INTRODUCTION
Settings for human-environment interactions are complex. They are composed of diverse ecological systems (including lakes, rivers, fisheries, forests, pastures, the ocean and the atmosphere), as well as human engineered systems (including roads, irrigation systems and communication networks). Finding ways to sustainably govern and manage these systems has become ever more difficult as they have become increasingly interlinked, and as the size of human populations and the level of economic development have both increased. Addressing this complexity must in turn overcome historical academic divisions between ecology, engineering and the social sciences, the tendencies of social scientists to build simplified models of complex systems in order to derive ideal types of governance, and an overreliance on a limited set of research methods to study social and environmental systems. To effectively sustain environmental systems, it is necessary to go beyond frequently-recommended simple panaceas to build general diagnostic frameworks that can be used to conduct rigorous research and achieve better policy analysis. The relevant disciplines need to be built on sounder theory of complex systems, and recognition of the nested levels and near-decomposability in such systems (for example see Brunckhorst Reference Brunckhorst2010).
In this paper, we first provide a brief overview of the current overreliance on panaceas, particularly with respect to the use of idealized property-rights regimes and the need to move beyond simple solutions to difficult and complex problems. Secondly, we review the progress that has been made in recent times in recognizing the need for a diversity of institutional processes that are matched to the scale and characteristics of the particular ecological and cultural systems involved. Specifically, we focus on institutional diversity in forest governance and a research programme concerning co-management of natural resources. Thirdly, we identify property rights within an institutional research programme and explore a relatively recent research programme that focuses on social-ecological systems (SESs). Fourthly, we discuss the relationship between the SES framework and a more diagnostic approach to analysis, as well as the relationship the SES framework has to earlier research on the design principles that appear to underlie sustainable governance systems related to small- and medium-sized common-pool resources. Finally, we discuss some implications these issues have on future research and draw several conclusions.
PANACEAS AND PROPERTY RIGHTS
Modern society faces a diversity of environmental problems, including biodiversity loss, diminishing natural resource stocks and the threat of massive climate change. Humans have developed a range of policy responses in their efforts to cope with environmental problems, with varying degrees of success. Unfortunately, the ability of scientists and analysts to explain and learn from these problems and diverse responses has been limited by a historically simplistic approach to policy analysis. We term this the panacea problem (Brock & Carpenter Reference Brock and Carpenter2007; Meinzen-Dick Reference Meinzen-Dick2007; Ostrom et al. Reference Ostrom, Janssen and Anderies2007).
The panacea problem occurs whenever a single presumed solution is applied to a wide range of problems. This problem has two distinct dimensions. The first dimension occurs in situations where a theory is too precise to be flexibly adapted to the range of cases to which it is applied. This dimension has been discussed extensively (Hayek Reference Hayek1945; Scott Reference Scott1998): a government may fail by homogenizing the diversity of contexts to which it applies its policies and management practices. This first dimension of the panacea problem is sometimes referred to as a blueprint approach to governance, which leads to a lack of fit between programmes and their supposed social-ecological targets (Korten Reference Korten1980). Numerous examples of this type of policy failure have been documented due to this dimension of the panacea problem. Evans (Reference Evans2004, pp. 30–31) described the problem within international development aid projects: ‘Currently, the dominant method of trying to build institutions that will promote development is to impose uniform institutional blueprints on the countries of the global south—a process which I call ‘institutional monocropping’. This process has produced profoundly disappointing results.’
Campbell et al. (Reference Campbell, Gordon, Luckert, Petheram and Vetter2006) analyzed the failures that have occurred in semi-arid grazing lands owing to the efforts of scholars to discover optimal stocking regimes and the efforts of government agencies to apply them. They suggested ‘a lack of connection between the micro-economics literature and natural science and social-anthropological literature’ and the need for a recognition ‘that policy prescriptions at national or even regional levels are likely to have limited value due to context specificity’ (Campbell et al. Reference Campbell, Gordon, Luckert, Petheram and Vetter2006, p. 75). This problem also pervades fisheries policy (St Martin et al. Reference St Martin, McCay, Murray, Johnson and Oles2007). As Degnbol et al. (Reference Degnbol, Gislason, Hanna, Jentoft, Raakjær, Nielsen and Clyde Wilson2006, p. 534) discussed: ‘Today, disciplinary boundaries narrow the perspective of fisheries management, creating tunnel vision and standardized technical fixes to complex and diverse management problems. . . . We claim that improvements in fisheries management will be realized not through the promotion of technical fixes but instead by embracing and responding to the complexity of the management problem.’
The other dimension of the panacea problem involves theories that are excessively vague instead of excessively precise. This has historically occurred when very general, ideal governance types or property regimes are advocated as being the primary way to manage natural resources successfully. Traditionally, economic and environmental policy analysis and their related fields have been dominated by this approach in the form of the state-market dichotomy (Weimer & Vining Reference Weimer and Vining2005).
