Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-v2ckm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T14:10:59.071Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An experimental analysis of cooperation and productivity in the trust game

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Cary Deck*
Affiliation:
University of Arkansas, Fayetteville, AR, USA

Abstract

In the standard trust game the surplus is increased by the risk taking first mover while cooperation by the second mover is a one-to-one transfer. This paper reports results from experiments in which the reverse holds; the first mover's risky trust is not productive and the second mover's cooperation is productive. This subtle difference significantly lowers the likelihood of trust but increases the likelihood of cooperation conditional on trust. Evidence is presented that the change in trust is consistent with first movers failing to anticipate the later result. Drawing upon the analogy that the trust game represents a model of exchange, the results suggest that markets should be organized so that the buyer moves first and not the seller as in the original trust game.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Economic Science Association 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10683-007-9186-9) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: an experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J., & Vesterlund, L. (2001). Which is the fair sex? Gender differences in altruism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 293312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10, 122142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. American Economic Review, 90, 166193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 817869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, D., & Van Huyck, J. (2003). Evidence on the equivalence of the strategic and extensive form representation of games. Journal of Economic Theory, 110, 290308.Google Scholar
Coricelli, G., McCabe, K., & Smith, V. (2000). Theory-of-mind mechanism in personal exchange. In Hatano, G., Okada, N., & Tanabe, H. (Eds.), Affective Minds. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Cox, J. C., & Deck, C. A. (2005). On the nature of reciprocal motives. Economic Inquiry, 43, 623635.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, J. C., & Deck, C. A. (2006a). Assigning intentions when actions are unobservable. Southern Economic Journal, 73(2), 307314.Google Scholar
Cox, J. C., & Deck, C. A. (2006b). When are women more generous than men? Economic Inquiry, 44(4), 587598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crockett, S., Smith, V., & Wilson, B. (2006). Exchange and specialization as a discovery process (Working Paper). Interdisciplinary Center for Economic Science, George Mason University.Google Scholar
Deck, C. A. (2001). A test of behavioral and game theoretic models of play in exchange and insurance environments. American Economic Review, 91, 15461555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, M., & Gneezy, U. (2000). Measuring beliefs in an experimental lost wallet game. Games and Economic Behavior, 30(2), 163182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelmann, D., & Strobel, M. (2004). Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple distribution experiments. American Economic Review, 94, 857869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, A., Gächter, S., & Kovács, J. (1999). Intrinsic motivation and extrinsic incentives in a repeated game with incomplete contracts. Journal of Economic Psychology, 20, 251284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., von Rosenbladt, B., Schupp, J., & Wagner, G. (2003). A nation-wide laboratory: examining trust and trustworthiness by integrating behavioral experiments into representative surveys (Discussion Paper No. 715), IZA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R., Kariv, S., & Markovits, D. (2005). Distinguishing social preferences from preferences for altruism (Working Paper). UC Berkeley.Google Scholar
Güth, W., Huck, S., & Müller, W. (2001). The relevance of equal splits in ultimatum games. Games and Economic Behavior, 37, 161169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E., McCabe, K. A., Shachat, K., & Smith, V. L. (1994). Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior, 7, 346380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCabe, K. A., & Smith, V. L. (2000). A comparison of naïve and sophisticated subject behavior with game theoretic predictions. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 97, 37773781.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McCabe, K. A., Rigdon, M. L., & Smith, V. L. (2003). Positive reciprocity and intentions in the trust game. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 52, 267275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rigdon, M. (2002). Efficiency wages in an experimental labor market. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 99, 1334813351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. (1994). Economics in the laboratory. Journal of Economics Perspectives, #(1), 113131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Deck supplementary material

Deck supplementary material 1
Download Deck supplementary material(File)
File 20 KB
Supplementary material: File

Deck supplementary material

Deck supplementary material 2
Download Deck supplementary material(File)
File 140.8 KB