group affiliation and altruistic norm enforcement. American Economic Review, 96(2), 217221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloor, D. (2002). Wittgenstein, rules and institutions. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buckle, S. (1991). Natural law and the theory of property: Grotius to Hume. Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Crockett, S., Smith, V. L., & Wilson, B. J. (2009). Exchange and specialisation as a discovery process. Economic Journal, 119(539), 11621188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J. (2001). Learning to speculate: experiments with artificial and real agents. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 25, 295319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Gachter, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: the economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henningsen, A. (2008). micEcon: Microeconomics. R package version 0.5-6.Google Scholar
Howitt, P., & Clower, R. (2000). The emergence of economic organization. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 41, 5584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hume, D. (2000). A treatise of human nature (1740). New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kimbrough, E. O. (Forthcoming). Heuristic learning and the discovery of specialization and exchange. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control.Google Scholar
Kimbrough, E. O., Smith, V. L., & Wilson, B. J. (2010). Exchange, theft, and the social formation of property. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 74, 206229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levine, D. K. (1998). Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1(3), 593622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levine, R. (2005). Law, endowments, and property rights. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(3), 6188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neuwirth, E. (2007). RColorBrewer: ColorBrewer palettes. R package version 1.0-2.Google Scholar
R Development Core Team (2010). R: a language and environment for statistical computing. Vienna: R Foundation for Statistical Computing. ISBN 3-900051-07-0. http://www.R-project.org.Google Scholar
Skyrms, B. (2004). The stag hunt and the evolution of social structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1974). Experimental economics: induced value theory. The American Economic Review, 66(2), 274279.Google Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1982). Microeconomic systems as an experimental science. The American Economic Review, 72(5), 923955.Google Scholar
Warnes, G. R., Bolker, B., & Lumley, T. (2008). gtools: various R programming tools. R package version 2.5.0.Google Scholar
Westermarck, E. (1908). The origin and development of the moral ideas. Whitefish: Kessinger (2007).Google Scholar
Wyman, K. M. (2005). From fur to fish: reconsidering the evolution of private property. New York University Law Review, 80, 117240.Google Scholar
Young, H. P. (1993). The evolution of conventions. Econometrica, 61(1), 5784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. P. (1996). The economics of convention. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(2), 105122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Kimbrough supplementary material

Kimbrough supplementary material
Download Kimbrough supplementary material(File)
File 492.3 KB