I. Introduction
One of the few certainties about the root causes of COVID-19 (commonly known as the “coronavirus”) is that the disease qualifies as a zoonosis Footnote 1 (ie an animal disease transmitted to humans). In addition, as strong evidence links the epidemic to infected animals displayed in a market to be sold as food, it is clear that the pandemic that shocked the world in 2020 is closely intertwined with food safety. Moving from here and looking at the phenomenon through the lens of those who study the overall regulation of this sector, three reflections can be made.
Firstly, the issue of food safety is global: if food safety regulations are ineffective, insufficient or too permissive anywhere in the world, or even close to home, the effects may be felt on a global scale. Real or perceived risks within food regulation systems can have consequences for trade (eg restrictions on unsafe products) and damage suppliers, vendors and whole food industries, causing economic and reputational damage. Or, as most of the planet has witnessed in recent months, problems stemming from flawed food safety systems can devastate the health and well-being of individuals, communities and the economies of entire nations.
Secondly, if the problem is global, then so must be the solution. Although the globalisation of goods and trade still presents unresolved problems,Footnote 2 a path of “deglobalisation” seems anachronistic and illogical, starting with the renouncing of world trade as we know it for an unlikely autarchy of the Nation States (even if we accept that efforts to contain the coronavirus in recent months have been almost exclusively domesticFootnote 3 ). However, looking at the long run and considering the indirect consequences of the epidemic, the governanceFootnote 4 of food safety must be organised on a global scale with greater and more effective development of instruments that are already available, including common rules and regulatory mechanisms, supranational institutions, world administrative and judicial systems and coordination and linking mechanisms between States or between regions of States.
Thirdly, if the legal instruments for common health and food safety governance already exist and need to be strengthened, we need to consider the direction in which to do so (ie with what content, with what objectives and with what resources). In this regard, as will be shown in this paper, the sector in question needs improvement not only with regards to the COVID-19 pandemic, but also because it is still ineffective in the prevention of many diseases of agro-food origin. Bearing in mind that the perspective of prevention is the most sustainable, most effective and least costly in terms of the current state of global regulation, it is necessary to highlight a need for improvement: the level of protection of health from food products must be increased; the scope of food safety regulation must be extended to all of the phases of food production; and the harmonisation of principles, rules, standards and regulatory approaches must be achieved according to parameters of safety that are greater than those that are currently in place.Footnote 5
Nevertheless, it should be noted that any change will result in the expenditure of public money and sacrifices for other sectors, with greater costs for the food industry and consumers. Moreover, improved results in such regulation require a precise political will, shared by all States or most of the international community, which thus far has been lacking. Now, however, the global governance of such a sector is called upon to make radical and innovative decisions.
In the face of these problems, we will first discuss some possible solutions, then come back to them in the concluding section of this paper.
The first involves the balance between the interests at stake (ie mainly the protection of health and the freedom of production and trade of food and feed). The balance between the two sectors must be rethought in such a way that, with greater powers entrusted to the competent authorities, the protection of the former prevails at the expense of the latter. Such a paradigm shift must be made according to predefined and detailed rules – and not arbitrarily or for the benefit of partial interests. This suggests a reorganisation of the world’s regulatory structures, notably the Codex Alimentarius Commission (CAC),Footnote 6 which – because of its overly free trade-orientated character (Section II) – should only become a standard-setting body of the World Health Organization (WHO), with the exclusion of the control of the Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) and modifying the connection with the World Trade Organization (WTO). In this way, the WTO and the CAC would enter into a dialectical relationship, and the FAO would have the function of producing standards exclusively for the protection of health, through which to derogate the rules on free trade on the basis of decisions shared on a global scale and without giving rise to forms of protectionism of a nationalistic matrix (Section V.1).
Secondly, the time is ripe to extend the application of the precautionary principle to a global scale (Section V.2). Such a principle, which is now used only in the European Union (EU) and in some States, but not in international law (unless as soft law), has the effect of increasing the discretion of public regulators in the face of uncertain science and the possibility of risk and allows authorities to adopt preventative measures that are more restrictive than the common ones. In this way, it admits derogations to the harmonised system of rules in respect of some formal limits: only for temporary measures in cases of scientific uncertainty and for greater health protection than that established by common norms. Moreover, despite what is commonly believed, precautionary measures constitute a compromise aimed at limiting the protectionism and arbitrariness of Nation States because such preventative measures are circumscribed and governed by rules and procedures (Section III).
Finally, all those regulatory instruments that are already in use, albeit with little efficacy, need to be strengthened and made more effective. Among these, two in particular need reforming: the traceability of the origins of food and mandatory information to be indicated on the label (Section V.3); and the harmonisation, coordination and horizontal connection between the systems of control on a global scale (Section V.4).