More recently, some scholars have misunderstood a research programme studying community-based common-pool resource management (NRC [National Research Council] 1986, 2002; Feeny et al. Reference Feeny, Berkes, McCay and Acheson1990; Ostrom Reference Ostrom1990) that has illustrated the capacity of the users of a resource to develop and sustain common-property regimes. Based on this misunderstanding, some policy analysts have added a third ideal type to the first two, namely common-property management. Berkes (Reference Berkes2007, p. 15189) warned that ‘community-based conservation as a blueprint solution threatened to become a panacea itself’ (see also Hackel Reference Hackel1999; Barrett et al. Reference Barrett, Brandon, Gibson and Gjertsen2001; Murphree Reference Murphree2002). Unsurprisingly, this has led to a backlash of criticism against community-based natural resource management as a panacea (Shanmugaratnam Reference Shanmugaratnam1996; Satria et al. Reference Satria, Matsuda and Sano2006; but see Dressler et al. Reference Dressler, Büscher, Schoon, Brockington, Hayes, Kull, McCarthy and Shrestha2010).
Advocacy for each of these ideal types relies on a widely accepted tenet of environmental management and conservation: that property rights in one form or another over land or some other resource are required in order to provide the right incentives to participants (Hanna & Munasinghe Reference Hanna and Munasinghe1995). It is presumed that when someone does not own a resource, they have no long-term interests in sustaining the resource over time and thus cannot be expected to act beneficially towards that resource. Thus, without property rights, open-access conditions prevail, which frequently do lead to environmental destruction (Dasgupta & Heal Reference Dasgupta and Heal1979; Brander & Scott Taylor Reference Brander and Scott Taylor1998). The closely related dichotomies of the state versus the market and of private versus public ownership have been fortified in part by falsely presuming that any resource not owned privately or by a government is an open-access resource (Hardin Reference Hardin1968; Alchian & Demsetz Reference Alchian and Demsetz1973). The frequently proposed alternative to open access is one of the two idealized property-rights regimes, namely government or private ownership.
These idealized governance types have been applied to environmental conservation in several ways. One important example has been through the implementation of protected areas and national parks. Private ownership, or a mix of public and private ownership and management, also has a history of promotion and implementation through conservation easements and conservation by farmers and rangers (Western & Wright Reference Western, Wright, Western and Wright1994; Cooper et al. Reference Cooper, Bernstein and Claasen2005; Fairfax et al. Reference Fairfax, Gwin, King, Raymond and Watt2005; Brunson & Huntsinger Reference Brunson and Huntsinger2008), and the Convention on Biological Diversity (URL http://www.cbd.int/) stresses the importance of conservation outside of public areas. However, public ownership with stringent formal regulations regarding use patterns is still seen in some circles as the silver bullet to biodiversity conservation (Terborgh Reference Terborgh1999; Lovejoy Reference Lovejoy2006).
As of 2005, approximately 86% of the world's forests were owned by national governments and protected areas had grown to cover c. 6.4 million km2 of forest globally (Agrawal et al. Reference Agrawal, Chhatre and Hardin2008). By 2010, the percentage of forest land owned by national governments had decreased to 80% (FAO [Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations] 2010), signalling a slight shift away from state-centred and administrated forest governance regimes. Interestingly, Agrawal et al. (Reference Agrawal, Chhatre and Hardin2008, p. 1462) concluded that ‘the effectiveness of forest governance is only partly explained by who owns forests. At the local level, existing research finds only a limited association between whether forests are under private, public, or common ownership and changes in forest cover or sustainability of forest management.’
These results, which are part of a larger research programme we will discuss shortly, illustrate the difficulties that arise from panacea prescriptions. Ideal governance types as panaceas may be so general as to contain little real prescriptive content (Dietz et al. Reference Dietz, Ostrom and Stern2003). There is, for example, an extremely large number of practical variations of public ownership and governance. This allows for other variables and more specific institutional processes to affect outcomes. In this case the problem is not misplaced precision, but institutional prescriptions that are devoid of meaningful content.
EXAMINING INSTITUTIONAL DIVERSITY
Diversity of forest institutions around the world
Some progress has been made to move forward from the overreliance on panaceas in efforts to improve environmental conservation. An important component of this progress is the extensive empirical research now conducted on the diversity of institutions found around the world that are involved in environmental conservation (Berkes & Turner Reference Berkes and Turner2006; Ostrom & Nagendra Reference Ostrom and Nagendra2006; Bray Reference Bray2010). Empirical studies are uncovering a diversity of institutions that achieve sustainable development, as well as those that do not. Several factors beyond the very generalized labels associated with the idealized property-rights regimes discussed above are associated with successes in the field.
Many of these empirical studies have been conducted within the International Forestry Resources and Institutions (IFRI) research programme, active since the early 1990s. At that time, Marilyn Hoskins of the FAO asked Elinor Ostrom whether the Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis would apply their prior theory and methods to forestry resources and begin a long-term collaborative research network of centres located around the world (Gibson et al. Reference Gibson, McKean and Ostrom2000; Poteete & Ostrom Reference Poteete and Ostrom2004; Wollenberg et al. Reference Wollenberg, Merino, Agrawal and Ostrom2007). IFRI programme collaborating centres are now located in Bolivia, Colombia, Guatemala, India, Kenya, Mexico, Nepal, Tanzania, Thailand, Uganda and the USA, with new centres being established in Ethiopia and China. IFRI is the only interdisciplinary long-term monitoring and research programme studying forests owned by governments, private organizations and communities in multiple countries.
