1. Introduction
Since 1990, there has been a heated debate over the impact of trade liberalization on the environment. Anti-globalists argue that international trade will lead pollution-intensive industries to relocate to developing countries with less stringent environmental regulations (the pollution haven effect). In addition, opponents of globalization speculate that nations would compete further by lowering environmental standards in a regulatory race to the bottom. Pro-globalists contend that international trade could bring about an improvement in the environment as pollution-intensive industries move to capital-abundant developed countries with stricter environmental regulations (the factor endowment effect). Proponents also argue that trade can improve environmental outcomes by encouraging greater efficiency, diffusing abatement technologies and raising environmental awareness.Footnote 1
Empirical research has found a positive link between trade openness and environmental quality. In early studies, Shafik and Bandyopadhyay (Reference Shafik and Bandyopadhyay1992) and Lucas et al. (Reference Lucas, Wheeler and Hettige1992) show that more open economies experienced lower levels of ambient sulfur dioxide (SO2) and toxic emissions in the 1980s. Antweiler et al. (Reference Antweiler, Copeland and Taylor2001) and Harbaugh et al. (Reference Harbaugh, Levinson and Wilson2002) find that openness reduces SO2 concentrations. Likewise, Cole and Elliott (Reference Cole and Elliott2003), Cole (Reference Cole2004), and Kellenberg (Reference Kellenberg2008) show that trade openness decreases concentrations of other air pollutants (i.e., nitrogen oxides and particulate matter (PM)). In an important paper, Frankel and Rose (Reference Frankel and Rose2005) control for the endogeneity of trade and income and also find that openness reduces air pollution.Footnote 2
The most common measure of trade openness is the trade share: imports and exports as a percentage of GDP.Footnote 3 The trade share, however, is an outcome measure that combines aspects of ‘natural openness’ as determined by geography and factor endowments with trade policy (Berg and Krueger, Reference Berg and Krueger2003; Wei, Reference Wei2000; Wacziarg, Reference Wacziarg2001). As a result, the exact interpretation of the negative coefficient for the trade share is unclear. Is it that more naturally open economies import cleaner production techniques, greener corporate practices and stricter environmental policies? Or is it that more liberal trade policies carry with them cleaner production techniques, greener corporate practices and stricter environmental policies?Footnote 4
There are reasons to believe that natural openness and trade policy could have different quantitative and possibly qualitative impacts on the environment. First, from a theoretical point of view, we argue that the trade costs associated with trade policy are more likely to be ‘iceberg costs’, while the costs associated with natural openness are more likely to be per-unit transportation costs and fixed market-entry costs.Footnote 5 As such, trade policy is predicted to affect the volume of trade, while natural openness is predicted to have an impact on both the volume of trade and the number and variety of exporting firms. Second, from an empirical standpoint, the majority of the trade share and the trade costs that underlie it can be attributed to natural openness. In a review of trade costs, Anderson and van Wincoop (Reference Anderson and van Wincoop2004) report that the bulk of trade costs are non-policy: transportation costs, border-related trade costs and distribution costs. Similarly, Wei (Reference Wei2000) find that population and geography differences explain half of the variation in the trade share, while trade policy measures add very little explanatory power. Third, from a strategic point of view, there is an incentive for governments to substitute environmental policy for trade policy when undergoing trade liberalization (Copeland, Reference Copeland2000; Ederington, Reference Ederington2001). As a result, environmental protection may be less when openness is being driven by trade policy as opposed to natural openness.
In this paper, we examine the relative roles played by natural openness and trade policy in explaining the trade and environment link. We first decompose the trade share into natural openness and trade policy. We create a measure of natural openness by regressing the log trade share on size, geography, language and relative factor endowments and then taking the exponent of the fitted value of the regression. For trade policy, we use four different types: the component of the trade share attributable to observed trade policy (policy-induced openness), the trade policy measures themselves (trade policy indicators), a combination of trade policy indicators (trade policy indices), and deviations of observed prices from some hypothetical free trade level (price deviations).
We then estimate the individual effects of natural openness and trade policy on three air pollutants: nitrogen dioxide (NO2), SO2 and PM. We follow the empirical strategy of Frankel and Rose, which controls for the endogeneity of income and trade. Initially, we find that natural openness reduces all three air pollutants, while policy-induced openness lowers NO2 and SO2 concentrations. However, when we use other trade policy measures and control for domestic environmental regulations, we find that natural openness continues to lower air pollution, while trade policy has a limited effect. Our results therefore suggest that ‘natural’ geographic and endowment differences play a more important role than deliberate trade policy decisions in explaining the trade and environment link.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. We discuss the relationship between openness, trade policy and the environment in section 2. We present our empirical methodology in section 3. We discuss our results in section 4 and conclude in section 5.
