Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-7g5wt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T23:05:38.421Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

How sensitive are bargaining outcomes to changes in disagreement payoffs?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Nejat Anbarci*
Affiliation:
School of Accounting, Economics and Finance, Deakin University, 70 Elgar Road, Burwood, VIC 3125, Australia
Nick Feltovich*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Monash University, Clayton, VIC 3800, Australia

Abstract

We use a human-subjects experiment to investigate how bargaining outcomes are affected by changes in bargainers’ disagreement payoffs. Subjects bargain against changing opponents, with randomly drawn asymmetric disagreement outcomes that vary over plays of the game, and with complete information about disagreement payoffs and the cake size. We find that subjects only respond about half as much as theoretically predicted to changes in their own disagreement payoff and to changes in their opponent’s disagreement payoff. This effect is observed in a standard Nash demand game and a related unstructured bargaining game, in both early and late rounds, and is robust to moderate changes in stake sizes. We show theoretically that standard models of expected utility maximisation are unable to account for this under-responsiveness, even when generalised to allow for risk aversion. We also show that quantal-response equilibrium has, at best, mixed success in characterising our results. However, a simple model of other-regarding preferences can explain our main results.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2013 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic Supplementary Material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-013-9352-1) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Anbarci, N., & Feltovich, N. (2013). How responsive are people to changes in their bargaining position? Earned bargaining power and the 50–50 norm (Working paper). Monash University.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Bernheim, B. D. (2009). Social image and the 50–50 norm: a theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects. Econometrica, 77, 16071636. 10.3982/ECTA7384Google Scholar
Binmore, K. (2007). Playing for real: a text on game theory, Oxford: Oxford University Press 10.1093/acprof:oso/9780195300574.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., Shaked, A., & Sutton, J. (1985). Testing noncooperative bargaining theory: a preliminary study. The American Economic Review, 75, 11781180.Google Scholar
Binmore, K., Morgan, P., Shaked, A., & Sutton, J. (1991). Do people exploit their bargaining power? An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 3, 295322. 10.1016/0899-8256(91)90030-ICrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., Proulx, C., Samuelson, L., & Swierzbinski, J. (1998). Hard bargains and lost opportunities. The Economic Journal, 108, 12791298. 10.1111/1468-0297.00343CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, I., & Frey, B. (1999). Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games: comment. The American Economic Review, 89, 335339. 10.1257/aer.89.1.335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. E. (1991). A comparative model of bargaining: theory and evidence. The American Economic Review, 81, 10961136.Google Scholar
Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. The American Economic Review, 90, 166193. 10.1257/aer.90.1.166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral game theory: experiments in strategic interaction, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cameron, L. (1999). Raising the stakes in the ultimatum game: experimental evidence from Indonesia. Economic Inquiry, 37, 4759. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1999.tb01415.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, H., & van Damme, E. (1993). Global games and equilibrium selection. Econometrica, 61, 9891018. 10.2307/2951491CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Groot Ruiz, A., & Ramer, R. Schram, A. (2010). Structure in legislative bargaining (Working paper). CREED, University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817868. 10.1162/003355399556151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feltovich, N. (2005). Critical values for the robust rank-order test. Communications in Statistics. Simulation and Computation, 34, 525547. 10.1081/SAC-200068395CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feltovich, N., & Swierzbinski, J. (2011). The role of strategic uncertainty in games: an experimental study of cheap talk and unstructured bargaining in the Nash demand game. European Economic Review, 55, 554574. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2010.07.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischer, S., Güth, W., & Pull, K. (2007). Is there as-if bargaining?. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 36, 546560. 10.1016/j.socec.2006.12.013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S., & Riedl, A. (2005). Moral property rights in bargaining with infeasible claims. Management Science, 51, 249263. 10.1287/mnsc.1040.0311CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. Kremer, K., & Macho, V. (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen, Göttingen: Gesellschaft für Wissenschaftliche Datenverarbeitung 7993.Google Scholar
Harrison, G. (1987). Risk aversion and the Nash solution in stochastic bargaining experiments. Economics Letters, 24, 321326. 10.1016/0165-1765(87)90064-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsayni, J. C., & Selten, R. (1988). A general theory of equilibrium selection in games, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hoffman, E., & Spitzer, M. L. (1982). The Coase theorem: some experimental tests. The Journal of Law & Economics, 25, 7398. 10.1086/467008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., & Spitzer, M. L. (1985). Entitlements, rights, and fairness: an experimental examination of subjects’ concepts of distributive justice. The Journal of Legal Studies, 14, 259297. 10.1086/467773CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, C. A., & Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. The American Economic Review, 92, 16441655. 10.1257/000282802762024700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E., & Smorodinsky, M. (1975). Other solutions to Nash’s bargaining problem. Econometrica, 43, 513518. 10.2307/1914280CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kannai, Y. (1977). Concavifiability and constructions of concave utility functions. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 4, 156. 10.1016/0304-4068(77)90015-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., & Palfrey, T. R. (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 638. 10.1006/game.1995.1023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., & McLennan, A. M. Turocy, T. L. (2007). Gambit: software tools for game theory, version 0.2007.12.04. http://www.gambit-project.org.Google Scholar
Munier, B., & Zaharia, C. (2003). High stakes and acceptance behavior in ultimatum bargaining. Theory and Decision, 53, 187207. 10.1023/A:1022815832351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. (1950). The bargaining problem. Econometrica, 18, 155162. 10.2307/1907266CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. (1953). Two-person cooperative games. Econometrica, 21, 128140. 10.2307/1906951CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ochs, J., & Roth, A. E. (1989). An experimental study of sequential bargaining. The American Economic Review, 79, 355384.Google Scholar
Perry, M., & Reny, P. J. (1993). A non-cooperative bargaining model with strategically timed offers. Journal of Economic Theory, 59, 5077. 10.1006/jeth.1993.1004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perry, M., & Reny, P. J. (1994). A noncooperative view of coalition formation and the core. Econometrica, 62, 795817. 10.2307/2951733CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. The American Economic Review, 83, 12811302.Google Scholar
Rankin, F. W. (2006). Requests and social distance in dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60, 2736. 10.1016/j.jebo.2004.08.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E. (1979). Axiomatic models of bargaining, Berlin: Springer 10.1007/978-3-642-51570-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E. Kagel, J. H., & Roth, A. E. (1995). Bargaining experiments. Handbook of experimental economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press 253348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E., Prasnikar, V., Okuno-Fujiwara, M., & Zamir, S. (1991). Bargaining and market behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: an experimental study. The American Economic Review, 81, 10681095.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A. (1982). Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica, 50, 97109. 10.2307/1912531CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siegel, S., & Castellan, N. J. Jr. (1988). Nonparametric statistics for the behavioral sciences, New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Simon, L. K., & Stinchcombe, M. B. (1989). Extensive form games in continuous time: pure strategies. Econometrica, 57, 11711214. 10.2307/1913627CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skyrms, B. (1996). Evolution of the social contract, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 10.1017/CBO9780511806308CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slonim, R., & Roth, A. E. (1998). Learning in high stakes ultimatum games: an experiment in the Slovak Republic. Econometrica, 66, 569596. 10.2307/2998575CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomson, W. (1987). Monotonicity of bargaining solutions with respect to the disagreement point. Journal of Economic Theory, 42, 5058. 10.1016/0022-0531(87)90102-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Anbarci and Feltovich supplementary material

Anbarci and Feltovich supplementary material
Download Anbarci and Feltovich supplementary material(File)
File 230.7 KB