Forests are a particularly important form of land cover given their role in climate change related emissions and carbon sequestration (Canadell & Raupach Reference Canadell and Raupach2008), the biodiversity they contain (Dallmeier & Comiskey Reference Dallmeier and Comiskey1998), and their contribution to rural livelihoods in developing countries and regions (Shackleton & Shackleton Reference Shackleton and Shackleton2004). As mentioned already, government-owned protected areas are frequently recommended as ‘the’ way of preserving the ecosystem services generated by forests (Terborgh Reference Terborgh1999).
In an effort to examine whether government ownership of protected areas is a necessary condition for improving forest density, Hayes (Reference Hayes2006) used IFRI data to compare different forest governance types via a rating of forest density (on a five-point scale) assigned to a forest by the forester or ecologist who had supervised the mensuration of trees, shrubs and ground cover in a random sample of forest plots. Of the 163 forests included in the analysis, 76 were government-owned forests legally designated as protected forests, and 87 were public, private or communally owned forested lands used for a wide diversity of purposes. No statistical difference was found between the forest densities in officially designated protected areas and all other forested areas.
Conversely, other IFRI studies have found that lower-level (more specific) variables can be very significant. Gibson et al. (Reference Gibson, Williams and Ostrom2005), for example, examined the monitoring behaviour of 178 forest user groups and, controlling for many other variables, found a strong positive correlation between the level of monitoring and a forester's assessment of forest density. Recent studies by Coleman (Reference Coleman2009) and Coleman and Steed (Reference Coleman and Steed2009) also found that a major variable affecting forest conditions was investment in monitoring by local users. Further, when local users are given harvesting rights, they are more likely to monitor illegal uses themselves. Other studies also stress the relationship between local monitoring and better forest conditions (Banana & Gombya-Ssembajjwe Reference Banana, Gombya-Ssembajjwe, Gibson, McKean and Ostrom2000; Ghate & Nagendra Reference Ghate and Nagendra2005; Ostrom & Nagendra Reference Ostrom and Nagendra2006; Webb & Shivakoti Reference Webb and Shivakoti2008).
Chhatre and Agrawal (Reference Chhatre and Agrawal2008) examined the changes in the condition of 152 forests under diverse governance arrangements as affected by the size of the forest, collective action around forests related to improvement activities, size of the user group and the dependence of local users on a forest. They found that ‘forests with a higher probability of regeneration are likely to be small to medium in size with low levels of subsistence dependence, low commercial value, high levels of local enforcement, and strong collective action for improving the quality of the forest’ (Chhatre & Agrawal Reference Chhatre and Agrawal2008, p. 1327).
The legal designation of a forest as a protected area is not by itself related to forest density. Our research shows that forests under different property regimes (government, private or communal) sometimes meet enhanced social goals such as biodiversity protection, carbon storage or improved livelihoods, but sometimes these property regimes fail to provide such goals. Indeed, when governments adopt top-down decentralization policies, leaving local officials and users in the dark, stable forests may become subject to deforestation (Banana et al. Reference Banana, Vogt, Bahati and Gombya-Ssembajjwe2007). Detailed field studies of monitoring and enforcement illustrate the challenge of achieving high levels of forest regrowth without active involvement of local forest users (see Batistella et al. Reference Batistella, Robeson and Moran2003; Agrawal Reference Agrawal2005; Andersson et al. Reference Andersson, Gibson and Lehoucq2006; Tucker Reference Tucker2008). Thus, it is not the general type of forest governance that is crucial in explaining forest conditions; rather, it is how a particular governance arrangement fits the local ecology and social context, how specific rules are developed and adapted over time, and whether users consider the system to be legitimate and equitable (for a more detailed overview of the IFRI research programme, see Poteete et al. Reference Poteete, Janssen and Ostrom2010, chapter 5).
Co-management and polycentricity
Progress has also been made horizontally by considering multiple idealized governance types at once (as opposed to vertically, digging down into the importance of lower-level institutional variables). It has been increasingly recognized that, even within the three ideal governance types, a mix of these idealized property regimes is likely to be more appropriate in many situations than any single one (Lubell Reference Lubell, Scholz and Stiftel2005; Scholz & Wang Reference Scholz and Wang2006). Indeed, many communities associated with common-property arrangements actually employ a mix of common and private property (Ostrom Reference Ostrom1990). For example, it is typical in community-based irrigation systems for agricultural parcels of land to be privately owned, while the water and pastures are held as common property (Trawick Reference Trawick2001).
Two or three of the idealized governance types can interact in environmental conservation contexts. For example, recent cap-and-trade programmes effectively combine government management and private ownership of the traded rights (Stavins Reference Stavins2008). One important and now firmly established branch of research explores the outcomes that result from co-management of a natural resource between user groups and governments (Carlsson & Berkes Reference Carlsson and Berkes2005; Borrini-Feyerabend et al. Reference Borrini-Feyerabend, Pimbert, Farvar, Kothari and Renard2007; Brunckhorst et al. Reference Brunckhorst, Reeve, Morley, Bock, Pettit, Cartwright, Bishop, Lowell, Pullar and Duncan2008). There is a close relationship between the literature on co-management and the study of institutions as an organizing concept for analysing social systems (Sandström Reference Sandström2009).