Every year, World Food Safety Day is held on 7 June. In 2019, less than a year before the COVID-19 pandemic, FAO and WHO announced that unsafe food causes many foodborne diseases worldwide that affect around 600 million people every year, posing a serious burden to global humanity. Footnote 7 The website of the European Food Safety Authority states that “almost one in ten people in the world fall ill after eating contaminated food”, Footnote 8 with 420,000 people dying each year from unsafe food, including 125,000 children under the age of five. Footnote 9 The management of this issue is costly – not only in terms of human lives lost, but also in resources and time spent, and it is estimated at around US$110 billion per year are spent on medical and production expenses. Footnote 10
These latest data would be enough to demonstrate that food safety is still a fundamental objective of global governance, and that reforms are needed in this area to improve the regulation of the sector, particularly for the purpose of protecting health and preventing diseases arising from the activities of agro-food production. Now, with the spread of the pandemic caused by COVID-19 – which has not been random, given the numbers mentioned aboveFootnote 11 – the world’s decision-makers have the opportunity to rethink the system, ensuring that the regulation of food safety after coronavirus is able to ward off, or at least minimise, the risks of new food-borne pandemics arising.
II. International standards and food safety: the Codex Alimentarius Commission between health and free trade
The CAC, as mentioned above, is a second-level international organisation, created by FAO and WHO, to adopt standards, guidelines and codes of conduct on the safety and quality of agro-food products. The measures adopted by the CAC are based on scientific reports provided by independent committees established by “parental organisations”, but they are then discussed and reworked – on the basis of distinct conveniences, political intentions and sensitivities – by representatives of the nation states that meet in the committees that are part of the CAC’s organisational system. From a legal point of view, these measures constitute formally non-binding technical standards (soft law), of a specific and substantial nature, to which nation states can adjust their internal regulations, either by conforming to them (eg by transcribing their content into national regulatory measures) or by basing them on the parameters contained therein.
Standards are very important and, despite their non-binding character, very effective as regulatory tools for a number of reasons.
Firstly, because the international nature of supply chains means that foods and related resources are now constantly in movement around the globe, the transitory nature of food makes standardisation a very useful – indeed, essential – mechanism to facilitate trade, avoid arbitrariness by individual States and harmonise governance of the matter.Footnote 12 Moreover, the measures of the CAC are specific and very detailed, presenting technical parameters and defined limits: it is very difficult for a State that wants to comply with international law to diverge from the contents of the standards.
Secondly, the total number of the CAC’s Member States, which, with governmental delegates, actively participate in the drafting and approval of the standards, is 187.Footnote 13 As this equates to the majority of all countries in the international community, it is fair to say that the CAC is well attended.
Finally, the CAC is closely linked to and recalled by the WTO rules – notably, the so-called SPS AgreementFootnote 14 – to adopt exceptions to free trade for the protection of health. In this regard, the presence of a standard and adherence to it through national regulatory measures make it possible to derogate from the rules of the liberalisation of free trade worldwide simply by reference to that standard: it is a presumption of compliance wherein national measures are considered automatically consistent with the WTO’s binding rules. On the other hand, if a more restrictive measure of the standard has been chosen, a scientific demonstration will have to be offered to show why this has been done, with the possibility of being called before a dispute resolution body to justify the divergence from the rules of international trade. This gives standards considerable binding force, even if factual and indirect.
The rigidity of the standards-based harmonisation system can create conflicts due to different interpretations as to whether products and substances are truly risky or not. This has actually happened in some of the most controversial and debated cases.Footnote 15 Nevertheless, above all, we need to think about the aims for which standards are adopted and the level of safety that is transfused in them, as balanced with the protection of international trade. The objectives of the CAC are contained in Article 1 of the Statutes, Footnote 16 where what is indicated in letter (a) is of particular relevance: “protecting the health of the consumers and ensuring fair practices in the food trade”.Footnote 17
Consumers’ health protection, set out as one of the CAC’s primary objectives, provides for forms of prevention and management of possible risks to avoid harm to consumers’ health, but it must be balanced against the other fundamental, complementary and linked objective of ensuring fair practices in the food trade.
With regard to health protection, the scope of the CAC’s measures must be framed within a proper interpretation of such words. In fact, the specific and exclusive reference to the category of “consumers” excludes the protection of health in general from the aims of the CAC. As reported in the aforementioned norm, the reference is to the final users of an asset (food), recognised as such and chosen for certain characteristics that it must inevitably possess. This has various consequences.
Firstly, the standards refer not only to the integrity of a substance, but also to the composition of a product in relation to its commercial name, to the labelling of certain foods Footnote 18 and, in general, to consumers’ trust and consumers’ information about ingredients and ways of production.
Secondly, the consumer reference excludes all safety standards regarding any harmful effects that can occur during production, transport or sales processes and is limited only to the stage of food ingestion. This reduces the scope of these rules, which, for example, do not deal with the use of pesticides or breeding techniques – except with regard to residues left in food – or with cases of the spread of contact or airborne diseases.
