Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-f9bf7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T16:18:27.922Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Dominant Strategy Adoption and Bidders’ Experience with Pricing Rules

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Ronald M. Harstad*
Affiliation:
Faculty of Management and RUTCOR, Rutgers University, 640 Bartholomew Road, Piscataway, NJ 08854-8003, USA

Abstract

Truthful revelation is a dominant strategy in both English (oral ascending bid) and second-price sealed-bid private-values auctions. Controlled observations of English auctions are largely consistent with the dominant strategy prediction, but laboratory second-price auctions exhibit substantial and persistent overbidding, even with prior experience. However, the experience of having bid in an English auction has a significant learning effect, moving bidding in subsequent second-price auctions closer to the dominant strategy. I explore two treatments isolating facets of the lessons learned from English auction participation, leading me to the following conclusions. Part of the lesson carried over appears to be considering prices one-by-one, but most of it appears to be a crude awareness that overbidding leads to losses. A claim that English auction experience teaches subjects to recognize the dominant strategy in second-price auctions seems overly optimistic. I introduce a nonparametric technique to test coefficient restrictions when the assumption of normally distributed errors is untenable.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2001 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bacharach, M. (1993). “Variable Universe Games.” In Binmore, K., Kirman, A., and Tani, P (eds.), Frontiers of Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 255275.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. (1995). “Individual Decision Making.” In Kagel, J.H. and Roth, A.E. (eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, pp. 587703.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cason, T.M. and Friedman, D. (1997). “Price Formation in Single Call Markets.” Econometrica. 65, 311345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppinger, V.M., Smith, V.L., and Titus, J.A. (1980). “Incentives and Behavior in English, Dutch and Sealed-Bid Auctions.” Economic Inquiry. 18, 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J.C., Roberson, B., and Smith, V.L. (1982). “Theory and Behavior of Single Object Auctions.” In Smith, V.L. (ed.), Research in Experimental Economics, vol. 2. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Crawford, V.P. (1995). “Adaptive Dynamics in Coordination Games.” Econometrica. 63, 103143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, V.P. (1995b). “Theory and Experiment in the Analysis of Strategic Interaction.” Discussion paper 95-37, University of California, San Diego.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D. and Levine, D. (1995). “How Irrational Are Subjects in Extensive-Form Games?American Economic Review. 85.Google Scholar
Gale, J., Binmore, K., and Samuelson, L. (1995). “Learning to Be Imperfect: The Ultimatum Game.” Games and Economic Behavior. 8, 5690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, G.W. (1989). “Theory and Misbehavior in First Price Auctions.” American Economic Review. 79, 749762.Google Scholar
Harrison, G.W. (1994). “Expected Utility Theory and the Experimentalists.” Empirical Economics. 19, 223253. Reprinted in J.D. Hey (ed.), Experimental Economics, Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag, 1994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, G.W., Harstad, R.M., and Rutström, E.E. (1995). “Experimental Methods and Elicitation of Values,” Working paper #B-338, Sonderforschungsbereich 303, University of Bonn.Google Scholar
Harstad, R.M. and Marrese, M. (1982). “Behavioral Explanations of Efficient Public Good Allocations.” Journal of Public Economics. 9, 367383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., Menkhaus, D.J., Chakravarti, D., Field, R.A., and Whipple, G.D. (1993). “Using Laboratory Experimental Auctions in Marketing Research: A Case Study of New Packaging for Fresh Beef.” Marketing Science. 12, 318338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J.H., Harstad, R.M., and Levin, D. (1987). “Information Impact and Allocation Rules in Auctions with Affiliated Private Values: A Laboratory Study.” Econometrica. 55, 12751304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J.L., and Thaler, R.H., (1990). “Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem.” Journal of Political Economy. 98, 13251348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, P. (1992). A Guide to Econometrics. Cambridge, M.A: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Krishna, V. and Rosenthal, R. (1995). “Simultaneous Auctions with Synergies,” ISP discussion paper #56, Boston University.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R. and Palfrey, T. (1995). “Quantal Response Equilibria for Normal-Form Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 10, 638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, PR. (1987). “Auction Theory.” In Bewley, T. (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory: Fifth World Congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pezanis-Christou, P (1996). “On the Impact of Low Balling: Experimental Results in Asymmetric Auctions.” Working paper, University of New South Wales.Google Scholar
Roth, A.E. (1995). “Bargaining Experiments.” In Kagel, J.H. and Roth, A.E. (eds.), The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press, pp. 253348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A.E. and Erev, I. (1995). “Learning in Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and Simple Dynamic Models in the Intermediate Term.” Games and Economic Behavior 8, 164212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothkopf, M.H. and Harstad, R.M. (1994). “Modeling Competitive Bidding: A Critical Essay.” Management Science. 40, 364384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutstrom, E.E. (forthcoming) “Home-Grown Values and the Design of Incentive Compatible Auctions.International Journal of Game Theory.Google Scholar
Selten, R. and Buchta, J. (2000). “Experimental Sealed Bid First Price Auctions with Directly Observed Bid Functions.” In Budescu, D., Erev, I., and Zwick, R. (eds), Games and Human-Behavior: Essays in Honor of Amnon Rapoport. Mahwah, NJ: Lawren Ehrbaum Associates.Google Scholar
Shogren, J.F., Shin, S.Y., Hayes, D.J., and Kliebenstein, J.B. (1994), “Resolving Differences in Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept.” American Economic Review. 84, 255270.Google Scholar
Smith, V.L. (1982). “Microeconomic Systems As an Experimental Science.” American Economic Review. 72, 923955.Google Scholar
Smith, V.L. and Walker, J.M. (1993). “Monetary Rewards and Decision Cost in Experimental Economics.” Economic Inquiry. 31, 245261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1981). “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice.” Science. 211, 453458.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1986). “Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions.” Journal of Business. 59 (2), part 2.Google Scholar
Vickrey, W. (1961). “Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders.” Journal of Finance. 16, 827.CrossRefGoogle Scholar