2. Openness, trade policy and the environment
2.1. Trade openness and the environment
Trade openness can have both indirect and direct effects on the environment. The most prominent indirect effect of trade openness is through economic growth. Trade can encourage investment flows, technology transfer and greater competition (Wacziarg, Reference Wacziarg2001). The resulting gains in factor accumulation and efficiency will increase the level of per capita income. However, the impact of higher per capita income on environmental outcomes depends upon the magnitudes of the scale, technique and composition effects (Copeland and Taylor, Reference Copeland and Taylor2004). The scale effect states that greater output requires more inputs, and as a consequence, generates more pollution. The technique effect is the adoption of cleaner production methods that results from increased demand for environmental regulations as growth increases. The composition effect is the change in the structure of production resulting from economic growth, which can either raise or lower pollution emissions.
Previous studies by Grossman and Krueger (Reference Grossman, Krueger and Garber1993) and others have found an inverted U-shaped relationship between per capita income and environmental degradation – the so-called environmental Kuznets curve – for many forms of pollution. At low levels of income, the demand for environmental quality is low relative to that of increased consumption. As a result, the scale (and composition) effect dominates the technique effect so that pollution increases with income. At higher levels of income, the demand for environmental quality rises so that greater consumption is willing to be sacrificed. Therefore, the technique effect becomes larger than the scale effect so that pollution decreases with income.
Trade openness can also have direct effects operating through scale, composition and technique effects (Copeland and Taylor, Reference Copeland and Taylor2004). Trade leads to larger production due to comparative advantage and economies of scale. As a result, the larger scale of production generates a higher level of pollution emission. This is the trade-induced scale effect which is positive. The trade-induced composition effect can be either positive or negative, depending upon a country's relative factor endowments and the stringency of its environmental regulations. The factor endowment hypothesis argues that greater openness will lead countries with relatively high capital–labor ratios (the ‘North’) to increase their production of capital-intensive goods, and countries with relatively low capital–labor ratios (the ‘South’) to increase their production of labor-intensive goods. Since capital-intensive goods are more pollution intensive, trade liberalization would lead to greater environmental degradation in the North and less environmental damage in the South. However, the pollution haven hypothesis argues that countries with weak environmental regulations have a comparative advantage in pollution-intensive production. As a result, increased openness will lead dirty industries to locate in countries with weaker environmental regulations and cleaner industries to locate in countries with stronger environmental regulations. Since countries with lower income levels tend to have weaker environmental regulations (Dasgupta et al., Reference Dasgupta, Mody, Roy and Wheeler2001), this hypothesis predicts that the South will specialize in dirty production, while the North will specialize in clean production.
The trade-induced technique effect is predicted to have a positive impact on the environment. Frankel (Reference Frankel2008) identifies three mechanisms for this beneficial link. First, increased competition from international trade can spur managerial and technological innovations beneficial to the environment. Second, multinationals can bring clean state-of-the-art production techniques from high-standard countries of origin (Esty and Gentry, Reference Esty, Gentry and Jones1997). Third, trade can raise public awareness of cleaner practices and policies from abroad. As a result, there could be a ‘race to the top’ for environmental standards.
2.2. Trade openness and trade costs
One can view trade openness as a reduction in trade costs. Trade costs are the cost of getting a good to the final user other than the costs of production. These include the transportation (freight and time) costs, information costs, local distribution (wholesale and retail) costs, legal and regulatory costs, and policy barriers (tariffs and non-tariff barriers).
In the trade literature, trade costs have traditionally been represented as iceberg costs. Iceberg costs are marginal costs that are proportional to the value shipped, with the value added of transportation services treated as pure waste, or ‘melt’ (Samuelson, Reference Samuelson1954). In new trade theory models with increasing returns and love for variety, iceberg costs are used to explain the home market effect where industries tend to concentrate in the markets with the largest number of consumers (Krugman, Reference Krugman1980). Trade liberalization in the form of a lower iceberg cost raises the volume of trade, but has no impact on the overall production of the firm and the number of products produced (Hummels, Reference Hummels1999).