A third important aspect concerns the effectiveness of the standards: they will have, as final recipients, not only the nation states that will be required to comply with them, but also the individual producers of specific foods and the generality of the world’s consumers. In this sense, it should be noted that the reference to the health of consumers could weaken the judicial protection of their rights: consumers can act indeed as owners of collective rights, while health protection is in itself a fundamental and human right, as well as a duty for any governing body. Footnote 19
With regard to the second aspect of the objectives of the CAC, namely the fairness of trade practices, which standardisation aims to achieve by preventing states from using consumer protection as a pretext for protectionist practices, an interpretation of the term “fair practices in trade” must be provided. The phrase, translatable to “correct (or just) commercial conduct”, is, at present, susceptible to receiving various readings, because the term “fair” has more than one meaning. Among them, it seems consistent to qualify the adjective “fair” as “legitimate”: that is, not contrary to the rules governing the matter of trade in international law. The “legitimate trade practices” are therefore those that comply with the rules and principles contained in the relevant legislation, which, in this case, consists of the Marrakech Agreements (ie the treaties governing WTO law). Footnote 20 As far as it concerns food safety, this means respect for the norms foreseen by the SPS Agreement.Footnote 21 The confirmation of such interpretations is to be found in the recall, by such a Treaty, of CAC standards. Footnote 22
The CAC, in accordance with the principles of its Statutes and with those indicated by the SPS Agreement, issues specific and detailed rules defining, case by case, when products or substances have characteristics and requirements that are considered risky and not unduly restrictive to trade. The CAC’s work ensures that Member States’ food safety measures do not become an unjustified pretext for surreptitiously restricting national markets: consumer health protection, however paramount, cannot be used to limit the trade in food if there is no real justification for such a limit (referring to CAC standards or scientific demonstration of risk).
The two objectives are functionally linked and interdependent: the pursuit of health protection must be balanced with the compliance with the trade rules contained in the Marrakech treaties. The harmonising of interests, therefore, actually takes place in the process of drafting and approving standards and not at the time of their implementation at home by nation states: this will make them immediately compliant with WTO law and, therefore, recallable from the latter.
The rationale of the second part of Article 1, however, not only has the consequence of placing a limit on the function of health protection (or – to put it better – its unjustified use), but also has the effect of limiting the pursuit of this objective to demonstrations and regulatory limits contained in heterogeneous treaties established with the aim of ensuring and fostering different interests, often conflicting with the protection of health, such as the freedom of international trade. Footnote 23 The regulatory apparatus of the CAC draws its legal strength from WTO rules and is conditioned by the latter because the issuing of standards is functionalised to prevent health protection from becoming a market restriction technique, but it is not aimed at protecting health itself: “Codex has no public health mandate to which it must conform its decisions”. Footnote 24 The presence of a dual general purpose, which is divided into the pursuit of two potentially conflicting objectives, has the effect of disempowering health protection from the beginning of the regulatory process.
That said, recent experiences, as well as earlier ones, would suggest a paradigm shift in the aims of the CAC. This, as a complementary and linked regulator to the WTO, should become a subject in a dialectical position – almost opposed – to that of the latter, with a relationship of dependence and parentage exclusively with the WHO. This should result in a genuine institutional reform of the current system, which will be taken into account in Section V.1.
III. The precautionary principle and its opponents
The precautionary principle is commonly adopted and observed in the EU and its Member States by recalling environmental and food safety legislation and Treaties. Footnote 25 Nevertheless, this principle does not enjoy the same standing beyond Europe’s borders. Some countries, including the USA, do not recognise it, and the international treaties that mention it Footnote 26 are not able to guarantee its actuation when health protection and other concurrent interests, such as economic and commercial ones, enter into conflict. Among the various regulatory regimes that do not accept a precautionary approach, there is the WTO, which does not justify derogation to free trade grounded on precaution. Footnote 27
For the purpose of its increased dissemination, it must be said that there is still no single legal definition of the precautionary principle, and its application has long been the subject of discussion: Footnote 28 namely, there is debate about the content of such a principle, which is considered too indeterminate, and about the requirements necessary for it to be invoked, which would not be enough to avoid disguised protectionism. Footnote 29 However, the use of precaution in public policies can be defined as the possibility of adopting a provisional measure (therefore limited to a certain period of time) aimed at preventing risk to health or the environment (eg by denying a license, seizing products or imposing restraints on economic activities) on the basis of scientific assessments of an uncertain and inconclusive nature that highlight a possibility (but not a probability, much less a certainty) that the risk will occur. The same measure must be reasonable, consistent with the investigation on which it is based – hence with the technical evaluations carried out – and proportionate; that is, aimed at creating as little loss as possible for those affected by it.
