Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-9klzr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-17T06:22:30.455Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Patience and time consistency in collective decisions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Laurent Denant-Boemont*
Affiliation:
University Rennes 1 - CREM, Place Hoche Rennes, France
Enrico Diecidue*
Affiliation:
INSEAD, Boulevard de Constance Fontainebleau, France
Olivier l’Haridon*
Affiliation:
University Rennes 1 - CREM, Place Hoche Rennes, France

Abstract

We present experimental evidence regarding individual and group decisions over time. Static and longitudinal methods are combined to test four conditions on time preferences: impatience, stationarity, age independence, and dynamic consistency. Decision making in groups should favor coordination via communication about voting intentions. We find that individuals are neither patient nor consistent, that groups are both patient and highly consistent, and that information exchange between participants helps groups converge to stable decisions. Finally we provide additional evidence showing that our results are driven by the specific role of groups and not by either repeated choices or individual preferences when choosing for other subjects.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2016 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-016-9481-4) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

We thank Aurelien Baillon, Nicolas Houy, Vincent Merlin, Amnon Rapoport, Jeeva Somasundaram, Karine Van Der Straeten, Marie-Claire Villeval, Peter Wakker, the editor of this journal as well as two anonymous referees for helpful comments. We also thank Elven Priour for programming the script and organizing the sessions.