Several justifications exist for adopting co-management arrangements to address environmental problems. First, scholars focusing on one level frequently find that processes at another level affect outcomes. Local systems are increasingly affected by external economic events and public policies. This argues for the inclusion of larger governance units when undertaking analysis of small-scale governance arrangements (Agrawal Reference Agrawal2003). Meanwhile, others have noted the difficulties that top-down government or international development agency interventions have faced when they do not take local user groups into account (Lam Reference Lam1998). This finding is also reflected in the IFRI programme. When local users are not involved in any aspect of the planning of a new project, they have no vested interest in the success of the project, and worse, they can directly or indirectly act to undermine it. In contrast, when users are involved, they can potentially use local knowledge to make a governance regime more adaptive, if collaborative arrangements are used to facilitate systematic learning (Armitage et al. Reference Armitage, Berkes and Doubleday2007).
Additionally, particular governance arrangements may have comparative advantages in resolving different types of problems. Local user groups frequently have comparative advantages in gathering and maintaining knowledge of local ecological complexity that would be costly for governments to collect (Moller et al. Reference Moller, Berkes, Lyver and Kislalioglu2004). However, communities may have comparative disadvantages in managing large-scale natural resources and environmental pollution problems (Rose Reference Rose, Ostrom, Dietz, Dolšak, Stern, Stonich and Weber2002).
Berkes (Reference Berkes, Ostrom, Dietz, Dolšak, Stern, Stonich and Weber2002) noted that co-management is not merely a task of assigning components of an environmental problem to various groups of participants and their associated property regimes. Because of cross-scale social and biophysical linkages, the interplay between local and more central governance structures must also be taken into account (Young Reference Young2002; Hill et al. Reference Hill, Williams, Pert, Robinson, Dale, Westcott, Grace and O'Malley2010). Additionally, co-management is not necessarily between a monolithic central government and one coherent community. Rather, it is a more complex arrangement between multiple sources of governance, or what has been referred to as polycentricity (McGinnis Reference McGinnis1999; Ostrom Reference Ostrom and McGinnis1999a, Reference Ostrom and McGinnisb).
A polycentric governance structure may at first seem chaotic. It was a fear of this supposed disorder resulting from the interactions among multiple decision-makers that for decades led many scholars and practitioners to advocate either extreme centralization or extreme decentralization and privatization in order to make decisions the function of one coherent decision-maker (Marshall Reference Marshall2005). However, extensive study of communities of users has established that polycentric arrangements that enable users to develop rules and organizations at multiple levels can work effectively (Ostrom et al. Reference Ostrom, Parks and Whitaker1978; Bromley & Feeny Reference Bromley, Feeny, McKean, Peters, Gilles, Oakerson, Runge and Thomson1992; Ostrom & Parks Reference Ostrom, Parks and McGinnis1999). Coping with all our present environmental problems will likely require similar polycentric governance arrangements across geographic scales beyond those considered by many community case studies (see Brunckhorst et al. Reference Brunckhorst, Coop and Reeve2006).
INSTITUTIONS AND SOCIAL-ECOLOGICAL SYSTEMS
Institutional frameworks
Over the past several decades, there has been a gradual shift in the literature from an exclusive focus on general property-rights regimes to a more inclusive emphasis on the institutions that affect environmental conditions. Institutions are defined as ‘potentially linguistic entities . . . that refer to prescriptions commonly known and used by a set of participants to order repetitive, interdependent relationships’ where ‘prescriptions refer to which actions (or states of the world) are required, prohibited, or permitted’ (Ostrom Reference Ostrom1986, p. 5). Institutions may be seen as commonly understood codes of behaviour that potentially reduce uncertainty, mediate self-interest and facilitate collective action.
Property-rights arrangements or regimes are one important result of institutional processes that affect outcomes. The three broad property-rights regime categories discussed earlier are a function of a myriad of specific rules that govern a particular setting. A functional common-property regime for a grazing pasture, for example, results from many rules, including those that specify rights and conditions for resource access, monitoring and leadership positions, possible sanctions and demands for contributions (Netting Reference Netting1972). A property right held by an actor results from these rules and enables the actor to take particular actions (Schlager & Ostrom Reference Schlager and Ostrom1992). In this context, the study of property rights becomes part of a more expansive study of the institutions that affect environmental conservation and natural resource management.
Following this transition, the task remains to construct the theories that relate institutional processes, including property rights, to outcomes. We have identified the two extremes in our discussion of the panacea problem: excessively general theories and excessively precise models. Costs are associated with each of these two problems, the first being a lack of meaningful content of overly general theories, and the second being a lack of applicability or accuracy with overly precise models (Cox Reference Cox2008). Young (Reference Young2002, p. 175) stated the resulting task for institutional analysts as follows: ‘What is necessary, at least at this stage, is an intermediate approach that avoids both pitfalls of excessive generalization and limitations arising from the treatment of each environmental problem as unique.’
Several frameworks have been developed to facilitate the construction of such theories and the institutional analysis of environmental management and conservation. Schlager (Reference Schlager and Sabatier2007, p. 294) described the importance of frameworks in scientific progress: ‘Frameworks provide theories with the general classes of variables that are necessary to explain phenomena. As theory development proceeds, frameworks may be revised to provide additional content and specificity to general classes of variables.’ Thus the relationship between framework and theory development is complementary and reciprocal. One institutional framework with which we are quite familiar is known as the institutional analysis and development (IAD) framework.