On the basis of this principle, therefore, a public authority can justify its own regulatory and restrictive decision without having to scientifically prove that there is a causal link – a rational relationship – between the prohibited or limited good or activity and the feared risk: being able to simply prove that, on this issue, the science is uncertain and that a possibility of the risk exists.
It is often affirmed that the precautionary principle necessarily requires institutions to choose the most prudent path, perhaps with crippling effects on development. The principle is considered by some to be too demanding because in every human activity there are always potential and imponderable risks, which could see even relatively safe activities prohibited, since no human action is at zero risk. Others still see it as an alternative criterion to science, based on an ideological and non-objective approach. Finally, others identify it in a principle that automatically puts environmental protection over other interests.
All of these interpretations should be re-examined.
Firstly, the precautionary principle does not impose obligations: in the rules that foresee it, temporary risk management measures based on precaution “may be taken” by the relevant authorities. Footnote 30 The principle is thus an option for regulators to make a cost–benefit analysis and have the possibility to make a prudent choice if the conditions provided by the precautionary principle apply. Footnote 31 The principle at stake does not force – acting as a prescriptive rule – a mandatory prudence inclined to generate protectionism, but it does provide for an increment in the legitimate discretion of decision-makers, which allows them also to consider a precautionary alternative, justifying the final choice in an appropriate manner and according to predefined procedural criteria.
Secondly, the principle is not aimed at removing the risk, but at reducing it. Precautionary decisions must be reasonable, Footnote 32 proportionate Footnote 33 and adequately motivated: Footnote 34 if these characters are missing, a judge can nullify them. The presence of these criteria excludes the possibility that prudence may be invoked for trivial reasons, inconsistently or disproportionately in the relationship between the risk and the adopted measure.
Thirdly, precaution is not an alternative to technical–scientific assessments, but consequential to these, when they are unable to provide certain and reliable answers. Only in this case does political discretion – understood as a considered choice of subjects responding to an electorate or in front of other bodies – regain strength by exercising the power (for which it is responsible) to choose whether and how to decide. Footnote 35
Finally, despite the precautionary approach naturally belonging to the rationale of sustainable development Footnote 36 and therefore as a legal tool to protect the environment, it indeed works as a general and meta-procedural principle that enlarges the discretion of competent administrative authorities, allowing them to have an extra choice and to motivate it on prudence, in front of possible and uncertain risk. Footnote 37 Despite the fact that the precautionary principle was born Footnote 38 and is directed to environment and health protection (its main areas of application), it does not necessarily produce decisions with those effects: it is a tool, in the hands of public authorities, to be used with those purposes.
Beyond any prejudices against this principle, there is, as has been said, some resistance to its use on an extra-national and non-European scale. This approach is explained by the intention of avoiding protectionist measures disguised as attempts to protect health. Nevertheless, this is too negative a view of the precautionary principle. On the contrary, the EU experience is crucial in changing this evaluation: it is precisely the EU legislation – based on a common market, requiring scientific demonstrations for trade-restrictive measures and inspired by legal harmonisation – that places an important emphasis on precaution, without suffering negative consequences on free trade. In cases where scientific uncertainty does not allow for a full assessment of the alleged risks, it is up to risk managers (and not risk assessors – ie the experts who have assessed it, without producing reliable results), through their discretionary weighting and within the limits of the precautionary principle, to determine what is the quantity or quality of risk that society is able to bear Footnote 39 – even at the expense of the free movement of goods, as long as the application of this principle is surrounded by the guarantees already described in the previous paragraphs.
Hence, as will be discussed below (Section V.2), it is suggested that the precautionary principle will be more widely disseminated and applied globally, obtaining the implementation methods, the discipline and the limits to its use precisely by EU law.
IV. Traceability, compulsory labelling and controls on food safety
The aim of increasing and improving food safety regulation systems on a global scale (ie with reference to global institutions, but also widely, in different countries) should be based on the development, better application or reform of several regulatory instruments already in place but still not sufficiently effective and efficient. Above all, as the core of such a regulatory sector is the enhancement of public policies directed to the prevention of diseases through safer nutrition, improvements must involve two strategic regulatory tools in addition to those already mentioned in the previous paragraphs: mandatory labelling and controls by public authorities.
Labelling is an instrument of regulation that is essentially based on knowledge and the decrease of so-called information asymmetries between producers and consumers, with a considerable amount of data indicated on the various food packages. It is a less incisive measure of bans, prohibitions or seizures, but – particularly in the case of mandatory information to be labelled – it is able to reduce health risks, although still with a restrictive effect on the marketability of a product. At the same time, at an empirical assessment, labelling as an instrument of regulation, although widely used, has so far proved not to be very effective. This is because it has to be combined with the high awareness of consumers, who should spend more time reading the labels, assessing the information reported on the basis of their knowledge and weighing such assessments against those of convenience, concerning the prices of the goods to be purchased.
