Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-9k27k Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T13:30:59.581Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Auctions with endogenous participation and an uncertain number of bidders: experimental evidence

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Diego Aycinena
Affiliation:
Facultad de Economía, Universidad del Rodario, Calle 12C No. 6-25 Bogotá, D.C., Colombia
Lucas Rentschler*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Finance, Utah State University, 3500 Old Main Hill, Logan, UT 84322, USA

Abstract

Attracting bidders to an auction is a key factor in determining revenue. We experimentally investigate entry and bidding behavior in first-price and English clock auctions to determine the revenue implications of entry. Potential bidders observe their value and then decide whether or not to incur a cost to enter. We also vary whether or not bidders are informed regarding the number of entrants prior to placing their bids. Revenue equivalence is predicted in all four environments. We find that, regardless of whether or not bidders are informed, first-price auctions generate more revenue than English clock auctions. Within a given auction format, the effect of informing bidders differs. In first-price auctions, revenue is higher when bidders are informed, while the opposite is true in English clock auctions. The optimal choice for an auction designer who wishes to maximize revenue is a first-price auction with uninformed bidders.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2017 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9558-8) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Anwar, S, McMillan, R, & Zheng, M (2006). Bidding behavior in competing auctions: Evidence from eBay. European Economic Review, 50(2), 307322. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2004.10.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aycinena, D, Bejarano, H, & Rentschler, L (2017). Informed entry in auctions. International Journal of Game Theory, 10.1007/s00182-017-0583-9Google Scholar
Camerer, C, & Lovallo, D (1999). Overconfidence and excess entry: An experimental approach. American Economic Review, 89(1), 306318. 10.1257/aer.89.1.306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, C (1998). Coordination in auctions with entry. Journal of Economic Theory, 82(2), 425450. 10.1006/jeth.1995.2452CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cao, X., & Tian, G. (2008). Second-price auctions with differentiated participation costs. Working paper.Google Scholar
Cao, X., & Tian, G. (2009). Second-price auctions with two-dimensional private information on values and participation costs. Working paper.Google Scholar
Cao, X, & Tian, G (2010). Equilibria in first-price auctions with participation costs. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2), 258273. 10.1016/j.geb.2009.11.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Y, Katuscak, P, & Ozdenoren, E (2013). Why can’t a woman bid more like a man?. Games and Economic Behavior, 77(1), 181213. 10.1016/j.geb.2012.10.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coppinger, V, Smith, V, & Titus, J (1980). Incentives and behavior in English, Dutch and sealed-bid auctions. Economic Inquiry, 18(1), 122. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1980.tb00556.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J, Roberson, B, & Smith, V (1982). Theory and behavior of single object auctions. Research in Experimental Economics, 2, 143.Google Scholar
Cox, J, Dinkin, S, & Swarthout, J (2001). Endogenous entry and exit in common value auctions. Experimental Economics, 4(2), 163181. 10.1023/A:1011432705173CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyer, D, Kagel, J, & Levin, D (1989). Resolving uncertainty about the number of bidders in independent private-value auctions: An experimental analysis. Rand Journal of Economics, 20(2), 268279. 10.2307/2555693CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelbrecht-Wiggans, R (1987). On optimal reservation prices in auctions. Management Science, 33(6), 763770. 10.1287/mnsc.33.6.763CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelbrecht-Wiggans, R (1993). Optimal auctions revisited. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(2), 227–39 10.1006/game.1993.1013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelbrecht-Wiggans, R, & Katok, E (2005). Experiments on auction valuation and endogenous entry. Advances in Applied Microeconomics: A Research Annual, 13, 169193. 10.1016/S0278-0984(05)13007-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U, & Thoni, C (2008). Excess entry in an experimental winner-take-all market. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 67(1), 150163. 10.1016/j.jebo.2006.05.018CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goeree, J, & Holt, C (2005). An explanation of anomalous behavior in models of political participation. American Political Science Review, 99(02), 201213. 10.1017/S0003055405051609CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, J, & Laffont, J (1984). Participation constraints in the vickrey auction. Economics Letters, 16(1), 3136. 10.1016/0165-1765(84)90138-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. (2004). An online recruitment system for economic experiments. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Harstad, R, Kagel, J, & Levin, D (1990). Equilibrium bid functions for auctions with an uncertain number of bidders. Economics Letters, 33(1), 3540. 10.1016/0165-1765(90)90197-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendricks, K, & Porter, RH (1988). An empirical study of an auction with asymmetric information. American Economic Review, 78(5), 865883.Google Scholar
Hendricks, K, Porter, RH, & Boudreau, B (1987). Information, returns, and bidding behavior in ocs auctions: 1954–1969. Journal of Industrial Economics, 35(4), 517542. 10.2307/2098586CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendricks, K, Porter, RH, & Spady, RH (1989). Random reservation prices and bidding behavior in OCS drainage auctions. Journal of Law and Economics, 32(2), S83S106. 10.1086/467189CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendricks, K, Porter, RH, & Tan, G (1993). Optimal selling strategies for oil and gas leases with an informed buyer. American Economic Review, 83(2), 234239.Google Scholar
Hendricks, K, Porter, RH, & Wilson, CA (1994). Auctions for oil and gas leases with an informed bidder and a random reservation price. Econometrica, 62(6), 14151444. 10.2307/2951754CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heydenreich, B, Müller, R, Uetz, M, & Vohra, R (2009). Characterization of revenue equivalence. Econometrica, 77(1), 307316. 10.3982/ECTA7168Google Scholar
