Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-v2ckm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T13:09:26.271Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A New Variant of the Winner's Curse in a Coasian Contracting Game

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Glen Archibald
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Finance, University of Mississippi, MS 38677
Nathaniel T. Wilcox*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Houston, Houston. TX 77204

Abstract

We examine behavior in a Coasian contracting game with incomplete information. Experimental subjects propose contracts, while automaton property right holders or “robot” players with uncertain preferences respond to those proposals. The most common pattern of proposals observed in these games results in too many agreements and, in some games, payoffs that are stochastically dominated by those resulting from rational proposals (which imply fewer agreements). In this sense, we observe a “winner's curse” similar to that observed in bidding games under incomplete information, such as the “common value auction” (Kagel, J.H. and Levin, D. (1986) American Economic Review. 76, 894-920) and the “takeover game” (Samuelson, W. and Bazerman, M.H. (1985) In Research in Experimental Economics, Vol. 3. JAI Press, Greenwich, pp. 105-137; Ball, S.B., Bazerman, M.H., and Carroll, J.S. (1990) Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 48, 1-22; Holt, C. and Sherman, R. (1994) American Economic Review. 84, 642-652). While the “naïve model” of behavior nicely predicts the winner's curse in those previous bidding games, it does not do so here. Instead, an alternative model we call the “guarantor model” explains the anomalous behavior best. Hence, we suggest this is a new variant of the winner's curse.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2002 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

To whom correspondence should be addressed.

References

Archibald, G. (1999). Coasian Bargaining Under Incomplete Information: Theories and Experiments. Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis. Houston: Department of Economics, University of Houston.Google Scholar
Archibald, G. and Wilcox, N. (2001). “What Causes “Naïve” Behavior in Takeover Games? Two Conjectures and Experiments.” Working paper, University of Houston, Department of Economics.Google Scholar
Ball, S.B., Bazerman, M.H., and Carroll, J.S. (1990). “An Evaluation of Learning in the Bilateral Winner's Curse.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 48, 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballinger, T.P. and Wilcox, N.T. (1997). “Decisions, Error and Heterogeneity.” Economic Journal. 107, 10901105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, J.E., Daley, L.A., Dickhaut, J.W., and O’Brien, J.R. (1986). “Controlling Preferences for Lotteries on Units of Experimental Exchange.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 101, 281306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. (1960). “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics. 3, 131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conlisk, J. (1989). “Three Variants on the Allais Example.” American Economic Review. 79, 392407.Google Scholar
Curley, S.P., Yates, J.F., and Abrams, R.A. (1986). “Psychological Sources of Ambiguity Avoidance.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes. 38, 230256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D. and Holt, C. (1993). Experimental Economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Efron, B. and Tibshirani, R.J. (1998). An Introduction to the Bootstrap. CRC Press, Boca Raton, Florida (First Published in 1993 by Chapman and Hall, Reprinted in 1998 by CRC Press).Google Scholar
Farrell, J. (1987). “Information and the Coase Theorem.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2, 113129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harless, D. and Camerer, C. (1994). “The Predictive Utility of Generalized Utility Theories.” Econometrica. 62, 12511289.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, G. (1989). “Theory and Misbehavior of First-Price Auctions.” American Economic Review. 79, 749762.Google Scholar
Harrison, G.W. and McKee, M. (1985). “Experimental Evaluation of the Coase Theorem.” Journal of Law and Economics. 28, 653670.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hershey, J.C., Kunreuther, H.C., and Schoemaker, P.J.H. (1988). “Sources of Bias in Assessment Procedures for Utility Functions.” In Bell, D., Raiffa, H., and Tversky, A. (eds.), Decision Making: Descriptive, Normative and Prescriptive Interactions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Hoffman, E. and Spitzer, M.L. (1982). “The Coase Theorem: Some Experimental Tests.” Journal of Law and Economics. 25, 7398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E. and Spitzer, M.L. (1985). “Experimental Tests of the Coase Theorem with Large Bargaining Groups.” Journal of Legal Studies. 14, 259297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, C.A. (1986). “Preference reversals and the independence axiom.” American Economic Review. 76, 508515.Google Scholar
Holt, C. and Sherman, R. (1994). “The Loser's Curse.” American Economic Review. 84, 642652.Google Scholar
Kagel, J.H. and Levin, D. (1986). “The Winner's Curse and Public Information in Common Value Auctions.” American Economic Review. 76, 894920.Google Scholar
Loomes, G. (1998). “Probabilities vs Money: A Test of Some Fundamental Assumptions About Rational Decision Making.” Economic Journal. 108, 477489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loomes, G. and Sugden, R. (1998). “Testing Different Stochastic Specifications of Risky Choice.” Economica. 65, 581598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, P.E., Moen, J.B., and Thompson, W.B. (1988). “Garden Path Errors in Diagnostic Reasoning.” In Bolc, L. and Coombs, M.J. (eds.), Expert System Applications. Springer-Verlag, Berlin.Google Scholar
Millner, E. and Pratt, M. (1992). A Test of Risk Inducement: Is the Inducement of Risk-Neutrality Neutral? TMs, Department of Economics, Virginia Commonwealth University.Google Scholar
Roth, A. and Malouf, W.K. (1979). “Game-Theoretical Models and the Role of Information in Bargaining.” Psychological Review. 86, 574594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, W. and Bazerman, M.H. (1985). “The Winner's Curse in Bilateral Negotiations.” In Smith, V.L. (ed.), Research in Experimental Economics, Vol. 3. JAI Press, Greenwich, CN, pp. 105137.Google Scholar
Slovic, P., Fischhoff, B., and Lichtenstein, S. (1982). “Response Mode, Framing and Information-Processing Effects in Risk Assessment.” In Hogarth, R. (ed.), New Directions for Methodology of Social and Behavioral Science: Question Framing and Response Consistency. Jossey-Bass Press, San Francisco.Google Scholar
Selten, R., Sadrieh, A., and Abbink, K. (1999). “Money Does not Induce Risk Neutral Behavior, but Binary Lotteries do Even Worse.” Theory and Decision. 46, 211249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starmer, C. and Sugden, R. (1991). “Does the Random-Lottery Incentive System Elicit True Preferences? An Experimental Investigation.” American Economic Review. 81, 971978.Google Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1986). “Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions.” In Hogarth, R.M. and Reder, M.W. (eds.), Rational Choice: The Contrast between Economics and Psychology. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Wilcox, N. (1993). “Lottery Choice: Incentives, Complexity and Decision Time.” Economic Journal. 103, 13971417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar