Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dkgms Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-17T00:03:29.027Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Individualism, collectivism, and trade

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Aidin Hajikhameneh*
Affiliation:
Institute for the Study of Religion, Economics and Society, Chapman University, 338 N. Glassell, Orange, CA 92866, USA
Erik O. Kimbrough*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University, 8888 University Drive, Burnaby, BC V5A 1S6, Canada Smith Institute for Political Economy and Philosophy, Chapman University, One University Drive, Orange, CA 92866, USA

Abstract

While economists recognize the important role of formal institutions in the promotion of trade, there is increasing agreement that institutions are typically endogenous to culture, making it difficult to disentangle their separate contributions. Lab experiments that assign institutions exogenously and measure and control individual cultural characteristics can allow for clean identification of the effects of institutions, conditional on culture, and help us understand the relationship between behavior and culture, under a given institutional framework. We focus on cultural tendencies toward individualism/collectivism, which social psychologists highlight as an important determinant of many behavioral differences across groups and people. We design an experiment to explore the relationship between subjects’ degree of individualism/collectivism and their willingness to abandon a repeated, bilateral exchange relationship in order to seek potentially more lucrative trade with a stranger, under enforcement institutions of varying strength. Overall, we find that individualists tend to seek out trade more often than collectivists. A diagnostic treatment and additional analysis suggests that this difference may reflect both differential altruism/favoritism to in-group members and different reactions to having been cheated in the past. This difference is mitigated somewhat as the effectiveness of enforcement institutions increases. Nevertheless we see that cultural dispositions are associated with willingness to seek out trade, regardless of institutional environment.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2017 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9560-1) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Berg, J, Dickhaut, J, & McCabe, K (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 122142. 10.1006/game.1995.1027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernhard, H, Fischbacher, U, & Fehr, E (2006). Parochial altruism in humans. Nature, 442(7105), 912915. 10.1038/nature04981CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bohnet, I, Frey, BS, & Huck, S (2001). More order with less law: On contract enforcement, trust, and crowding. American Political Science Review, 95(1), 131144. 10.1017/S0003055401000211CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, I, Greig, F, Herrmann, B, & Zeckhauser, R (2008). Betrayal a version: Evidence from Brazil, China, Oman, Switzerland, Turkey, and the USA. American Economic Review, 98, 294310. 10.1257/aer.98.1.294CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, I, Harmgart, H, Tyran, J-R et al., (2005). Learning trust. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3(2–3), 322329. 10.1162/jeea.2005.3.2-3.322CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, I, & Huck, S (2004). Repetition and reputation: Implications for trust and trustworthiness when institutions change. American Economic Review, 94(2), 362366. 10.1257/0002828041301506CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cassar, A, d’Adda, G, & Grosjean, P (2014). Institutional quality, culture, and norms of cooperation: Evidence from behavioral field experiments. The Journal of Law and Economics, 57(3), 821863. 10.1086/678331CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cassar, A, Friedman, D, & Schneider, PH (2010). A laboratory investigation of networked markets. The Economic Journal, 120(547), 919943. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2009.02326.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, Du, N, & Yang, C-L (2011). Trust and trustworthiness reputations in an investment game. Games and Economic Behavior, 72(2), 361375. 10.1016/j.geb.2010.09.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiu, L-H (1972). A cross-cultural comparison of cognitive styles in Chinese and American children. International Journal of Psychology, 7(4), 235242. 10.1080/00207597208246604CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC (2004). How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46(2), 260281. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00119-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, JC, & Deck, CA (2005). On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43(3), 623635. 10.1093/ei/cbi043CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, CC, & Wilson, RK (2004). Is trust a risky decision?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55(4), 447465. 10.1016/j.jebo.2003.11.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farias, M, & Lalljee, M (2008). Holistic individualism in the age of aquarius: Measuring individualism/collectivism in new age, catholic, and atheist/agnostic groups. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 47(2), 277289. 10.1111/j.1468-5906.2008.00407.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E (2009). On the economics and biology of trust. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2–3), 235266. 10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.2-3.235CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & Fischbacher, U (2004). Third-party punishment and social norms. Evolution and Human Behavior, 25(2), 6387. 10.1016/S1090-5138(04)00005-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & List, JA (2004). The hidden costs and returns of incentives-trust and trustworthiness among ceos. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(5), 743771. 10.1162/1542476042782297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & Rockenbach, B (2003). Detrimental effects of sanctions on human altruism. Nature, 422(6928), 137140. 10.1038/nature01474CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, EG, Deschamps, J-C, & Paez, D (2005). Variation of individualism and collectivism within and between 20 countries a typological analysis. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 36(3), 321339. 10.1177/0022022104273654CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist societies. Journal of Political Economy, 102, 912950. 10.1086/261959CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A (2000). The fundamental problem of exchange: A research agenda in historical institutional analysis. European Review of Economic History, 4(03), 251284. 10.1017/S1361491600000071CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hajikhameneh, A. (Working paper). Individualism, collectivism, and alternative enforcement mechanisms in exchange.Google Scholar
Hakim, N, Simons, DJ, Zhao, H, & Wan, X (2017). Do easterners and westerners differ in visual cognition? A preregistered examination of three visual cognition tasks. Social Psychological and Personality Science, 8, 142152. 10.1177/1948550616667613CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Healy, PJ (2007). Group reputations, stereotypes, and cooperation in a repeated labor market. American Economic Review, 97(5), 17511773. 10.1257/aer.97.5.1751CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J (2014). Rice, psychology, and innovation. Science, 344(6184), 593594. 10.1126/science.1253815CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hofstede, G (1980). Culture’s consequences, Beverly Hills: Sage.Google Scholar