More recently, trade costs are being modeled more broadly to include per-unit transportation costs and fixed market-entry costs (Hummels, Reference Hummels, Hoekman and Porto2010). The inclusion of these non-iceberg trade costs into new trade theory models generates richer dynamics where some firms export (Venables, Reference Venables1994; Medin, Reference Medin2002), higher quality goods are exported abroad (Hummels and Skiba, Reference Hummels and Skiba2004), and firms in developing countries pay higher transportation costs than developed countries (Hummels et al., Reference Hummels, Lugovskyy and Skiba2009). As a result, trade liberalization not only raises the volume of trade, but also increases the number and variety of exporting firms (Hummels, Reference Hummels1999).
On the empirical side, there is mounting evidence that transportation costs are per-unit, trade policy costs are iceberg and export entry costs are fixed. For example, Hummels and Skiba (Reference Hummels and Skiba2004) estimate a trade cost function and find that export prices depend positively upon per unit weight and negatively upon ad valorem tariff rates. Bernard and Jensen (Reference Bernard and Jensen2004) and Eaton et al. (Reference Eaton, Kortum and Kramarz2004) find that fixed export entry costs are a critical determinant in the firm-level decision to export. By applying a structural model, Das et al. (Reference Das, Roberts and Tybout2007) estimate that these export entry costs are quite significant: $300,000–500,000 per firm.
2.3. Natural openness, trade policy and the environment
There are theoretical, empirical and strategic reasons to believe that natural openness and trade policy can have different impacts on the environment. The above discussion on the nature of trade costs provides the basis for our theoretical predictions. Trade policy liberalization is likely to increase the volume of exports and thus reinforce the existing trade patterns. As a result, one would expect trade policy to lead to trade-induced composition effects, whether it is positive or negative. Natural openness, on other hand, is more likely to be realized through reductions in per-unit transportation costs and fixed entry costs. As such, natural openness will increase the number and variety of exporting firms. Therefore, one would expect natural openness to lead to both trade-induced composition effects and trade-induced techniques effects.
From an empirical standpoint, the majority of the trade share and the trade costs that underlie it can be attributed to natural openness. Anderson and van Wincoop (Reference Anderson and van Wincoop2004) report that the bulk of trade costs are non-policy: transportation costs, border-related trade costs and distribution costs. In terms of an ad valorem tax equivalent, transportation costs have been estimated to represent 21 per cent; border-related trade costs are 44 per cent, and 55 per cent are local distributional costs with half of the border-related trade costs attributable to non-policy factors.Footnote 6 Similarly, Wei (Reference Wei2000) and our results in table 1 find that half of the variation in the trade share can be explained by population, geography and language. However, trade policy measures explain less than 10 per cent of the variation in the trade share.
From a strategic point of view, governments can use either trade policy or environmental policy to improve the terms of trade for their domestic industries. If both policies are available, Copeland (Reference Copeland2000) shows that policy makers will use tariffs to protect domestic industries, but impose a domestic tax to internalize production externalities. However, if nations commit themselves to no tariffs, then policy makers will lower the domestic tax to protect the domestic industries and thus worsen the environment. Ederington (Reference Ederington2001) also finds that policy makers will reduce environmental protection if bound to a multilateral trade agreement. As a result, environmental protection will be less when openness is being driven by trade policy as opposed to natural openness.
2.4. Trade policy measures
We consider four different types of trade policy measures: policy-induced openness, trade policy indicators, trade policy indices, and deviations from observed prices.Footnote 7
The policy-induced openness measure is computed by isolating the variation in the trade share attributable to trade policy indicators (Wacziarg, Reference Wacziarg2001). In particular, the trade share is regressed on several geographic, endowment and trade policy measures. The sum of the predicted effects of the policy measures is policy-induced openness.
Trade policy indicators are direct incidence-based measures such as average tariff rates, collected duty revenue, non-tariff barriers, coverage rates and black market premiums. These indicators describe a country's policy position on trade and factor flows with the rest of the world. The main advantage of trade policy indicators is that they are obtained directly from observed data and can describe intermediate policy stances between closed and open economies.
Trade policy indices combine the information of several trade policy indicators into a single index. There are three popular trade indices: Sachs and Warner's Openness, the Heritage Foundation's Trade Freedom, and the Fraser Institute's Freedom to Trade. Each index uses predetermined criteria to weigh the impact of each policy indicator.Footnote 8
The fourth type is deviations of observed prices from some hypothetical free trade level. The most famous example is the Dollar (Reference Dollar1992) index of real exchange rate distortion. Dollar computed a price-deviation index by comparing the observed real exchange rate relative to the purchasing power parity rate purged of the effects of non-tradables.
