Hostname: page-component-7b9c58cd5d-dlb68 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-03-17T06:11:13.130Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An experimental examination of the house money effect in a multi-period setting

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Lucy F. Ackert*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Finance, Michael J. Coles College of Business, Kennesaw State University, Kennesaw, Georgia 30144; Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Atlanta, Georgia 30309-4470
Narat Charupat*
Affiliation:
Michael G. DeGroote School of Business, McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario, Canada L8S 4M4
Bryan K. Church*
Affiliation:
College of Management, Georgia Tech, Atlanta, Georgia 30332-0520
Richard Deaves*
Affiliation:
Michael G. DeGroote School of Business, McMaster University, Hamilton, Ontario, Canada L8S 4M4

Abstract

There is evidence that risk-taking behavior is influenced by prior monetary gains and losses. When endowed with house money, people become more risk taking. This paper is the first to report a house money effect in a dynamic, financial setting. Using an experimental method, we compare market outcomes across sessions that differ in the level of cash endowment (low and high). Our experimental results provide support for a house money effect. Traders’ bids, price predictions, and market prices are influenced by the amount of money that is provided prior to trading. However, dynamic behavior is difficult to interpret due to conflicting influences.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © 2006 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

The views expressed here are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta or the Federal Reserve System.

References

Barberis, N., & Huang, M. (2001). Mental accounting, loss aversion, and individual stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(4), 12471292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barberis, N., Huang, M., & Santos, T. (2001). Prospect theory and asset prices. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1), 154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barberis, N., Huang, M., & Thaler, R. (2002). Individual preferences, monetary gambles and the equity premium, working paper, University of Chicago and Stanford University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battalio, R. C., Kagel, J. H., & Jiranyakul, K. (1990). Testing between alternative models of choice under uncertainty: some initial results. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 3(1), 2550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bekaert, G., Hodrick, R. J., & Marshall, D. A. (1997). The implications of first-order risk aversion for asset market risk premiums. Journal of Monetary Economics, 40(1), 339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. (1995). Myopic loss aversion and the equity premium puzzle. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(1), 7392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, J. (2002). House money effects in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 5, 223231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, D. D., & Holt, C. A. (1993). Experimental economics. Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, K. D. (1996). Prospect theory: A literature review. International Review of Financial Analysis, 5(1), 1938.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gertner, R. (1993). Game shows and economic behavior: Risk-taking on “card sharks. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(2), 507521.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, D. (2001). Investor psychology and asset pricing. Journal of Finance, 56(4), 15331597.Google Scholar
Isen, A. M., & Patrick, R. E. (1983). The effect of positive feelings on risk-taking: When the chips are down. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Performance, 31, 194202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isen, A. M., & Geva, N. (1987). The influence of positive affect on acceptable level of risk: The person with the large canoe has a large worry. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 39, 145154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision-making under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knetsch, J. L., & Sinden, J. A. (1987). The persistence of evaluation disparities. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(3), 691695.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knetsch, J. L., Tang, F.-F., & Thaler, R. H. (2001). The endowment effect and repeated market trials: Is the vickrey auction demand revealing? Experimental Economics, 4(3), 257269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, H., & Levy, M. (2002). Experimental test of the prospect theory value function: A stochastic dominance approach. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 89, 10581081.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myagkov, M., & Plott, C. R. (1997). Exchange economies and loss exposure: Experiments exploring prospect theory and competitive equilibria in market environments. American Economic Review, 87(5), 801828.Google Scholar
Rabin, M., & Thaler, R. H. (2001). Anomalies: Risk aversion.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(1), 219232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, V. (1994). Economics in the laboratory. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(1), 113131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R., & Johnston, E. J. (1990). Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science, 36, 643660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science, 211, 453458.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickrey, W. (1961). Conter specualtion, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders. Journal of Finance, 16, 837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wakker, P. P. (2003). The data of levy and levy (2002). ‘prospect theory: Much ado about nothing?’ Actually support prospect theory. Management Science, 49(7), 979981.CrossRefGoogle Scholar