Nevertheless, with a view to strengthening the protection of health against harm from food products, the power of labels should not be underestimated. However, they must be used more forcefully and radically through a series of measures, which will be described below (Section V.3) and will briefly be outlined here.
Firstly, there must be an increase in the mandatory information to be borne by the producers. These must make visible, inter alia, whether aggressive, artificial, potentially polluting or harmful substances (even indirectly) to health are present or have been used during production.
Secondly, the traceability of each food must be complete, exhaustive and clear, with indications of the places where the food was produced, processed, altered, packaged, stocked and finally sold wholesale or retail.
Finally, the use of marks and label markings can make it easier to identify a food with a place of origin. This type of practice must be encouraged and enhanced in order to promote quality and territory-related productions, because they not only improve the sensory richness of a product, but indirectly also protect health by spreading foods that, because of their characteristics, should undergo less alteration with potentially harmful or non-natural products.
Another adjustment measure that needs to be enhanced is public controls on food productions and sale. These represent a crucial factor in food safety governance, and if we look at them on a global scale, there is an undeniable excessive fragmentation between the models adopted in various countries – with all of the differences concerning their efficiency and effectiveness. As the case of COVID-19 has perfectly demonstrated, if national and local product safety checks are not carried out correctly with the right frequency and with the ability to effectively impact food health guarantees, the common standards, norms and institutions aimed at protecting food safety risk losing incisiveness in achieving the objectives for which they had been drafted.
In this regard, in order to envisage a common and extensive comprehensive discipline of food safety controls, it is useful to model the recent reform adopted in the EU: EU Regulation n. 625/2017, Footnote 40 concerning the official controls performed by States to verify the conformity to the EU norms in various sectors of food and feed production.Footnote 41 This model is based on a set of common European norms and executive and effective tools and powers on behalf of nation states.
V. The regulation of food safety after the coronavirus: four proposals for a change in risk prevention
As anticipated, the analysis carried out so far has identified some critical points regarding the current regulation of food safety. Based on these considerations, four concrete proposals are suggested to reform the governance of the sector according to a more careful vision for risk prevention and health protection.
The first has an organisational–institutional nature and consists of a reform of the CAC and of its standardisation system, with the aim of increasing global health protection without resorting to State instruments that would risk encouraging protectionism.
The second is meta-procedural in nature and informs the rules of the game for regulators: it concerns the worldwide dissemination and application of the precautionary principle as it is used and interpreted in the EU and its member countries.
The third has to do with the specific discipline of regulation and consists of a particular instrument for this purpose being made more effective: mandatory labelling. This must be imposed for a higher number of substances and must contain more and more detailed information than it has now.
Finally, the latest proposal concerns a further aspect of the regulatory framework of food safety: namely, the system of controls. The proposal aims to set up a common model with rules and procedures shared on a global scale and executive activities on the territories, entrusted to the domestic authorities.
1. A new Codex Alimentarius Commission
As has been seen, at least in the fundamental objectives set out in the CAC’s Statutes, the latter has proved to be too conditioned by the WTO. It was also noted that the current global regulation of food safety presents an imbalance between health and free trade, for the benefit of the latter.
All of this suggests that the CAC should no longer be a standard-setter aimed at facilitating international trade – already fostered elsewhere – but one exclusively aimed at protecting health, which allows regulators to determine when, how and why the market for agro-food products can be closed or restricted for health reasons. In this way, the two regulatory systems would continue to be connected, but according to a horizontal design and not in a position of dependence, thus entering into a dialectical relationship to balance the different interests whose care is entrusted to them. The result is a paradigm shift for the CAC itself, which should only maintain one of its two fundamental objectives (ie to adopt standards on agro-food products in order to achieve a high level of protection of human health).
The clear distinction between the CAC and the WTO – which would not constitute a complete separation between the two governance systems – would create a form of dialogue of opposing terms between two global regulatory regimes, promoting a fair balancing between the different objectives and interests involved, which would “play on the same field”.Footnote 42 Moreover, the exemptions to free trade decided by the international community would be legitimised as not being derived from the protectionist arbitrariness of States, but decided on a global level. Finally, they would help to mitigate the current imbalance of global regulation, which is overly focused on freedom of trade and less on the protection of the weak and social interests (health, environment, social rights, welfare state, protection of workers, etc.).Footnote 43
From an organisational point of view, the solution could be found in the incorporation of the CAC within the WHO’s system alone. The CAC, therefore, would become an executive body controlled only by the WHO, attended by national delegates and based on independent scientific studies. It would be dedicated to identifying standards exclusively aimed at the protection of health in general – without the limitation of the consumers’ category – and directed at allowing the waiver of the rules of free trade whenever this is deemed necessary or appropriate.