The IAD framework is best thought of as a metatheoretical conceptual map that identifies an action situation, patterns of interactions, outcomes and an evaluation of these outcomes (Fig. 1). Efforts to explain collective action in field settings with diverse structures, particularly the complex public economies of USA metropolitan areas and common-property regimes around the world, were the stimuli leading to the development of the IAD framework. The IAD framework is consistent with multiple theories and models, but its closest relationship is to the language of game theory, since the working parts of an action situation and a game are intended to be the same.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921145648-87862-mediumThumb-S0376892910000834_fig1g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Figure 1 A framework for institutional analysis. Adapted from Ostrom (Reference Ostrom2005, p. 15).
An action situation is a central part of the IAD framework, and is internally structured by seven working parts, including (1) the set of actors, (2) the sets of positions actors fill in the context of this situation, (3) the set of allowable actions for actors in each position, (4) the level of control that an individual or group has over an action, (5) the potential outcomes associated with each possible combination of actions, (6) the amount of information available to actors, and (7) the costs and benefits associated with each possible action and outcome. These seven attributes of an action situation can be thought of as core micro variables that affect the preferences, information, strategies and actions of participants. Each attribute can take multiple forms that jointly affect the decisions made by actors. The internal structure of an action situation is itself affected by the relevant biophysical world, the community within which it is located, as well as by the specific rules in use. In light of fieldwork and further analysis, seven types of rules are posited to be most important in affecting outcomes in an action situation, as these are the rules that directly affect each of the internal working parts (Fig. 2).
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921145648-48515-mediumThumb-S0376892910000834_fig2g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Figure 2 Rules as external variables directly affecting the elements of an action situation. Adapted from Ostrom (Reference Ostrom2005, p. 189).
The IAD framework has been used as the foundation for creating coding forms to be used in an extensive meta analysis of irrigation and fishery cases around the world (see Schlager Reference Schlager1990; Tang Reference Tang1992), for irrigation systems in Nepal (Shivakoti & Ostrom Reference Shivakoti and Ostrom2002) and for the extensive studies of forests undertaken by the IFRI network. As such, the framework has proven to be quite useful, and the body of theory produced, particularly in common-pool resource (CPR) settings, is now extensive (Ostrom Reference Ostrom and Sabatier2007a). However, there have been increasing numbers of calls for a more biophysically sophisticated approach to these settings (Berkes & Folke Reference Berkes and Folke1998; Young Reference Young2002; Agrawal Reference Agrawal2003). It has become increasingly accepted that in order to make progress in environmental conservation theory and practice, an interdisciplinary approach needs to be taken that recognizes the equal importance of social and biophysical variables (Walker & Salt Reference Walker and Salt2006; Brunckhorst Reference Brunckhorst2010). We now turn our discussion to a more recent framework that addresses this issue, among others.
Social-ecological frameworks
Elinor Ostrom (Reference Ostrom2007b, Reference Ostrom2009) has introduced a diagnostic framework for the study of complex social-ecological systems (SESs). SESs are defined by Anderies et al. (Reference Anderies, Janssen and Ostrom2004) as social systems ‘in which some of the interdependent relationships among humans are mediated through interactions with biophysical and non-human biological units.’ A primary interest of scholars focusing on SESs has been examining their ability to sustain themselves in the face of disturbances over time, a feature which has been referred to by a wide range of concepts, including adaptive capacity, resilience, robustness, stability and transformability. These terms are used by various communities of scholars for different purposes, leading to some confusion in their meanings. At times they are used interchangeably, and other times different authors use a term in contradictory ways. An important common element, however, is their focus on dynamics of systems over time. This is an important step forward from the traditional ‘comparative statics’ (see Marshall Reference Marshall2005) approach, and is complementary to the progress in resolving the panacea problem discussed earlier.
McGinnis (Reference McGinnis2010) presented a revised version of the SES framework, composing a SES of several primary classes of entities, which are in turn embedded in a social, economic and political setting, and in related ecosystems (Fig. 3). Resource systems, resource units, governance systems and social systems composed of actors are the primary components of a SES. A SES can have multiple instances of each of these primary components. For example, within a SES there could be multiple resource systems, such as a forest, a lake and a river system. Each of these entities, in turn, has a set of attributes that can take on various values.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921145648-96445-mediumThumb-S0376892910000834_fig3g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Figure 3 Revised SES framework combining the IAD and SES frameworks (Source: McGinnis Reference McGinnis2010).
McGinnis (Reference McGinnis2010) also worked to combine the IAD and the SES frameworks; the primary source of integration is in the component labelled focal action situations (see Fig. 3). McGinnis (Reference McGinnis2010) conceptualized this as a network of interrelated action situations. To illustrate how this concept can organize the study of a SES, we briefly discuss here the case of the Taos valley acequias, a network of community-governed irrigation systems in northern New Mexico (Cox Reference Cox2010).