Pritchett (Reference Pritchett1996), Edwards (Reference Edwards1998) and especially Rodriguez and Rodrik (Reference Rodriguez, Rodrik, Bernanke and Rogoff2001) provide critiques of the trade policy measures. In general, each type suffers from potential measurement errors, omitted variable bias, aggregation problems and extraneous information. Moreover, the degree of bias introduced by each type is unknown. Therefore, rather than relying on one measure of trade policy, we use examples from all four types in our analysis.Footnote 9
3. Empirical methodology
3.1. Data
We use NO2, SO2 and PM concentrations to measure air pollution. The air pollution data are for 1995–2001 and are taken from the World Development Indicators.Footnote 10 NO2 is formed by the oxidation of nitric oxide, which is produced by most combustion processes. SO2 is created from burning coal or oil as a fuel and releasing sulfur. SO2 emissions can be reduced by switching to cleaner coal or using flue gas desulfurization (commonly known as ‘scrubbers’). PM includes dust, dirt, soot, smoke and liquid droplets directly emitted in the air by sources such as cars, construction, diesel trucks, fires, factories, power plants and natural windblown dust.
We disaggregate the trade share into natural openness and trade policy. For natural openness, we regress the trade share on contemporaneous population, geographic variables and lagged relative factor endowments. We then use the predicted value to record natural openness. For trade policy, we use policy-induced openness, trade policy indicators, trade policy indices, and deviations from observed prices to measure trade policy. Policy-induced openness is the predicted value of the trade policy indicators in the trade share regression. The trade policy indicators are the ratio of import duties to import value, ratio of export duties to export value, and the log of the black market premium. The trade policy indices are the Sachs–Warner Openness, Heritage Trade Freedom and Fraser Freedom to Exchange. Each trade policy index is normalized to a 0 to 1 scale, where 0 corresponds to ‘closed’ and 1 to ‘open’. The deviation from observed prices is the Dollar index of real exchange rate deviation. The Dollar index is also normalized to a 0 to 1 scale. Natural openness and the trade policy measures are averaged over 1985–1995 to smooth out temporary fluctuations and maximize country coverage.
The real GDP per capita, real GDP per capita squared, polity and surface area per person values used in the final estimation are measured in 1995. We use average values of factor accumulation, lagged natural openness and lagged trade policy to instrument for real GDP per capita, natural openness and trade policy, respectively. Appendix A provides the details of the data sources and dates.
The air pollution, trade share and real GDP data are shown in appendix B. There are 45 potential countries in our sample: 24 developed and 21 developing nations. As a result, there is a good deal of cross-sectional variation in our air pollution, trade and development data. However, our cross-sectional data set is unable to exploit any potential time variation in the data which could be used to control for unobserved differences across nations.
3.2. Empirical design
The first step is to create our estimate of natural openness: the component of the trade share attributable to population, geography and relative factor endowments. We regress the trade share on size, geography, language and relative factor endowments:
![\eqalign{\ln\lpar trade/GDP\rpar _i &=\alpha _0+\alpha _1 ln\lpar pop\rpar _i+\alpha _2 ln\lpar area\rpar _i+\alpha _3 ln\lpar remoteness\rpar _i \cr & \quad+\alpha _4 \lpar geography\rpar _i+\alpha _5 \lpar language\rpar _i \cr & \quad+\alpha _6 \lpar relativefactors\rpar _i+e_i} \eqno\lpar 1\rpar](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20160920233735430-0228:S1355770X11000271:S1355770X11000271_eqn1.gif?pub-status=live)
The variables pop and area are total population and surface area and control for country size. The variable remoteness is the weighted sum of each country's distance to all other countries in the world. We weigh each distance with initial real GDP of the other country to control for market size. The three geography variables are dummies for landlocked and island and the ratio of a country's sea coast length to its land area. There are three language dummy variables for English, French and Spanish speaking nations. The three relative factor endowments are capital per worker, schooling per worker and surface area per capita.Footnote 11 We also include an oil dummy to control for the role of extractive industries. Natural openness is measured as the exponent of the fitted value of (1).