While the CAC is essentially embedded in the WTO system, the WHO has so far developed itself as an autonomous regulation regime, with heterogeneous purposes and functions to those attributed to the CAC.Footnote 44 For this reason, and precisely as it is isolated from other international organisations, the WHO is a paradigmatic case for understanding the potential of “complex regimes”Footnote 45 and of the balance between different systems for the sake of a composition of interests in the non-national context. While the multipurpose nature of the FAO and CAC leads to an absorption of these interests into the macro-sectors of agricultural development and world trade, in this case there would be a dialectic between two regulatory regimes based on the production of health standards – which the WTO should also recognise as fully legitimate – having the legal strength and technical characteristics to operate as exemptions, exceptions or counter-limits to free trade.
2. The global precautionary principle
A second reform proposal concerns the dissemination and implementation, on a global scale, of the precautionary principle. With regards to what has been said above (Section III), it must be considered desirable – as well as theoretically possible in a strictly legal way – also to affirm the principle at stake in extra-European law. Global institutions could get the same principle out of EU law, but this innovation, it must be said, depends essentially on the contingent political will. For example, it should be the representatives of the governments who agree to a more precautionary change in the treaties governing the various subjects on a global scale – above all trade.
Current resistance is understandable, given the potential abuse of the suggested tool for implementing protectionist practices. Nevertheless, there are at least three reasons in favour of its use on a global scale.
First is its well-functioning in the EU legal order. To date, the precautionary principle has been used by the Union’s institutions and by the Member States in a widespread way in various matters, such as the environment or health protection. The Court of Justice is called into question if the precaution is unlawfully or disproportionately used and may nullify the measures based on those foundations,Footnote 46 while the common market continues functioning on a regular basis, without the principle giving rise to protectionist mechanisms between Member States.
The second is the need to increase health protection – on a global as well as a national level, even if it is in conflict with common standards. This approach would also trigger virtuous circuits, so that the precautionary resistance of one State would push others to increase their levels of protection. Although, as it was said at the start of this paper, events such as pandemics need a global response – in outbreak management as well as prevention – giving individual States the tools to impose an increase in health protection can have a positive effect not only within domestic systems, but also on common regulations.
Finally, the desire for greater discretion by national administrations would be a strong deterrent to the most radical protectionist movements, which would see a weapon weakened to challenge and counter global policies with illegitimate trade barriers (perhaps accepted by other international actors because of the geopolitical weight of those who implement them). Thanks to this principle, in fact, the national authorities could derogate from the common rules in the face of sensibilities, visions and approaches that are different from global ones – and with reference to sensitive and fundamental issues such as the environment and health – but only within the limits of a codified principle for which conditions, procedures and formalities are required. There is an increase in powers allocated at the domestic level, but it is contained. In the face of this, the ideological resistance to globalisation would have one less argument to use for its goals.
The application of the precautionary principle at the global level, qualifying as a decision-making criterion that can be used in certain areas (health, environment, etc.) only as a result of uncertain technical assessments, would constitute an important legal innovation to promote the protection of certain interests, balancing the harmonisation needs of supranational rules with the risk-regulating needs adopted at home, thus offering national administrations an extra weapon in the prevention of pandemics or other diseases. Hence, the centrality of the precautionary principle is evident: by ensuring rule-makers a more prudent and more interest-based decision-making alternative, it would produce a stronger and more effective protection of underrepresented goods and values such as the environment, biodiversity and health.
3. Compulsory labelling and traceability
The third proposal for reform of the food safety sector has to do with labelling, particularly mandatory labelling, and it links to the traceability and geographical identification of food. In this regard, three actions are suggested.
Firstly, certain food production techniques, which at present do not receive adequate publicity, must be made mandatory, explicit and simplified on labels: if a meat product comes out of intensive breeding; if genetically modified organisms have been used; if chemical herbicides have been used (eg glyphosateFootnote 47 ); if artificial preservatives or dyes have been used, etc. This type of guidance certainly comes at a cost to the biggest food producers, who may see their market damaged by the distrust of consumers regarding their goods. However, the obligatory use of this instrument encourages the use of agricultural techniques that are more environmentally friendly and the consumption of organic or otherwise more natural products, with a rebalancing of the agro-food market, which is currently in favour of large production and agro-industry, despite the proven advantages of small-scale, family and organic agriculture.Footnote 48
Secondly, labels should reconstruct the whole supply chain in a truthful and easily readable way, explicitly indicating the origin of the products and where they were cultivated, treated, processed and packaged. This second element of the labelling tool has a specific advantage that is consistent with the market economy system in which we live: to put States and their safety and quality control systems into competition, with a race-to-the-top effect. If – as the recent experience of COVID-19 has shown – the provenance of products from certain countries can affect their consumption (due to distrust in the control and regulation systems of some States), mandatory traceability will prompt rule-makers to implement governance models as efficiently and effectively as possible, being able to facilitate the export of national food products and encourage the spread of “good practices”. The rigour used in the traceability of the production chain generates competition between national regulators, with a trickle-down effect on the operators that are currently focused on the price, rather than the quality, of products.