Illustrating action situations in a social-ecological system
The approximately 51 acequias in the Taos valley (Fig. 4) have an average of 40 members, and have maintained agricultural productivity over a long period of time in a high-desert environment by maintaining high levels of collective action. This cooperation is required in order to build and sustain the irrigation infrastructure that steers snowmelt-derived surface water from the rivers flowing out of the eastward mountains out onto their irrigation fields. Each acequia is organized by a common-property arrangement to distribute its water and maintain its infrastructure, and is governed by an executive mayordomo and a set of three administrative commissioners who carry out these arrangements.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921145648-35984-mediumThumb-S0376892910000834_fig4g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Figure 4 Map of the Taos valley and acequia irrigated land.
The Taos valley acequias use two primary levels of governance: one within each acequia and another between groups of acequias. We can conceive of these as being two different classes of action situations. The primary function of having these two classes is to create a two-tiered governance structure that minimizes the number of actors involved in any one action situation. With fewer actors, transaction costs are lowered and trust and reciprocity are more easily maintained. This is done in two steps. First, the larger SES that the Taos valley acequias constitute is broken up into the 51 acequias, each of which has its own independent decision-making arrangements developed to resolve internal collective-action problems. This creates a set of action situations within each acequia with regard to the important collective tasks that must be accomplished, such as infrastructure provision as a public good and the distribution of water.
These action situations do not, however, resolve collective-action problems among acequias, as many of them are along the same rivers and have the same upstream-downstream relationship as do their individual members with each other. What is needed is a second set of action situations that take place among sets of acequias. The actors that participate in these settings are a subset of the acequia membership, namely the acequia mayordomos and commissioners. Because it is primarily the acequia officers who participate in these water-sharing agreements (repartimientos), the number of actors, and thereby the magnitude of the transaction costs, is also kept low at this second level of governance. Through these repartimientos, the acequias are able to maintain at least some level of cooperation in the distribution of water along the entire reach of a river.
These two types of action situations do not exhaust the arenas of decision-making that are relevant for the acequias. Local courts, for example, have frequently been an important source of conflict resolution for the acequias. This system has sustained the acequias for several hundred years. However, dramatic changes during the past several decades have altered the traditional incentives and disrupted the functioning of these irrigation systems. These changes include emigration of younger members, the introduction of a tourist economy and wealthy landowners, and an accompanying low-wage labour-market into the area.
A DIAGNOSTIC APPROACH
Continuing to unpack the SES framework
We now discuss the concept of diagnosis and how it may be facilitated by the SES framework. Diagnosis traditionally means ascertaining the nature or cause of something, usually of an unwanted condition. Tied to a diagnosis is the idea that different types of causes have implications for the efficacy of different types of treatments. The possible amelioration of a condition by successfully applying a particular treatment is the motivation for the process. Our interest in the process of diagnosis here is to explore the possibility of its use in overcoming the panacea problem discussed earlier.
The concept of diagnosis is not novel to its application to environmental conservation and natural resource management. The field of medicine has faced a long struggle in its efforts to overcome the recommendation of panaceas, such as various purges and use of aspirin, to solve an immense variety of physical ailments. Over time, biology has developed a rigorous nested approach to the study of the human body and medicine has adopted a diagnostic approach to understanding the problems related to individual health. Instead of offering one or a few general remedies for most problems (as was common in the nineteenth century), a doctor now asks several initial questions about the potential sources of a health problem and then probes deeper using X-rays and other diagnostic tools after assessing information about higher-level indicators (such as temperature, blood pressure, weight change and reported pain levels). Scholars and practitioners concerned with preserving the environment and maintaining its vital functions still need to develop a rigorous nested approach to analysis.
In the previous section we briefly explored some features of the SES framework. One feature we have not yet discussed is its multi-tiered quality. The primary entities (Fig. 3) are the first level of the framework. These are each associated with a set of attributes, which can, in turn, be decomposed into a set of subattributes to form the second level (or third level) of the framework (Fig. 5). These attributes can work to form particular types of entities that possess them, and it would be possible to arrange these types into hierarchical taxonomies. Depending upon an array of attributes, there may be different types of resource systems, for example, or different types of governance systems. There may also be different types of processes occurring within action situations. For example, social and environmental monitoring are two subtypes of the broader process of monitoring.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921145648-74550-mediumThumb-S0376892910000834_fig5g.jpg?pub-status=live)
Figure 5 Unpacking the SES framework into multiple levels.
This typological decomposition, which we leave for future work, is important for the diagnostic approach, because it enables analysis of different types of environmental problems and systems in order to determine what have been the most effective types of social-institutional responses to various types of natural systems and problems. This point was reinforced by Young (Reference Young2002, p. 176), when he discussed the importance of a diagnostic approach in addressing environmental problems: ‘the diagnostic approach seeks to disaggregate environmental issues, identifying elements of individual problems that are significant from a problem-solving perspective and reaching conclusions about design features necessary to address each element.’
Diagnosis and design principles
The SES framework discussed so far is exploratory and tentative. Nevertheless, it can help scholars move beyond the panacea problem by providing multiple levels of analysis. Across levels of the framework, an analyst can determine what is critically important in determining outcomes for one case, or for a whole set of cases. The larger the number of cases under examination, the more general the approach required, using the first or second levels of analysis, in order to produce accurate theories. This observation follows from the principle that at higher levels of aggregation, patterns can be more predictably found across a set of observations (Levin Reference Levin1992, Reference Levin1999). Thus, for a large number of cases, highly specific rules that produce particular outcomes across every case are unlikely to be found. What is more likely is that, when generalizing to a large number of cases, broad social and biophysical attributes associated with general categories of outcomes may be identified.
