Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-v2ckm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T23:07:42.769Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Experimental departures from self-interest when competing partnerships share output

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Josh Cherry
Affiliation:
Kellogg School of Management, Chicago, IL, USA
Stephen Salant
Affiliation:
University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI, USA
Neslihan Uler*
Affiliation:
University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI, USA

Abstract

When every individual’s effort imposes negative externalities, self-interested behavior leads to socially excessive effort. To curb these excesses when effort cannot be monitored, competing output-sharing partnerships can form. With the right-sized groups, aggregate effort falls to the socially optimal level. We investigate this theory experimentally and find that while it makes correct qualitative predictions, there are systematic quantitative deviations, always in the direction of the socially optimal investment. Using data on subjects’ conjectures of each other’s behavior we investigate altruism, conformity and extremeness aversion as possible explanations. We show that deviations are consistent with both altruism and conformity (but not extremeness aversion).

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2014 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-014-9413-0) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Ahn, T, Isaac, RM, & Salmon, TC (2008). Endogenous group formation. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 10, 171194. 10.1111/j.1467-9779.2008.00357.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahn, T, Isaac, RM, & Salmon, TC (2009). Coming and going: Experiments on endogenous group sizes for excludable public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 336351. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2008.06.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J, Harbaugh, WT, Vesterlund, L Durlauf, SN, & Blume, LE (2008). Altruism in experiments. The new Palgrave, 2London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bardsley, N (2008). Dictator game giving: Altruism or artefact?. Experimental Economics, 11(2), 122133. 10.1007/s10683-007-9172-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baye, MR, & Hoppe, HC (2003). The strategic equivalence of rent-seeking, innovation, and patent-race games. Games and Economic Behavior, 44, 217226. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00027-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, BD (1994). A theory of conformity. Journal of Political Economy, 102(5), 841877. 10.1086/261957CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, & Cooper, DJ (2007). It’s what you say not what you pay. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5(6), 12231268. 10.1162/JEEA.2007.5.6.1223CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J., Charness, G. & Ellman, M. (2012). How communication affects contract design: An experimental study of formal and informal contracting (unpublished manuscript).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brekke, K., Hauge, K., Lind, J., & Nyborg, K. (2009). Playing with the good guys: A public good game with endogenous group formation. Working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buckley, N., Mestelman, S., Muller, R. A., Schott, S., & Zhang, J. (2009). Shut up and fish: the role of communication when output sharing is used to manage a common property resource. Atlantic Canada Economics Association Papers and Proceedings.Google Scholar
Buckley, N., Mestelman, S., Muller, R. A., Schott, S., & Zhang, J. (2010). Effort Provision and Communication in Competing Teams. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Camerer, CF (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Charness, G (2000). Self-serving cheap talk: A test of Aumann’s conjecture. Games and Economic Behavior, 33(2), 177194. 10.1006/game.1999.0776CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Dufwenberg, M (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, Econometric Society, 74(6), 15791601. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00719.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Rabin, M (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817869. 10.1162/003355302760193904CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Yang, C. (2010). Endogenous group formation and efficiency: An experimental study. In Proceedings of the Behavioral and Quantitative Game Theory: Conference on Future Directions (BQGT ’10). doi:10.1145/1807406.1807463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaudhuri, A, Schotter, A, & Sopher, B (2009). Talking ourselves to efficiency: Coordination in inter-generational minimum effort games with private, almost common and common knowledge of advice. The Economic Journal, 119(534), 91122 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2008.02207.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chung, T-Y (1996). Rent-seeking contest when the prize increases with aggregate efforts. Public Choice, 87, 5566. 10.1007/BF00151729CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cournot, A. A. (1838). Recherches sur les Principes Mathématiques de la Théorie des Richesses. Reprinted by Dunod (2001).Google Scholar
