Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-wdhn8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T16:19:36.507Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Heterogeneous guilt sensitivities and incentive effects

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Charles Bellemare*
Affiliation:
Département d’économique, Université Laval, CRREP, Quebec City, Canada
Alexander Sebald*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Copenhagen, Denmark
Sigrid Suetens*
Affiliation:
CentER, and TILEC, Tilburg University, Tilburg, The Netherlands

Abstract

Psychological games of guilt aversion assume that preferences depend on (beliefs about) beliefs and on the guilt sensitivity of the decision-maker. We present an experiment designed to measure guilt sensitivities at the individual level for various stake sizes. We use the data to estimate a structural choice model that allows for heterogeneity, and permits that guilt sensitivities depend on stake size. We find substantial heterogeneity of guilt sensitivities in our population, with 60% of decision makers displaying stake-dependent guilt sensitivity. For these decision makers, we find that average guilt sensitivities are significantly different from zero for all stakes considered, while significantly decreasing with the level of stakes.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2017 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9543-2) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Abdellaoui, M, Barrios, C, & Wakker, PP (2007). Reconciling introspective utility with revealed preference: Experimental arguments based on prospect theory. Journal of Econometrics, 138, 356378. 10.1016/j.jeconom.2006.05.025CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J, & Bernheim, BD (2009). Social image and the 50–50 norm: A theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects. Econometrica, 77, 16071636. 10.3982/ECTA7384Google Scholar
Armantier, O, & Treich, N (2013). Eliciting beliefs: Proper scoring rules, incentives, stakes and hedging. European Economic Review, 62, 1740. 10.1016/j.euroecorev.2013.03.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attanasi, G, Battigalli, P, & Manzoni, E (2015). Incomplete-information models of guilt aversion in the trust game. Management Science, 62(3), 648667. 10.1287/mnsc.2015.2154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attanasi, G., Battigalli, P., and Nagel, R. (2013). Disclosure of belief-dependent preferences in a trust game. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Babcock, L, & Loewenstein, G (1997). Explaining bargaining impasse: The role of self-serving biases. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(1), 109126. 10.1257/jep.11.1.109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battigalli, P, & Dufwenberg, M (2007). Guilt in games. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 97, 170176. 10.1257/aer.97.2.170CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battigalli, P, & Dufwenberg, M (2009). Dynamic psychological games. Journal of Economic Theory, 144, 135. 10.1016/j.jet.2008.01.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumeister, R, Stillwell, A, & Heatherton, T (1994). Guilt: An interpersonal approach. Psychological Bulletin, 115, 243267. 10.1037/0033-2909.115.2.243CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bellemare, C, Kröger, S, & van Soest, A (2008). Measuring inequity aversion in a heterogeneous population using experimental decisions and subjective probabilities. Econometrica, 76, 815839. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2008.00860.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellemare, C, Sebald, A, & Strobel, M (2011). Measuring the willingness to pay to avoid guilt: Estimation using equilibrium and stated belief models. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 26, 437453. 10.1002/jae.1227CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellemare, C, Sebald, A, & Suetens, S (2017). A note on testing guilt aversion. Games and Economic Behavior, 102, 233239. 10.1016/j.geb.2016.11.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (2006). The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C, & Xiao, E (2009). Do the right thing: But only if others do so. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 22(2), 191208. 10.1002/bdm.621CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, C, Xiao, E, & Muldoon, R (2011). Trustworthiness is a social norm, but trusting is not. Politics, Philosophy, and Economics, 10, 170187. 10.1177/1470594X10387260CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C, & Hogarth, R (1999). The effects of financial incentives in experiments: A review and capital-labor-production framework. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19, 742. 10.1023/A:1007850605129CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J, Verhoogen, E, & Burks, S (2005). The effect of stakes in distribution experiments. Economics Letters, 86, 393398. 10.1016/j.econlet.2004.08.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Dufwenberg, M (2006). Promises and partnerships. Econometrica, 74, 15791601. 10.1111/j.1468-0262.2006.00719.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellingsen, T, Johannesson, M, Tjötta, S, & Torsvik, G (2010). Testing guilt aversion. Games and Economic Behavior, 68, 95107. 10.1016/j.geb.2009.04.021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & Schmidt, K (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817868. 10.1162/003355399556151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geanakoplos, J, Pearce, D, & Stacchetti, E (1989). Psychological games and sequential rationality. Games and Economic Behavior, 1, 6079. 10.1016/0899-8256(89)90005-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibson, R, Tanner, C, & Wagner, A (2013). Preferences for truthfulness: Heterogeneity among and within individuals. American Economic Review, 103, 532548. 10.1257/aer.103.1.532CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U, Meier, S, & Rey-Biel, P (2011). When and why incentives (don’t) work to modify behavior. Journal of Economic Perspective, 25, 191210. 10.1257/jep.25.4.191CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. (2004). The online recruitment system ORSEE 2.0—A guide for the organization of experiments in economics. Technical report, University of Cologne, Working Paper Series in Economics 10.Google Scholar
Güth, W, Schmittberger, R, & Schwarze, B (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 3(4), 367388. 10.1016/0167-2681(82)90011-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, C, & Laury, S (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic Review, 92, 16441655. 10.1257/000282802762024700CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khalmetski, K, Ockenfels, A, & Werner, P (2015). Surprising gifts: Theory and laboratory evidence. Journal of Economic Theory, 159, 163208. 10.1016/j.jet.2015.05.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krupka, EL, & Weber, RA (2013). Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary?. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11, 495524. 10.1111/jeea.12006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noussair, CN, Trautmann, ST, & van de Kuilen, G (2014). Higher order risk attitudes, demographics, and financial decisions. Review of Economic Studies, 81, 325355. 10.1093/restud/rdt032CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reuben, E, Sapienza, P, & Zingales, L (2009). Is mistrust self-fulfilling?. Economics Letters, 104, 8991. 10.1016/j.econlet.2009.04.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, A, & Sopher, B (2007). Advice and behavior in intergenerational ultimatum games: An experimental approach. Games and Economic Behavior, 58(2), 365393. 10.1016/j.geb.2006.03.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R, & Sauermann, H (1967). Die Strategiemethode zur Erforschung des Eingeschränkt Rationalen Verhaltens im Rahmen eines Oligopolexperiments. Beiträge zur Experimentellen Wirtschaftsforschung, Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr 136168.Google Scholar
Smith, V, & Walker, J (1993). Monetary rewards and decision costs in experimental economics. Economic Inquiry, 31, 245261. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.1993.tb00881.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trautmann, S. T., & van de Kuilen, G. (2015). Belief elicitation: A horse race among truth serums. Economic Journal (forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanberg, C (2008). Why do people keep their promises? An experimental test of two explanations. Econometrica, 76, 14671480. 10.3982/ECTA7673Google Scholar
Yang, Y., Onderstal, S., & Schram, A. (2012). Inequity aversion revisited. Working paper, University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Bellemare et al. supplementary material

Appendix A
Download Bellemare et al. supplementary material(File)
File 47.4 KB