Thirdly, the actual indication of provenance, if adequately guaranteed and protected from contamination and misleading information, may promote the excellence of certain products, anchored in specific geographical traditions and delimited to certain territories. This aspect – which can apparently be seen as a departure from the objective of “levelling the playing field”, belonging to the globalised market based on competition with equal arms – serves to protect superior or specialised production methods and to encourage competition between producers aimed at raising quality (and not only lowering costs), with the effect of favouring healthier productions because they are preferable to standardised ones. Even if such special protection for geographically connected products already exists – for example, in protected designations of origin (PDOs) and protected geographical indications (PGIs) – the present system, despite developing well in Europe, is still not widespread worldwide, where quality products are often damaged by fraud, imitation or insufficient protection.Footnote 49
These proposed changes may have some disadvantages, which must also be highlighted.
Firstly, readability: it is well known that too much information on the label is counterproductive. It is also necessary to study how certain indications are compatible with the knowledge of the average consumer, who does not have all of the tools to understand the consequences of ingesting certain substances. And yet, these very aspects suggest the importance of public regulation of the phenomenon: the institutions of global food security are called upon to involve experts in the various fields – not only those of the biological and medical sciences, but also those of communication, for instance – to identify labelling systems that are exhaustive, clear and effective.
Secondly, misinformation: there is inevitably the risk that untrue labels will change the message and have the exact opposite effect of what they were designed. This risk translates into a cost to public institutions responsible for the protection of food safety: public administrations must ensure – through indications, prescriptions, inspections and controls – that what is on the label corresponds to reality. And this type of activity requires significant resources and a comprehensive and shared organisation of controls. This second point will be discussed further in the following section, while the first point, being a matter of politics and not properly a legal issue, will depend on the open decisions of politicians in power from now on: the choice is whether to invest resources in this field, accepting the risk of unsatisfactory results or high costs, but with the opportunity to improve the current system.
4. A common system of food safety controls
Finally, with regards to the control system, it was anticipated that the aim of creating a common framework at a global level should follow the European pattern, contained in the EU Regulation n. 625/2017. This has the dual aim of rationalising and simplifying the regulatory framework on controls, incorporating different agro-food subjects into a single text and establishing a harmonised EU-wide discipline for organising these activities with reference to the entire food supply chain.
This model is an important paradigm for global food regulation. On the one hand, it maintains the regulatory discipline of agro-food in its harmonised and supranational nature, Footnote 50 and on the other hand, the execution of common rules – with a margin of discretion that may widen or narrow over time – occurs at the domestic level. This is coherent with the necessity of striking a balance between common and global prerogatives of a worldwide sector and the local components and interests related to food, which are strongly attached to territories and local traditions. Footnote 51
In establishing a set of common rules to ensure that food and feed are safe and healthy, Regulation n. 625 recognises that Member States have the power to make this unified legislation effective, directly carrying out official monitoring activities (which also include inspection powers, formal verification, sanctioning, etc.). It is in fact the States themselves that designate the competent authorities to carry out the checks provided by the Regulation, since they are “in the best position” (Considering n. 26, Reg. n. 625) to make this choice.
The considered norm standardises the content of regulatory action in the sector, including the ways, procedures, powers and forms by which such action must be put in place (by supranational and national or local actors). In addition, organisational models are made common, giving rise to a network system in which competences, functions and certain modes of implementation and organisation are defined by the European discipline, while the nation states are in charge of actuation, in connection with each other and with the Union institutions.
The rationale – to be considered as a model for global regulation – is that of a common governance that manages to centralise the regulation of the sector and is able to strike a difficult balance between two fundamental – yet critical – prerequisites for a taut system: the preservation of the domestic policies on issues of varying sensitivity at the local level; and that of providing for common rules that allow for the uniform development of a strategic economic sector for the whole area, particularly in terms of trade. The discipline is therefore both multilevel, because it divides certain tasks between the Union and the Member States, and composite, because it affects all of the competent actors operating within a common system.
In addition, the choice to qualify controls as a “system”, anchoring them to the need for compliance with Regulation n. 625, puts in place a model of network regulation, one that is, at the same time, supranational and transnational: the authorities operating in this sector not only respond to national policies and rules, but they are part of a system in connection with their counterparts in the other Member States and with the European Commission, in accordance with common principles and standards. To do this, they are called to adapt their organisational structures, functionalising them to the conduct of executive activities so that they are as consistent and in accordance with EU discipline as possible. The system is sectoral (only for agro-food), transnational (it brings all Member States together) and composite (it provides functions, powers, subjects and activities involving both the Union and the States). The implemented model is therefore a complex and multifaceted “common administrative system” consisting of heterogeneous bodies.
