Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dlb68 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-16T13:56:39.706Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Capital structure irrelevance in the laboratory: an experiment with complete and asymmetric information

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Arturo Macias*
Affiliation:
Universidad Nacional de Educacion a Distancia (UNED) and Banco de España, Madrid, Spain

Abstract

This article presents a laboratory experiment about capital structure irrelevance. The equity and debt issued by a firm are traded in two double-auction markets. In the Public treatment a signal carrying information about the firm’s value is known to all traders, while in the Private treatment, it is only disclosed to some randomly chosen participants. In treatment Public the conditions for capital structure irrelevance hold. The experimental results support the irrelevance of the capital structure but reject the rational expectations (risk-neutral) valuation. Treatment effects are significant and information is more efficiently embedded in prices in the Public treatment. The results from treatment Private on prices support the prior information over the rational expectations equilibrium. The analysis of the final portfolios of informed and uninformed participants suggests incomplete adjustment towards the prior information equilibrium predicted holdings.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), under exclusive licence to Economic Science Association 2022

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Supplementary Information The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-022-09757-8.

This article was developed within the Interuniversity Doctorate in Economics (DECIDE). I want to thank Marc Vorsatz (UNED) for his research direction and the Ministerio de Economia y Competitividad (Government of Spain) for its support through project ECO2015 65701-P. I am solely responsible for any errors.

Replication materials available at https://osf.io/3ygja/download this link.

References

Angerer, M., Neugebauer, T., & Shachat, J. (2019). Arbitrage bots in experimental asset markets. MPRA Paper 96224, University Library of Munich.Google Scholar
Asparouhova, E., Besliu, C., Lemmon, M., & Rock, B. (2016). Payout policy, investor rationality, and market efficiency: Evidence from laboratory experiments. Technical report, Working paper, University of Utah.Google Scholar
Bejan, C. (2020). Investment and financing in incomplete markets. Economic Theory, 69(1), 149182. 10.1007/s00199-018-1160-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biais, B., Hilton, D., Mazurier, K., & Pouget, S. (2005). Judgmental overconfidence, self-monitoring and trading performance in an experimental financial market. Review of Economic Studies, 72(2), 287312. 10.1111/j.1467-937X.2005.00333.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borio, C. (2014). The financial cycle and macroeconomics: What have we learnt?. Journal of Banking and Finance, 45, 17031723. 10.1016/j.jbankfin.2013.07.031CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bossaerts, P., Frydman, C., & Ledyard, J. (2014). The speed of information revelation and eventual price quality in markets with insiders: Comparing two theories. Review of Finance, 18(1), 122. https://academic.oup.com/rof/article/18/1/1/1615240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruguier, A. J., Quartz, S. R., & Bossaerts, P. (2010). Exploring the nature of “Trader Intuition”. The Journal of Finance, 65, 122. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2010.01591.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., & Neugebauer, T. (2019). A test of the Modigliani-Miller invariance theorem and arbitrage in experimental asset markets. The Journal of Finance, 65, 493529. 10.1111/jofi.12736CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, J. E. (1988). Statistical power analysis for the behavioral sciences, Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates Inc.Google Scholar
Corgnet, B., DeSantis, M., & Porter, D. (2020). The distribution of information and the price efficiency of markets. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 110, 103671 10.1016/j.jedc.2019.02.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corgnet, B., Deck, C. A., DeSantis, M., Hampton, K. W., & Kimbrough, E. O. (2020). Reconsidering rational expectations and the aggregation of diverse information in laboratory security markets. Working Papers 19-11, Chapman University, Economic Science Institute.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. The American Economic Review, 70, 393408.Google Scholar
Hamada, R. S. (1960). Portfolio analysis, market equilibrium and corporation finance. The Journal of Finance, 24, 1331. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1969.tb00339.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. (1966). Investment decisions under uncertainty: Applications of the state-preference approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80, 252–77 10.2307/1880692CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ho, J., & Robinson, J. (1994). The relevance of financial policy in perfect capital markets. International Review of Financial Analysis, 3(2), 97111. 10.1016/1057-5219(94)90019-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiang, Y., Lee, M.-L. T., He, X., Rosner, B., & Yan, J. (2020). Wilcoxon rank-based tests for clustered data with R package clusrank. https://www.jstatsoft.org/article/view/v096i06.Google Scholar
Kornsgold, Y. (2021). Oh, that, Hertz: Protecting unsophisticated investors from buying stock in bankrupt companies. Columbia Business Law Review.Google Scholar
Kraus, A., & Litzenberger, R. (1973). State-preference model of optimal financial leverage. Journal of Finance, 28, 911922. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.1973.tb01415.xGoogle Scholar
Kumar, A. (2009). Who gambles in the stock market?. Journal of Finance, 64, 18891933. 10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01483.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levati, M. V., Qiu, J., & Mahagaonkar, P. (2012). Testing the Modigliani-Miller theorem directly in the lab. Experimental Economics, 15, 693716. 10.1007/s10683-012-9322-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lintner, J. (1969). The aggregation of investor’s diverse judgments and preferences in purely competitive security markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 4, 347400. 10.2307/2330056CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markowitz, H. (2014). Mean-variance approximations to expected utility. European Journal of Operational Research, 234, 346355. 10.1016/j.ejor.2012.08.023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, R. (1974). On the pricing of corporate debt: The risk structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance, 29, 449470.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. The American Economic Review, 48, 261297.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. (1963). Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: A correction. The American Economic Review, 53, 433443.Google Scholar
Neugebauer, T., Shachat, J., & Szymczak, W. (2020). A test of the Modigliani-Miller theorem, dividend policy and algorithmic arbitrage in experimental asset markets. ESI Working Papers-Chapman University.Google Scholar
Page, L., & Siemroth, C. (2021). How much information is incorporated into financial asset prices? Experimental evidence. The Review of Financial Studies, 34(9), 44124449. https://academic.oup.com/rfs/article-abstract/34/9/4412/6050887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, C., & Sunder, S. (1982). Efficiency of experimental security markets with insider information: An application to rational expectations models. Journal of Political Economy, 90, 663698. 10.1086/261084CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, C., & Sunder, S. (1988). Rational expectations and the aggregation of diverse information in laboratory security. Econometrica, 56, 10851118. 10.2307/1911360CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V., Suchanek, G., & Williams, A. W. (1988). Bubbles, crashes, and endogenous expectations in experimental spot asset markets. Econometrica, 56(5), 11191151. 10.2307/1911361CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. (1969). A re-examination of the Modigliani-Miller theorem. American Economic Review, 59(5), 784793.Google Scholar
Stöckl, T., Huber, J., & Kirchler, M. (2010). Bubble measures in experimental asset markets. Experimental Economics, 13, 284298. 10.1007/s10683-010-9241-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, J. (2005). The theory of corporate finance, Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Titman, S. (2002). The Modigliani and Miller theorem and the integration of financial markets. Financial Management, 31(1), 101115. 10.2307/3666323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Macias supplementary material

Macias supplementary material
Download Macias supplementary material(File)
File 245.6 KB