An example of this process and this principle is the development of a set of institutional design principles (Ostrom Reference Ostrom1990), which characterize long-lasting community-based natural resource management systems. Ostrom (Reference Ostrom1990) had searched for specific rules that might persist across many of these systems, but could not find a specific pattern; however, in agreement with Levin's principle, Ostrom (Reference Ostrom1990) found coarser patterns which were embodied in the design principles. Cox et al. (Reference Cox, Arnold and Villamayor-Tomas2010) have analysed 91 studies produced since Ostrom's (Reference Ostrom1990) original work that evaluate the principles, and found them to be moderately well-supported. We summarize their central findings here:
(1) Support for the principles was consistent across the primary sectors examined (forests, fisheries, pasture and irrigation).
(2) Support did not differ significantly between empirical studies that explicitly examined the principles and those that examined them implicitly.
(3) Conditions stipulated by each individual principle were significantly more likely to be found in successful cases of community-based natural resource management than in unsuccessful cases, and these conditions were significantly more likely to be absent in unsuccessful cases than in successful cases.
(4) Much of the criticism and lack of support for the principles came from abstract studies. Empirical studies (case studies, syntheses and large-n statistical analyses), which presented evidence for or against one or more particular principles, were moderately supportive of the principles.
In their review, Cox et al. (Reference Cox, Arnold and Villamayor-Tomas2010) also discussed several prominent critiques of Ostrom's principles that have arisen since their introduction. As implied by the list above, these criticisms were primarily abstract or theoretical. The main empirical criticism was that the principles did not exhaustively list all the relevant factors associated with sustainability, and this is certainly the case. The primary theoretical criticism found in the literature was that the design principles represent just the panacea problem discussed above. The principles are seen by some scholars as an example of the first type of panacea problem: overspecificity. They are seen as representing an overgeneralization to a broad range of cases, abstracting excessively from local context and history of particular cases (Cleaver Reference Cleaver1999, Reference Cleaver2000; Steins & Edwards Reference Steins and Edwards1999; Young Reference Young2002; Blaikie Reference Blaikie2006).
We can use the SES framework and the discussion thus far to better understand this issue. In constructing the principles, Ostrom initially was looking for specific rules that typified successful long-lasting systems. In the absence of such specific patterns, Ostrom resorted to more aggregated conditions that she labelled design principles. In doing so, she traded off specificity for more general applicability.
Several of the principles mentioned by Ostrom are processes that occur within action situations, such as graduated sanctioning and monitoring by accountable monitors. Processes in action arenas result, or emerge, from a configuration of social and biophysical factors, not just one particular rule (Figs. 1–2). This is why it was difficult for Ostrom (Reference Ostrom1990) to find patterns at the more specific level of individual rules; because they are merely one component of a complex configuration producing emergent processes and outcomes (see also fig. 1 in Brunckhorst Reference Brunckhorst2010). When other elements of a configuration change, the effects of a particular rule are likely to change as well. However, the more general conditions stipulated by the principles can be satisfied by a variety of these configurations. The condition of monitoring, for example, encompasses a diversity of configurations of social and biophysical factors that may produce such a condition, and thus can avoid excessive specificity.
Other design principles correspond to important level 2 variables. Along with the other general high-level attributes of the main components of a SES, the design principles can serve as a starting point for a diagnostic approach to the study of complex SESs. These highly aggregated attributes include the idealized property-rights regimes discussed earlier. To conclude, the design principles lack an important degree of specificity. This is a limitation, because they are less precise than a more specific theory could be. It is also a potential strength, in that they may avoid the panacea problem of overspecificity, and serve as part of a basis for a diagnostic approach to analysis.
FUTURE WORK
We have reviewed the panacea problem, which needs to be confronted in order to advance the science and the practice of environmental conservation. We have also presented some potential advances in accomplishing this task, and discussed the multi-tiered interdisciplinary framework that, once fully developed, can capture social-ecological properties and dynamics to promote understanding of complex SESs. However, much work remains to firmly establish a research programme using a diagnostic approach that facilitates the accumulation of empirical data on both social and biophysical variables at multiple levels of aggregation. Several promising areas in which such work could be done can be identified.
To begin, our discussion has focused primarily on the structural properties of social-ecological situations, without much discussion of the dynamics or processes that occur within them. Ecosystem ecology, which, in addition to focusing on ecosystem structure, emphasizes the study of flows of material and energy through ecosystems, may provide a lesson in understanding dynamics (Chapin et al. Reference Chapin, Matson and Mooney2002). A similar approach could be taken to the study of SESs. One way may be to introduce a typology of disturbances that may affect SESs over time (Schoon & Cox Reference Schoon and Cox2010), thus moving beyond a historically static (or comparative static) approach to the study of social systems and SESs. This method may thus incorporate more ecological components and dynamics into frameworks and studies, which are currently underemphasized in this work.
In addition to this consideration, the approach here has several methodological implications. The SES framework, and the diagnostic perspective more generally, requires that case studies be conducted, where an analyst examines one case at various levels of specificity or generality, as needed. These case studies can be useful in stimulating new theoretical developments: ‘close examination of individual cases offers opportunities to develop concepts and theory, identify the limits of general relationships and disprove deterministic hypotheses, control for confounding effects through within-case comparisons, and disentangle causal processes’ (Poteete et al. Reference Poteete, Janssen and Ostrom2010, p. 33).