References

Abdellaoui, M, Bleichrodt, H, & l’Haridon, O (2013). Sign-dependence in intertemporal choice. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 47, 225253. 10.1007/s11166-013-9181-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Sprenger, C (2012). Estimating time preferences from convex budgets. The American Economic Review, 102, 33333356. 10.1257/aer.102.7.3333CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Sprenger, C (2012). Risk preferences are not time preferences. American Economic Review, 102, 33573376. 10.1257/aer.102.7.3357CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Augenblick, N, Niederle, M, & Sprenger, C (2015). Working over time: Dynamic inconsistency in real effort tasks. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130, 10671115. 10.1093/qje/qjv020CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baucells, M, & Heukamp, FH (2012). Probability and time trade-off. Management Science, 58, 831842. 10.1287/mnsc.1110.1450CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benzion, U, Rapoport, A, & Yagil, J (1989). Discount rates inferred from decisions: An experimental study. Management Science, 35, 270284. 10.1287/mnsc.35.3.270CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bleichrodt, H, & Johannesson, M (2001). Time preference for health: A test of stationarity versus decreasing timing aversion. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 45, 265282. 10.1006/jmps.2000.1312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bleichrodt, H, Rohde, KI, & Wakker, PP (2008). Koopmans’ constant discounting for intertemporal choice: A simplification and a generalization. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 52, 341347. 10.1016/j.jmp.2008.05.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bleichrodt, H, Rohde, KI, & Wakker, PP (2009). Non-hyperbolic time inconsistency. Games and Economic Behavior, 66, 2738. 10.1016/j.geb.2008.05.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bostic, R, Herrnstein, RJ, & Luce, RD (1990). The effect on the preference-reversal phenomenon of using choice indifferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 13, 193212. 10.1016/0167-2681(90)90086-SCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J, & Cooper, DJ (2006). A change would do you good.... An experimental study on how to overcome coordination failure in organizations. American Economic Review, 96, 669693. 10.1257/aer.96.3.669CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caplin, A, & Leahy, J (2004). The supply of information by a concerned expert. The Economic Journal, 114, 487505. 10.1111/j.0013-0133.2004.0228a.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, F, He, H, Martinsson, P, Qin, P, & Sutter, M (2012). Household decision making in rural China: Using experiments to estimate the influences of spouses. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 84(2), 525536. 10.1016/j.jebo.2012.08.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casari, M, & Dragone, D (2015). Choice reversal without temptation: A dynamic experiment on time preferences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 50, 119140. 10.1007/s11166-015-9211-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Rabin, M (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly journal of Economics, 117(3), 817869. 10.1162/003355302760193904CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Sutter, M (2012). Groups make better self-interested decisions. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26, 157176. 10.1257/jep.26.3.157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coller, M, & Williams, MB (1999). Eliciting individual discount rates. Experimental Economics, 2, 107127. 10.1023/A:1009986005690CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, DJ, & Kagel, JH (2005). Are two heads better than one? Team versus individual play in signaling games. American Economic Review, 95(33), 477509. 10.1257/0002828054201431CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DellaVigna, S (2009). Psychology and economics: Evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 315372. 10.1257/jel.47.2.315CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denant-Boemont, L., & Loheac, Y. (2011). Time and teams: An experimental study about group inter-temporal choice. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Dohmen, T, Falk, A, Huffman, D, & Sunde, U (2010). Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability?. American Economic Review, 100, 12381260. 10.1257/aer.100.3.1238CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epper, T., & Fehr-Duda, H. (2012). The missing link: Unifying risk taking and time discounting. Department of Economics, University of Zurich, Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epper, T, Fehr-Duda, H, & Bruhin, A (2011). Viewing the future through a warped lens: Why uncertainty generates hyperbolic discounting. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 43, 169203. 10.1007/s11166-011-9129-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishburn, PC, & Rubinstein, A (1982). Time preference. International Economic Review, 23, 677694. 10.2307/2526382CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, R, Myerson, RB, Rietz, TA, & Weber, RJ (1993). An experiment on coordination in multi-candidate elections: The importance of polls and election histories. Social Choice and Welfare, 10, 223247. 10.1007/BF00182507CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S (2005). Cognitive reflection and decision making. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19, 2542. 10.1257/089533005775196732CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S, Loewenstein, G, & O’donoghue, T (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of economic literature, 40, 351401. 10.1257/jel.40.2.351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerardi, D, & Yariv, L (2007). Deliberative voting. Journal of Economic Theory, 134, 317338. 10.1016/j.jet.2006.05.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giné, X., Goldberg, J., Silverman, D., & Yang, D. (2014). Revising Commitments: Field evidence on the adjustment of prior choices. Working paper, World Bank.Google Scholar
Glaeser, EL, & Sunstein, CR (2009). Extremism and social learning. Journal of Legal Analysis, 1, 263324. 10.4159/jla.v1i1.10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goeree, JK, & Yariv, L (2011). An experimental study of collective deliberation. Econometrica, 79, 893921. 10.3982/ECTA8852Google Scholar
Gollier, C, & Zeckhauser, R (2005). Aggregation of heterogeneous time preferences. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 878896. 10.1086/430853CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halevy, Y (2008). Strotz meets Allais: Diminishing impatience and the certainty effect. American Economic Review, 98(3), 11451162. 10.1257/aer.98.3.1145CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halevy, Y (2015). Time consistency: Stationarity and time invariance. Econometrica, 83, 335352. 10.3982/ECTA10872CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holcomb, JH, & Nelson, PS (1992). Another experimental look at individual time preference. Rationality and Society, 4, 199220. 10.1177/1043463192004002006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horowitz, JK (1992). A test of intertemporal consistency. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 17, 171182. 10.1016/0167-2681(92)90085-PCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackson, M, & Yariv, L (2014). Present bias and collective dynamic choice in the lab. American Economic Review, 104, 41844204. 10.1257/aer.104.12.4184CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackson, M, & Yariv, L (2015). Collective dynamic choice: The necessity of time inconsistency. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 7(4), 150178.Google Scholar