Dasgupta, P, & Heal, G (1979). Economic theory and exhaustible resources, Oxford: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dietl, H, Franck, E, & Lang, M (2008). Overinvestment in team sports leagues: A contest theory model. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 55, 353368. 10.1111/j.1467-9485.2008.00457.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A, Fehr, E, & Fischbacher, U (2005). Driving forces behind informal sanctions. Econometrica, 73, 20172030. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2005.00644.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heintzelman, M, Salant, S, & Schott, S (2009). Putting free-riding to work: A partnership solution to the common-property problem. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 57, 309320. 10.1016/j.jeem.2008.07.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, M, & Norton, D (2013). Endogenous institutions and the possibility of reverse crowd out. Public Choice, 156, 253284. 10.1007/s11127-011-9897-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagi, W. (2001). The tragedy of the commons revisited: Sharing as a means to avoid environmental ruin. IWOE Discussion Paper 91, Institute for Economy and the Environment, University of St. Gallen.Google Scholar
Konrad, K (2009). Strategies and dynamics in contests, New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kosfeld, M, Okada, A, & Rield, A (2009). Institution formation in public goods games. The American Economics Review, 99(4), 13351355. 10.1257/aer.99.4.1335CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ledyard, J Roth, A, & Kagel, J (1995). Public goods: A survey of experimental research. The handbook of experimental economics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
List, JA (2007). On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. Journal of Political Economy, 115(3), 482493. 10.1086/519249CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luzzati, T Gallagati, M, & Kirman, A (1999). Economics theory and conformity. Beyond the representative agent, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Noussair, C., Plott, C., & Riezman, R. (1995). An experimental investigation of the patterns of international trade. The American Economic Review, 85(3), 462491.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action, New York: Cambridge University Press 10.1017/CBO9780511807763CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E, Walker, J, & Palfrey, TR (1991). Communication in a commons: Cooperation without external enforcement. Laboratory research in political economy, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press 287322.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E, Walker, J, & Gardner, R (1992). Covenants with and without a sword: Self-governance is possible. American Political Science Review, 86, 404417. 10.2307/1964229CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E, Gardner, R, & Walker, J (1994). Rules, games, and common pool resources, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, T, Putterman, L, & Unel, B (2005). Voluntary association in public goods experiments: Reciprocity, mimicry and efficiency. The Economic Journal, 115, 10321053. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2005.01031.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Platteau, J-P, Seki, E Aoki, M, & Hayami, Y (2000). Community arrangements to overcome market failures: Pooling groups in Japanese fisheries. Market, community, and economic development, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Poteete, A., Janssen, M., & Ostrom, E. (2010). Working together:. Collective action, the commons, and multiple methods in practice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Putterman, L., Tyran, J. P., & Kamei, K. (2010). Public goods and voting on formal sanction schemes: An experiment. Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sahlins, M (1972). Stone age economics, New York: Aldine de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Schott, S. (2001). A partnership solution to the tragedy of the commons. In 4th Toulouse Conference on Environment and Resource Economics. Toulouse, France.Google Scholar
Schott, S, Buckley, N, Mestelman, S, & Muller, RA (2007). Output sharing in partnerships as a common-pool resource management instrument. Environmental Resource Economics, 37(4), 697711. 10.1007/s10640-006-9062-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I (1989). Choice based on reasons: The case of attraction and compromise effects. Journal of Consumer Research, 16, 158174. 10.1086/209205CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simonson, I, & Tversky, A (1992). Choice in context: Tradeoff contrast and extremeness aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 29, 281295. 10.2307/3172740CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutter, M, Haigner, S, & Kocher, M (2010). Choosing the carrot or the stick? Endogenous institutional choice in social dilemma situations. Review of Economic Studies, 77, 15401566. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2010.00608.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyran, JR, & Feld, L (2006). Achieving compliance when legal sanctions are non-deterrent. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108, 135156. 10.1111/j.1467-9442.2006.00444.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Velez, MA, Stranlund, JK, & Murphy, JJ (2009). What motivates common pool resource users? Experimental evidence from the field. Journal of Economics Behavior and Organization, 70, 485497. 10.1016/j.jebo.2008.02.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, J, Gardner, R, Herr, A, & Ostrom, E (2000). Collective choice in the commons: Experimental results on proposed allocation rules and votes. The Economic Journal, 110(460), 212234. 10.1111/1468-0297.00497CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Cherry et al. supplementary material

Appendix: Instructions
Download Cherry et al. supplementary material(File)
File 135.1 KB