Following the completion of a number of case studies, the research programme can move to a different well-established methodology, namely meta-analyses (Ostrom Reference Ostrom1990; Pagdee et al. Reference Pagdee, Kim and Daugherty2006; Rudel Reference Rudel2008; Cox et al. Reference Cox, Arnold and Villamayor-Tomas2010). Meta-analysis here would initially involve coding a set of cases consistently through the SES framework. A challenge that previous efforts have faced is the lack of consistency in what variables are discussed in individual cases. Previous meta-analyses have had to review a large number of cases to identify a small set that contained information about the same set of variables (Ostrom et al. Reference Ostrom, Gardner and Walker1994; Pagdee et al. Reference Pagdee, Kim and Daugherty2006). This problem can begin to be addressed by conducting case studies with the SES framework in mind at the outset. This, in turn, will help those case studies by guiding the analyst towards the possible variables for consideration.
Following data coding, the next step is to look for patterns across cases. According to Levin's (Reference Levin1992, Reference Levin1999) principle, there are more likely to be consistent patterns across many cases at higher levels of aggregation in the framework. For example, it is likely that across the majority of cases, some form of environmental monitoring of the condition of an appropriated resource will be advantageous. This is a general enough condition that it may not depend on the presence or value of more specific variables. The methods most likely to be useful in finding these patterns are descriptive and inferential statistics.
At lower levels of aggregation, cases will be more distinct, and traditional statistical techniques will be less successful at identifying generalities. For example, each SES that employs some form of environmental monitoring will probably conduct it with a unique set of specific rules that it does not share with other SESs. To examine these lower levels, small and medium sample-size methodologies, such as within-case process tracing (George & Bennett Reference George and Bennett2005), cross-case comparisons and qualitative-comparative analysis (Ragin Reference Ragin1987, Reference Ragin2008) may be used.
At these higher levels of specificity, the kinds of theories sought are what George and Bennett (Reference George and Bennett2005) referred to as typological theories. A typological theory is ‘a theory that specifies independent variables, delineates them into the categories for which the researcher will measure the cases and their outcomes, and provides not only hypotheses on how these variables operate individually, but also contingent generalizations on how and under what conditions they behave in specified conjunctions or configurations to produce effects on specified dependent variables’ (George & Bennett Reference George and Bennett2005, p. 235).
Typological theorizing, and the broader approach advocated here, is consonant with the paradigm of adaptive natural resource management, which emphasizes complex interactions revealed in part through case-based work, and a movement away from ‘command-and-control’ approaches that focus exclusively on one or a few target variables (Johnson et al. Reference Johnson, Swanson, Herring and Greene1999). This command-and-control approach, which produces management prescriptions using highly simplified models, is very similar to the panacea problem as we have described it.
In this typological context, independent variables become more like causal conditions, and these conditions form a configuration of values that constitutes a specific case (Ragin Reference Ragin2000). One way of viewing the SES framework is as a means for typologically decomposing resource systems and units, governance systems and actors, based on their properties and the properties of their subcomponents. A typological theory can then be thought of as relating these subtypes in various arrangements to outcomes.
To conclude, new knowledge created through this process can be brought to bear on existing social-ecological problems, of which there are many. This application process faces its own challenges. While there is no panacea for linking knowledge to action, Cash et al. (Reference Cash, Clark, Alcock, Dickson, Eckley, Guston, Jager and Mitchell2003, p. 8089) presented some preliminary findings on how this may be accomplished for the novel field of sustainability science, of which we conceive this work to be a part, most importantly, ‘all else being equal, those systems that made a serious commitment to managing boundaries between expertise and decision making more effectively linked knowledge to action than those that did not.’ In order to overcome the panacea problem, an important amount of work and innovation must occur conceptually, methodologically and practically in order to build a new research programme on the sustainability of complex SESs.
CONCLUSIONS
It will be a challenge to move beyond overly simplistic models of environmental and social processes and the accompanying recommendations for relatively simple blueprint property-rights systems as ‘the’ way to solve environmental problems. To do the social-ecological work that is needed will require knowledge and perspectives from scientific disciplines that are frequently isolated from one another. It will also require a novel integration of methodologies to study social and environmental processes. Enabling scholars from multiple disciplines to share a common framework for diagnosing the sources of diverse environmental problems will take time and effort within a dedicated research programme.
The empirical analyses and frameworks we presented above are good foundation for this work. Considerable further analysis, modification and reformulation are needed, however, before the goal of strong interdisciplinary knowledge of complex SESs is achieved. Understanding the dynamics of differently structured SESs and how diverse interventions may increase or decrease sustainability of these systems over time is a major undertaking. While this will be difficult, we hope that our discussion of the panacea problem has illustrated the importance of doing the hard work to overcome overly simplified responses to serious environmental problems that have unfortunately typified previous work. Hopefully, future work can address these problems, creating and profiting from a dialogue between scientists of different disciplines, as well as between scientists and practitioners, under the auspices of an applied science of sustainability.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
We are appreciative of the support provided by the National Science Foundation and the excellent editing of Patty Lezotte.