Holt, C, & Laury, S (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 16441655. 10.1257/000282802762024700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houser, D, Schunk, D, & Winter, J (2010). Distinguishing trust from risk: An anatomy of the investment game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 74(1), 7281. 10.1016/j.jebo.2010.01.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huck, S, & Lünser, GK (2010). Group reputations: An experimental foray. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 73(2), 153157. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.09.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hui, CH, & Triandis, HC (1986). Individualism-collectivism a study of cross-cultural researchers. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 17(2), 225248. 10.1177/0022002186017002006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ji, L-J, Zhang, Z, & Nisbett, RE (2004). Is it culture or is it language? Examination of language effects in cross-cultural research on categorization. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87(1), 57 10.1037/0022-3514.87.1.57CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Johnson, ND, & Mislin, AA (2011). Trust games: A meta-analysis. Journal of Economic Psychology, 32(5), 865889. 10.1016/j.joep.2011.05.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlan, DS (2005). Using experimental economics to measure social capital and predict financial decisions. American Economic Review, 95, 16881699. 10.1257/000282805775014407CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karni, E (2009). A mechanism for eliciting probabilities. Econometrica, 77(2), 603606. 10.3982/ECTA7833Google Scholar
Kimbrough, EO, & Rubin, J (2015). Sustaining group reputation. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 31(3), 599628. 10.1093/jleo/ewu019CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kimbrough, EO, & Vostroknutov, A (2016). Norms make preferences social. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(3), 608638. 10.1111/jeea.12152CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kitayama, S, Duffy, S, Kawamura, T, & Larsen, JT (2003). Perceiving an object and its context in different cultures a cultural look at new look. Psychological Science, 14(3), 201206. 10.1111/1467-9280.02432CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kitayama, S, Park, H, Sevincer, AT, Karasawa, M, & Uskul, AK (2009). A cultural task analysis of implicit independence: Comparing north America, Western Europe, and East Asia. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 97(2), 236 10.1037/a0015999CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kreps, DM, Milgrom, P, Roberts, J, & Wilson, R (1982). Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners’ dilemma. Journal of Economic Theory, 27(2), 245252. 10.1016/0022-0531(82)90029-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krupka, EL, & Weber, RA (2013). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary?. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 495524. 10.1111/jeea.12006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, T (2010). Institutional causes of economic underdevelopment in the middle east: A historical perspective. Research of Institutional Economics, 3, 16.Google Scholar
Leibbrandt, A, Gneezy, U, & List, JA (2013). Rise and fall of competitiveness in individualistic and collectivistic societies. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110(23), 93059308. 10.1073/pnas.1300431110CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Markus, HR, & Kitayama, S (1991). Culture and the self: Implications for cognition, emotion, and motivation. Psychological Review, 98(2), 224 10.1037/0033-295X.98.2.224CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, KA, Rigdon, ML, & Smith, VL (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in trust games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 52(2), 267275. 10.1016/S0167-2681(03)00003-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nisbett, RE, Peng, K, Choi, I, & Norenzayan, A (2001). Culture and systems of thought: Holistic versus analytic cognition. Psychological Review, 108(2), 291 10.1037/0033-295X.108.2.291CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
North, DC (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 10.1017/CBO9780511808678CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborn, J, Wilson, BJ, & Sherwood, BR (2015). Conduct in narrativized trust games. Southern Economic Journal, 81(3), 562597. 10.4284/0038-4038-2013.292CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oyserman, D, Coon, HM, & Kemmelmeier, M (2002). Rethinking individualism and collectivism: Evaluation of theoretical assumptions and meta-analyses. Psychological Bulletin, 128(1), 372. 10.1037/0033-2909.128.1.3CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
R Development Core Team. (2012). R: A language and environment for statistical computing. Vienna, Austria: R Foundation for Statistical Computing. ISBN 3-900051-07-0.Google Scholar
Romney, AK, & d’Andrade, RG (1964). Cognitive aspects of English kin terms. American Anthropologist, 66(3), 146170. 10.1525/aa.1964.66.3.02a00870CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schechter, L. A. (2005). Trust, trustworthiness, and risk in rural Paraguay. Ph.D. thesis, Citeseer.Google Scholar
Schwartz, SH (1992). Universals in the content and structure of values: Theoretical advances and empirical tests in 20 countries. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 25, 165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, VL, & Wilson, BJ (2017). Sentiments, conduct, and trust in the laboratory. Social Philosophy and Policy, 34(1), 2555. 10.1017/S0265052517000024CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Talhelm, T, Haidt, J, Oishi, S, Zhang, X, Miao, FF, & Chen, S (2015). Liberals think more analytically (more “weird”) than conservatives. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 41(2), 250267. 10.1177/0146167214563672CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Talhelm, T, Zhang, X, Oishi, S, Shimin, C, Duan, D, Lan, X et al., (2014). Large-scale psychological differences within china explained by rice versus wheat agriculture. Science, 344(6184), 603608. 10.1126/science.1246850CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Triandis, HC (1995). Individualism and collectivism, Boulder: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Triandis, HC (2001). Individualism-collectivism and personality. Journal of Personality, 69(6), 907924. 10.1111/1467-6494.696169CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Triandis, HC, Bontempo, R, Villareal, MJ, Asai, M, & Lucca, N (1988). Individualism and collectivism: Cross-cultural perspectives on self-ingroup relationships. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 54(2), 323 10.1037/0022-3514.54.2.323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Triandis, HC, McCusker, C, & Hui, CH (1990). Multimethod probes of individualism and collectivism. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 59(5), 1006 10.1037/0022-3514.59.5.1006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Hajikhameneh and Kimbrough supplementary material

Appendices to Hajikhameneh and Kimbrough, “Individualism, Collectivism and Trade”
Download Hajikhameneh and Kimbrough supplementary material(File)
File 421.3 KB