The second step is to compute policy-induced openness. We add trade policy indicators and indices to our trade share regression:
![\eqalign{\ln\lpar trade/GDP\rpar _i &=\alpha _0+\alpha _1 \ln\lpar pop\rpar _i+\alpha _2 \ln\lpar area\rpar _i+\alpha _3 \ln\lpar remoteness\rpar _i \cr & \quad+\alpha _4 \lpar geography\rpar _i+\alpha _5 \lpar language\rpar _i+\alpha _6 \lpar relativefactors\rpar _i \cr & \quad+\alpha _7 \lpar tradepolicies\rpar _i+e_i} \eqno\lpar 2\rpar](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20160920233735430-0228:S1355770X11000271:S1355770X11000271_eqn2.gif?pub-status=live)
The exponent of the estimated effect of policy – – is our measure of policy-induced openness. We have three trade policy indicators and three indices at our disposal. We therefore use the predicted values of those combinations that produce the ‘best fit’ in terms of predicted signs and highest adjusted R-squared.
The third step is to estimate the individual effects of natural openness and trade-policy openness on air pollution. We adopt the specification of Frankel and Rose (Reference Frankel and Rose2005):
![\eqalign{Pollution_i &=\varphi _0+\varphi _1 ln\lpar Y/pop\rpar _i+\varphi _2 \lsqb ln\lpar Y/pop\rpar _i \rsqb ^2+\varphi _3 \lpar Polity\rpar _i \cr & \quad+\varphi _4 ln\lpar area/pop\rpar _i+\beta _1 \lpar naturalopenness\rpar _i \cr & \quad+\beta _2 \lpar tradepolicyopenness\rpar _i+e_i }\eqno\lpar 3\rpar](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary:20160920233735430-0228:S1355770X11000271:S1355770X11000271_eqn3.gif?pub-status=live)
where Y/pop is real GDP per capita, Polity is a measure of democracy (−10 for ‘strongly autocratic’ to +10 for ‘strongly democratic’), and area/pop is surface area per person. The EKC hypothesis predicts an inverted U-shaped relationship between real GDP per capita and pollution (φ1 > 0 and φ2 < 0). Barrett and Graddy (Reference Barrett and Graddy2000) and Frankel and Rose (Reference Frankel and Rose2005) find that greater democracy improves the environment (φ3 < 0), while Frankel and Rose (Reference Frankel and Rose2005) show that greater congestion (more people per square mile) harms the environment (φ4 < 0).
3.3. Two-stage least squares
There is potential endogeneity of real GDP per capita (and squared), natural openness and trade policy in (3). For real GDP, environmental degradation can reduce production possibilities and thus cause lower growth rates, especially in the developing world (Arrow et al., Reference Arrow, Bolin, Costanza, Dasgupta, Folke, Holling, Jansson, Levin, Mäler, Perrings and Pimentel1995). For natural openness, the inclusion of contemporaneous population in (1) creates a feedback from environmental degradation to natural openness through the impact of air pollution on mortality rates. For trade policy, the feedback potential operates through environmental policy. Kennedy (Reference Kennedy1994) and Barrett (Reference Barrett1994) find that trade liberalization can reduce (or even raise) environmental regulation. Porter (Reference Porter1991) argues that environmental regulation can stimulate productivity and thus impact economic growth. By impacting environmental policy and productivity, trade policy can have a simultaneous impact on air pollution (dependent variable) and income (independent variable).
We therefore estimate equation (3) using two-stage least squares (2SLS). In the first stage, we estimate natural openness, trade policy, real GDP per capita and real GDP per capita squared as functions of lagged natural openness, lagged trade policy, fitted trade openness, fitted real GDP per capita, fitted real GDP per capita squared, and the exogenous variables. The fitted trade share variable is the aggregated predicted values of a geographic-based gravity model (Frankel and Romer, Reference Frankel and Romer1999). The fitted real GDP per capita terms are constructed from regressing real GDP per person on initial real GDP per capita, population, the trade share, investment, population growth, and primary and secondary enrollment (Frankel and Rose, Reference Frankel and Rose2005).
An instrumental variable must satisfy two requirements: it must be orthogonal to the error term (validity) and it must be correlated with the included endogenous variable (relevance). We use the Hansen J-statistic to test for the orthogonality of the instruments when there are more excluded instruments than endogenous variables (over-identification). Relevance is examined through the first-stage F-statistics and the Shea (Reference Shea1997) partial R-squares of the excluded instruments. However, the recent literature on weak instruments (c.f. Stock et al., Reference Stock, Wright and Yogo2002) has shown that mere instrument relevance is insufficient. In particular, there is a possibility that each endogenous variable can be nearly explained by the same combination of instruments (i.e., ‘weak’).