The European legislature has created a centralised system organised through a decentralised, coordinated and structured model according to a common design. The latter, however, does not determine the specific content of the control discipline, for which it makes a referral to the various substantive regulations, identifying shared principles, methodologies and procedures, which in turn are adopted as parameters for compliance checks on national authorities and operators. In this way, it functionalises domestic bodies to a harmonised European approach, leading to a simplification and speeding up of controls, in favour of greater efficiency.
The model maintains a reserve of local discretion without prejudicing common needs and establishes itself as a “partial denationalisation”, Footnote 52 which makes up for differences in common purposes and subordinates administrative activity to complex guidelines and principles. Thus, it follows a design that is transnational, because it involves joint and linked action by national authorities; centralised and supranational, because aims, approaches, principles, rules and organisational models are established or influenced by EU law; and decentralised, since the enforcement of the controls and activities related to them is entrusted to the domestic authorities.
The system described above can also be extended on a global scale, because – as has been shown by the COVID-19 story – efficiency, effectiveness and consistency of food safety controls are fundamental conditions for ensuring health and thus preventing the spread of new pandemics and, at the same time, ensuring the functioning of the current model of trade on a global scale. In this project, the role of the EU and the CAC should be filled by the WHO, with a dedicated body within the WHO being responsible for coordinating and supervising national controls, as well as the dissemination of uniform rules to be adapted in order to implement the common model established at the global level.
As one of its various advantages, this system would have a double positive effect: when a country complies with the controls adopted by the common model, a safety patent is granted to the products it intends to export, with guarantees and useful and beneficial consequences both in terms of health protection and from a commercial and economic point of view.
VI. Conclusions
COVID-19, a disease thought to be transmitted from animals to humans, caused the 2020 pandemic that, at the time of writing, is still out of control in many parts of the world. There is strong evidence that the infected animals had been displayed in a market lacking hygiene standards and proper controls, to be sold as food. In a process known as zoonosis, the host animals passed the virus onto humans, who, in turn, spread the disease into the wider community. There is strong evidence that an unsuitable, insufficient, flawed and excessively permissive food safety system was the key to the original transmission of the disease. The consequences of that initial inadequate regulation have been felt everywhere – and not only in the village, region or state where the virus originated. To date, millions have contracted the disease, with hundreds of thousands of deaths having occurred worldwide.
This brief synthesis of the outbreak now called the coronavirus pandemic helps us to summarise some important points discussed in this paper.
Firstly, food safety plays a central role in protecting health: a good system of food safety regulation allows us to work on disease prevention, both by protecting and incentivising the production of healthy and quality foods and by ensuring the protection of health at all stages of the supply chain, from the first steps of production to the final consumption.
Secondly, the protection of food safety is a matter of global importance: a worldwide problem or phenomenon must be tackled on a global scale. In order to continue enjoying the comparative advantages offered by the international market, the present model of trade regulation must be equipped – more than it currently is – with common and harmonised rules and regulatory structures, establishing exemptions to that system and able to protect other interests within the global market, including those that may conflict with some free trade prerogatives.
Finally, the global regulation of food safety requires – in light of the recent disaster, but also based on earlier data reported by key international organisations in the field – an increase in the level of health protection, even at the expense of commercial and productive prerogatives.
In order to implement the suggested improvements, various reforms may be implemented. Four are identified: (1) to transform the CAC into an organisation that issues international food safety standards with the sole and exclusive purpose of protecting health, in derogation of free trade rules; (2) to apply the precautionary principle on a global scale and in international organisations; (3) to strengthen the mandatory labelling tool, with real and complete traceability of the production chain and with information that is not only useful for guiding consumers, but also for directing manufacturers towards more virtuous processes; and (4) to create a common system of controls that, while leaving room for States in the executive phase, keeps principles, rules, procedures, coordination and supervision at the centre, and at the supranational level.
The discipline of agro-food concerns a strategic sector that is closely linked to the liberalisation of markets on a global scale and requires common rules that facilitate trade but also maintain high guarantees of safety and quality. This sector, therefore, needs a public organisational apparatus – with regulatory, executive and control functions – that is widespread and extensive and that acts uniformly and consistently, while leaving a margin of discretion to nation states for greater health protection. To date, however, the food safety regulation system has appeared to be unbalanced, at times ineffective and not sufficiently attentive to the protection of health and safety.
For these reasons, global decision-makers are called upon to improve and make more effective the current global regulatory framework by changing the objectives of common rules towards a more health-orientated design and by ensuring that these rules are implemented as homogeneously as possible, while leaving the executive activity to national bodies and their expertise.