Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dkgms Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T13:28:52.122Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Kindness, confusion, or … ambiguity?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Carmela Di Mauro
Affiliation:
D.A.P.P.S.I, Università degli Studi di Catania, Catania, Italy
Massimo Finocchiaro Castro*
Affiliation:
DSSGES, Department of Historical, Legal, Economic and Social Studies, Università degli Studi Mediterranea di Reggio Calabria, via Campanella 38/A, 89125 Reggio Calabria, Italy

Abstract

Other-regarding preferences or decision errors are the main explanations put forward to justify contributions exceeding the non-cooperative optimum in VCM games. An alternative rationale relies on ambiguity aversion. Ambiguity aversion increases the perceived marginal benefit of own contributions, which in equilibrium will exceed the Nash level. We present a series of experiments testing this hypothesis. To control for other-regarding preferences, we run a two-player game in which a human player plays with a virtual agent. Players are assigned either to a risky setting (known probabilities of opponent's choices) or to an ambiguity setting (probabilities of opponent's contribution are vague). Results show that ambiguity affects contributions. However, attitude to ambiguity appears to be affected by the location of the aggregate Nash optimum inside the decision space.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2011 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi: 10.1007/s10683-011-9284-6) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Abdellaoui, M., Baillon, A., Placido, L., & Wakker, P. P. (2010). The rich domain of uncertainty: source functions and their experimental implementation. American Economic Review, 101(2), 695723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, S. P., Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (1998). A theoretical analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 70, 297323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in public goods experiments: kindness or confusion? The American Economic Review, 85, 891904.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, D. (1980). Individual contributions to public goods. Economics Letters, 5, 359361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C., & Karjalainen, R. (1994). Ambiguity-aversion and non-additive beliefs in non-cooperative games: experimental evidence. In Munier, B. & Machina, M. (Eds.), Models and experiments in risk and rationality (pp. 325358). Norwell: Kluwer Academic.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C., & Weber, M. (1992). Recent developments in modeling preferences: uncertainty and ambiguity. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 325370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chateauneuf, A., Eichberger, J., & Grant, S. (2007). Choice under uncertainty with the best and the worst in mind. Journal of Economic Theory, 137, 538567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, M., Jaffray, J. Y., & Said, T. (1985). Individual behaviour under risk and under uncertainty: an experimental study. Theory and Decision, 18, 203–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D. D., & Holt, C. A. (1993). Experimental economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Mauro, C. (2008). Uncertainty aversion vs. competence: an experimental market study. Theory and Decision, 64(2), 301331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Mauro, C., & Maffioletti, A. (2004). Attitudes to risk and attitudes to uncertainty: experimental evidence. Applied Economics, 36, 357372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichberger, J., & Kelsey, D. (2002). Strategic complements, substitutes and ambiguity: the implications for public goods. Journal of Economic Theory, 106, 436466.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichberger, J., & Kelsey, D. (2009, forthcoming). Are the treasures of game theory ambiguous? Economic Theory.Google Scholar
Eichberger, J., Kelsey, D., & Schipper, B. C. (2008). Granny versus game theorist: ambiguity in experimental games. Theory and Decision, 64(2), 333362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichberger, J., Kelsey, D., & Schipper, B. C. (2009). Ambiguity and social interaction. Oxford Economic Papers, 61, 355379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellsberg, D. (1961). Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axiom. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75, 643669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferraro, P., Rondeau, D., & Poe, G. L. (2003). Detecting other-regarding behavior with virtual players. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 51, 99109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, C. R., & Tversky, A. (1995). Ambiguity aversion and comparative ignorance. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 585603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghirardato, P., & Marinacci, M. (2002). Ambiguity made precise: a comparative foundation. Journal of Economic Theory, 102, 251289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilboa, I., & Schmeidler, D. (1989). Maxmin expected utility with a non-unique prior. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 18, 141153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goeree, J. K., Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Private costs and public benefits: unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 83, 255276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halevy, Y. (2007). Ellsberg revisited: an experimental study. Econometrica, 75(2), 503536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heinemann, F., Nagel, R., & Ockenfels, P. (2009). Measuring strategic uncertainty in coordination games. Review of Economic Studies, 76(1), 181221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hogarth, R. M., & Einhorn, H. J. (1990). Venture theory: a model of decision weights. Management Science, 36(7), 780803.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houser, D., & Kurzban, R. (2002). Revisiting kindness and confusion in public goods experiments. The American Economic Review, 92(4), 10621069.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R. M., & Walker, J. M. (1998). Nash as an organising principle in the voluntary provision of public goods: experimental evidence. Experimental Economics, 1, 191206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R. M., McCue, K., & Plott, C. (1985). Public goods provision in an experimental environment. Journal of Public Economics, 26, 174.Google Scholar
Keppe, H., & Weber, M. (1995). Judged knowledge and ambiguity aversion. Theory and Decision, 39, 5177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keser, C. (1996). Voluntary contributions to a public good when partial contributions is a dominant strategy. Economics Letters, 50(3), 359366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laury, S. K., & Holt, C. (2008). Voluntary provision of public goods: experimental results with interior Nash equilibria. In Plott, C. & Smith, V. (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economic results. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Laury, S. K., Walker, J. M., & Williams, A. W. (1999). The voluntary provision of a pure public good with diminishing marginal returns. Public Choice, 99, 139160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ledyard, J. O. (1995). Public goods: a survey of experimental research. In Kagel, J. & Roth, A. E. (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics (pp. 111194). Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., & Palfrey, T. R. (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., McLennan, A. D., & Turocy, T. L. (2007). Gambit: software tools for game theory. Version 0.2007.01.30. http://gambit.sourceforge.net.Google Scholar
Palfrey, T., & Prisbrey, J. (1997). Anomalous behavior in linear public goods experiments: how much and why? The American Economic Review, 87(5), 829846.Google Scholar
Sandier, T., Sterbenz, F., & Posnett, J. (1987). Free riding and uncertainty. European Economic Review, 31, 16051617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sarin, R., & Weber, M. (1993). Effects of ambiguity in market experiments. Management Science, 39, 602615.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmeidler, D. (1989). Subjective probability and expected utility without additivity. Econometrica, 57, 571787.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sefton, M., & Steinberg, R. (1996). Reward structures in public good experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 61, 263287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Dijk, F., Sonnemans, J., & van Winden, F. (2002). Social ties in a public good experiment. Journal of Public Economics, 85, 275299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, K., & Chesson, H. (1999). Hopes and fears: the conflicting effects of risk ambiguity. Theory and Decision, 47, 153–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wakker, P. (2001). Testing and characterizing properties of non-additive measures through violations of the sure-thing principle. Econometrica, 69, 10391059.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Mauro and Castro supplementary material

Mauro and Castro supplementary material
Download Mauro and Castro supplementary material(File)
File 109.1 KB