Holt, C, & Laury, S (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92(5), 16441655. 10.1257/000282802762024700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, M, Pevnitskaya, S, & Schnier, K (2012). Individual behavior and bidding heterogeneity in sealed bid auctions where the number of bidders is unknown. Economic Inquiry, 50(2), 516533. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2011.00393.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ivanova-Stenzel, R, & Salmon, T (2004). Bidder preferences among auction institutions. Economic Inquiry, 42(2), 223236. 10.1093/ei/cbh056CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ivanova-Stenzel, R, & Salmon, T (2008). Revenue equivalence revisited. Games and Economic Behavior, 64(1), 171192. 10.1016/j.geb.2008.01.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ivanova-Stenzel, R, & Salmon, T (2008). Robustness of bidder preferences among auction institutions. Economic Inquiry, 46(3), 355368. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2007.00111.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ivanova-Stenzel, R, & Salmon, T (2011). The high/low divide: Self-selection by values in auction choice. Games and Economic Behavior, 73(1), 200214. 10.1016/j.geb.2010.12.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J, & Levin, D (1993). Independent private value auctions: Bidder behaviour in first-, second-and third-price auctions with varying numbers of bidders. Economic Journal, 103(419), 868879. 10.2307/2234706CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klemperer, P (2002). What really matters in auction design. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(1), 169189. 10.1257/0895330027166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin, D, & Ozdenoren, E (2004). Auctions with uncertain numbers of bidders. Journal of Economic Theory, 118(2), 229251. 10.1016/j.jet.2003.11.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin, D, & Smith, J (1994). Equilibrium in auctions with entry. American Economic Review, 84(3), 585599.Google Scholar
Li, T, & Zheng, X (2009). Entry and competition effects in first-price auctions: Theory and evidence from procurement auctions. Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 13971429. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2009.00558.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J, & Lucking-Reiley, D (2002). Bidding behavior and decision costs in field experiments. Economic Inquiry, 40(4), 611619. 10.1093/ei/40.4.611CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lu, J (2009). Auction design with opportunity cost. Economic Theory, 38(1), 73103. 10.1007/s00199-008-0331-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matthews, S (1987). Comparing auctions for risk averse buyers: A buyer’s point of view. Econometrica, 55(3), 633–46 10.2307/1913603CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAfee, R, & McMillan, J (1987). Auctions with entry. Economics Letters, 23(4), 343347. 10.1016/0165-1765(87)90142-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAfee, R, & McMillan, J (1987). Auctions with a stochastic number of bidders. Journal of Economic Theory, 43(1), 119. 10.1016/0022-0531(87)90113-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAfee, PR (1993). Mechanism design by competing sellers. Econometrica, 61(6), 12811312. 10.2307/2951643CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menezes, F, & Monteiro, P (2000). Auctions with endogenous participation. Review of Economic Design, 5(1), 7189. 10.1007/s100580050048CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miralles, A (2008). Intuitive and noncompetitive equilibria in weakly efficient auctions with entry costs. Mathematical Social Sciences, 56(3), 448455. 10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2008.06.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moreno, D, & Wooders, J (2011). Auctions with heterogeneous entry costs. RAND Journal of Economics, 42(2), 313336. 10.1111/j.1756-2171.2011.00135.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, RB (1981). Optimal auction design. Mathematics of Operations Research, 6(1), 5873. 10.1287/moor.6.1.58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palfrey, T, & Pevnitskaya, S (2008). Endogenous entry and self-selection in private value auctions: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 66(3), 731747. 10.1016/j.jebo.2006.06.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, M, & Severinov, S (1997). Competition among sellers who offer auctions instead of prices. Journal of Economic Theory, 75(1), 141179. 10.1006/jeth.1997.2278CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, M, & Severinov, S (2006). Internet auctions with many traders. Journal of Economic Theory, 130(1), 220245. 10.1016/j.jet.2005.04.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pevnitskaya, S. (2004). Endogenous entry in first-price private value auctions: The self-selection effect. Working paper.Google Scholar
Reiley, D. H. (2005). Experimental evidence on the endogenous entry of bidders in internet auctions. In Rapoport, A. & Zwick, R. (Eds.), Experimental business research (Vol. II, pp. 103121). Springer.Google Scholar
Roberts, J, & Sweeting, A (2013). When should sellers use auctions?. American Economic Review, 103(5), 18301861. 10.1257/aer.103.5.1830CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A (1994). Lets keep the con out of experimental econ.: A methodological note. Empirical Economics, 19(2), 279–89 10.1007/BF01175875CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, W (1985). Competitive bidding with entry costs. Economics Letters, 17(1–2), 5357. 10.1016/0165-1765(85)90126-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, J, & Levin, D (1996). Ranking auctions with risk averse bidders. Journal of Economic Theory, 68(2), 549561. 10.1006/jeth.1996.0031CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, J, & Levin, D (2002). Entry coordination in auctions and social welfare: An experimental investigation. International Journal of Game Theory, 30(3), 321350. 10.1007/s001820100083CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stegeman, M (1996). Participation costs and efficient auctions. Journal of Economic Theory, 71(1), 228259. 10.1006/jeth.1996.0116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tan, G, & Yilankaya, O (2006). Equilibria in second-price auctions with participation costs. Journal of Economic Theory, 130(1), 205219. 10.1016/j.jet.2005.02.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickrey, W (1961). Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders. Journal of Finance, 16(1), 837. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1961.tb02789.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ye, L (2004). Optimal auctions with endogenous entry. The BE Journal of Theoretical Economics, 4(1), 8.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Aycinena and Rentschler supplementary material

Online Supplement
Download Aycinena and Rentschler supplementary material(File)
File 183.4 KB