Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-7g5wt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T16:18:27.370Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Are benevolent dictators altruistic in groups? A within-subject design

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Lucy F. Ackert*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Finance, Michael J. Coles College of Business, Kennesaw State University, 1000 Chastain Road, Kennesaw, GA 30144, USA Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, 1000 Peachtree Street NE, Atlanta, GA 30309-4470, USA
Ann B. Gillette*
Affiliation:
Kennesaw State University, Kennesaw, GA, USA Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Atlanta, GA, USA
Jorge Martinez-Vazquez*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, 14 Marietta Street, Atlanta, GA, 30303, USA
Mark Rider*
Affiliation:
Georgia State University, Atlanta, GA, USA

Abstract

We use a within-subject experimental design to investigate whether systematic relationships exist across distinct features of individual preferences: altruism in a two-person context, risk aversion in monetary outcomes, and social preferences in a group context. We find that altruism is related to demographic variables, including years of education, gender, and age. Perhaps most importantly, self allocation in a two-person dictator game is related to social preferences in a group context. Participants who are more generous in a dictator game are more likely to vote against their self-interest in a group tax redistribution game which we interpret to be an expression of social preferences.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2010 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

The views expressed here are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta or the Federal Reserve System. Financial support of the International Studies Program, Andrew Young School at Georgia State University and the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta is gratefully acknowledged. The authors thank Vid Adrison and Astha Sen for outstanding research assistance. We are also grateful to Glenn Harrison, Tim Cason (the editor), and two anonymous referees for very helpful insights and comments, and to participants of the ESA 2007 and APEE 2008 meetings.

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi: 10.1007/s10683-010-9269-x) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Ackert, L. F., Gillette, A. B., Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Rider, M. (2007a). Voting on tax policy design: a test of the selfish versus social preferences hypothesis. Public Finance Review, 35(2), 263284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ackert, L. F., Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Rider, M. (2007b). Social preferences and tax policy design: some experimental evidence. Economic inquiry, 45(3), 487501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: an experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Vesterlund, L. (2001). Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 292312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battigalli, P., & Dufwenberg, M. (2009). Dynamic psychological games. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(1), 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., Koch, A., & Normann, T. H. (2009). Preferences and beliefs in a sequential social dilemma: a within-subjects analysis. IZA Working Paper No. 4624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., & Normann, T. H. (2010). A within-subject analysis of other-regarding preferences. Games and Economic Behavior. doi:10.106/j.geb.2010.09.008.Google Scholar
Bolton, G. E., Katok, E., & Zwick, R. (1998). Dictator game giving: rules of fairness versus acts of kindness. International Journal of Game Theory, 27(2), 269299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G.E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. The American Economic Review, 90(1), 166193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brosig, J., Riechmann, T., & Weimann, J. (2007). Selfish in the end? An investigation of consistency and stability of individual behavior. Working Paper, University of Magdeburg.Google Scholar
Charness, G., & Genicot, G. (2009). Informal risk sharing in an infinite-horizon experiment. Economic Journal, 119(537), 796825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Gneezy, U. (2007). Strong evidence for gender differences in investment. Working Paper, Department of Economics, University of California at Santa Barbara.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Villeval, M. (2009). Cooperation, competition, and risk attitudes: an intergenerational field and laboratory experiment. The American Economic Review, 99(3), 956978.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Gjerstad, S. (2007). A tractable model of reciprocity and fairness. Games and Economic Behavior, 59(1), 1745.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C., Friedman, D., & Sadiraj, V. (2008). Revealed altruism. Econometrica, 76(1), 3169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), 268298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelmann, D., & Strobel, M. (2004). Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple distribution experiments. The American Economic Review, 94(4), 857869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelmann, D., & Strobel, M. (2006). Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple distribution experiments: reply. The American Economic Review, 96(5), 19181925.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feddersen, T. J., Gailmard, S., & Sandroni, A. (2009). Moral bias on large elections: theory and experimental evidence. The American Political Science Review, 103(2), 175192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817868.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J., Savin, N. E., & Sefton, M. (1994). Fairness in simple bargaining experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 6(3), 347369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., & Gintis, H. (Eds.) (2004). Foundations of human sociality: economic experiments and ethnographic evidence from fifteen small-scale societies. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hey, J. D., & Lee, J. (2005). Do subjects remember the past? Applied Economics, 37(1), 918.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., & Spitzer, M. (1985). Entitlements, rights, and fairness: an experimental examination of subjects’ concepts of distributive justice. Journal of Legal Studies, 14(2), 259297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutström, E. E., & Williams, M. B. (2000). Entitlements and fairness: an experimental study of distributive preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 43(1), 7589.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

52.5KB
Download undefined(File)
File 53.8 KB