Kang, M-I, & Ikeda, S (2014). Time discounting and smoking behavior: Evidence from a panel survey. Health Economics, 23, 14431464. 10.1002/hec.2998CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kirby, KN, & Maraković, NN (1995). Modeling myopic decisions: Evidence for hyperbolic delay-discounting within subjects and amounts. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 64, 2230. 10.1006/obhd.1995.1086CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G, & Prelec, D (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 573597. 10.2307/2118482CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luhan, WJ, Kocher, MG, & Sutter, M (2009). Group polarization in the team dictator game reconsidered. Experimental Economics, 12, 2641. 10.1007/s10683-007-9188-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maciejovsky, B, Sutter, M, Budescu, DV, & Bernau, P (2013). Teams make you smarter: How exposure to teams improves individual decisions in probability and reasoning tasks. Management Science, 59, 12551270. 10.1287/mnsc.1120.1668CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meier, S, & Sprenger, CD (2015). Temporal stability of time preferences. Review of Economics and Statistics, 97, 273286. 10.1162/REST_a_00433CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Millner, A., & Heal, G. (2014). Resolving intertemporal conflicts: Economics vs Politics. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moscovici, S, & Zavalloni, M (1969). The group as a polarizer of attitudes. Journal of personality and social psychology, 12, 125 10.1037/h0027568CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, RB, & Weber, RJ (1993). A theory of voting equilibria. American Political Science Review, 87(1), 102114. 10.2307/2938959CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noussair, C, Robin, S, & Ruffieux, B (2004). Revealing consumers’ willingness-to-pay: A comparison of the BDM mechanism and the Vickrey auction. Journal of Economic Psychology, 25, 725741. 10.1016/j.joep.2003.06.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palfrey, TR (2009). Laboratory experiments in political economy. Annual Review of Political Science, 12, 379388. 10.1146/annurev.polisci.12.091007.122139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perez-Arce, F. (2011). The effect of education on time preferences. Working paper, RAND Corporation.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps, ES, & Pollak, RA (1968). On second-best national saving and game-equilibrium growth. The Review of Economic Studies, 35(2), 185199. 10.2307/2296547CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, CR (1967). A notion of equilibrium and its possibility under majority rule. The American Economic Review, 57(4), 787806.Google Scholar
Read, D, Frederick, S, & Airoldi, M (2012). Four days later in Cincinnati: Longitudinal tests of hyperbolic discounting. Acta Psychologica, 140, 177185. 10.1016/j.actpsy.2012.02.010CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Robson, AJ, & Szentes, B (2014). A biological theory of social discounting. American Economic Review, 104, 34813497. 10.1257/aer.104.11.3481CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rohde, KI (2010). The hyperbolic factor: A measure of time inconsistency. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 41, 125140. 10.1007/s11166-010-9100-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, PA (1937). A note on measurement of utility. The Review of Economic Studies, 4, 155161. 10.2307/2967612CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sayman, S, & Öncüler, A (2009). An investigation of time inconsistency. Management Science, 55, 470482. 10.1287/mnsc.1080.0942CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schaner, S (2015). Do opposites detract? Intrahousehold preference heterogeneity and inefficient strategic savings. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7, 135174.Google Scholar
Schkade, D, Sunstein, CR, & Kahneman, D (2000). Deliberating about dollars: The severity shift. Columbia Law Review, 100, 11391175. 10.2307/1123539CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schram, AJ (2004). Experimental public choice, Berlin: Springer.Google Scholar
Shapiro, J. (2010). Discounting for you, me, and we: Time preference in groups and pairs. Working paper.Google Scholar
Sobel, J (2014). On the relationship between individual and group decisions. Theoretical Economics, 9, 163185. 10.3982/TE1185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stoner, JA (1968). Risky and cautious shifts in group decisions: The influence of widely held values. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 4, 442459. 10.1016/0022-1031(68)90069-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strotz, RH (1955). Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization. The Review of Economic Studies, 23, 165180. 10.2307/2295722CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Takeuchi, K (2011). Non-parametric test of time consistency: Present bias and future bias. Games and Economic Behavior, 71, 456478. 10.1016/j.geb.2010.05.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R (1981). Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Economics Letters, 8, 201207. 10.1016/0165-1765(81)90067-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Viscusi, WK, Phillips, OR, & Kroll, S (2011). Risky investment decisions: How are individuals influenced by their groups?. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 43, 81106. 10.1007/s11166-011-9123-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wölbert, E., & Riedl, A. (2013). Measuring time and risk preferences: Reliability, stability, domain specificity. CESifo working paper no 4339.Google Scholar
Zuber, S (2010). The aggregation of preferences: Can we ignore the past?. Theory and Decision, 70, 367384. 10.1007/s11238-010-9225-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material

Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material 1
Download Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material(File)
File 39.9 KB
Supplementary material: File

Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material

Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material 2
Download Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material(File)
File 309.9 KB
Supplementary material: File

Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material

Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material 3
Download Denant-Boemont et. al. supplementary material(File)
File 54.6 KB