With more than one endogenous variable, we use the Stock and Yogo (Reference Stock, Yogo, Stock and Andrews2005) weak instrument test to determine the strength of our instruments. The Stock and Yogo weak instrument test compares the Cragg–Donald statistic to critical values based upon the worst possible case of weak instruments.Footnote 12 If the instruments are weak, then the Cragg–Donald statistic takes a low value, the 2SLS estimates are biased, and the standard errors are underestimated (i.e., the null rejection rate based on t-tests at the nominal 5 per cent level could in fact be 10 per cent or more). However, if the instruments are strong, then the Cragg–Donald statistic exceeds the critical value and we can reject the fact that the 2SLS estimates have the potential to be biased of more than 10 per cent with a risk of rejecting the null wrongly of 5 per cent.
4. Empirical results
Table 1 reports the results for the trade share regressions. In column 1, we include the geographic and language variables. These variables explain 54 per cent of the variation in the trade share. As expected, the coefficients for economic size are negative. As with Wei (Reference Wei2000), we also find that economies more distant from world markets have lower trade shares, while countries with longer coast lines (relative to surface area) have larger trade shares. The language variables are generally insignificant. In column 2, we add relative factor endowments. A positive coefficient implies that countries with different factor endowments trade more à la Heckscher–Ohlin, while a negative coefficient implies that countries with similar factor endowments trade more à la new trade theory. We find that countries with similar capital and skill endowments tend to trade more which suggests that these countries conduct more intra-industry trade. We measure natural openness as the exponent of the predicted value from column 2.
Table 1. Explaining the trade share
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-80800-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab1.jpg?pub-status=live)
Notes: The dependent variable is the log of imports plus exports as a share of GDP. Robust t-statistics are in parentheses where ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5, and 10% level of confidence, respectively.
We next add trade policy indicators and indices to our trade share regression. In column 3, we include the ratios of import duties to imports and export duties to exports to quantify import and export tax rates. As expected, the coefficient for each trade tax is negative, indicating that countries with more restrictive trade policies have a lower trade share. We then add the black market premium to control for foreign exchange restrictions in column 4.Footnote 13 The coefficient for the black market premium also has its expected negative sign and is significant.
In the remaining columns, we include the different trade policy indices. These indices are combinations of tariff rates, non-tariff barriers, export monopolies, black market premium and capital controls. The coefficient for each trade policy index is positive, but only the coefficient for the Fraser Institute's Freedom to Exchange is economically and statistically significant. Lastly, in column 8, we add back the trade policy indicators to see if we can increase the predictive power. Although the trade policy indicators are insignificant, there is a slight increase in the adjusted R-squared so we use the sum of the predicted values for the trade policy variables in column 8 to construct our measure of policy-induced openness.Footnote 14
Tables 2a and 2b report the summary statistics and correlation coefficients for our trade openness measures. The trade share is highly correlated with natural openness, but weakly correlated with each trade policy. This is not surprising given the strong predictive power of population and geography in table 1. There is also very little correlation between natural openness and each trade policy indicator. Within trade policy, there is a high correlation between policy-induced openness and the Fraser Freedom to Exchange index.
Table 2a. Summary statistics of trade openness measures
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-73312-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab2.jpg?pub-status=live)
Table 2b. Correlation matrix of trade openness measures
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-37968-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab3.jpg?pub-status=live)
As a baseline, we estimate the impact of natural openness along with real GDP per capita, polity and area per person on air pollution. Table 3 presents the results where the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates are shown on the left and the 2SLS estimates are displayed on the right.Footnote 15 We cannot test for over-identification (instrument validity) since the number of instruments equals the number of endogenous variables. In the first stage, the F-statistics are high (with two exceptions) and the Shea partial R-squared are far above zero. These test results suggest relevant instruments. In the weak instrument test, the Cragg–Donald statistic exceeds the critical value, which means that we reject the null of hypothesis that the relative bias of the 2SLS coefficient is more than 10 per cent of the OLS bias (with a risk of 5 per cent).
Table 3. Natural openness and air pollution
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-97909-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab4.jpg?pub-status=live)
Notes: The dependent variable is listed on the top. Each equation is estimated using OLS and 2SLS. Robust t-statistics are in parentheses. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5, and 10% level of confidence, respectively.
For 2SLS, the trade share, real GDP per capita and real GDP per capita squared are instrumented with fitted trade share, predicted real GDP per capita and predicted real GDP per capita squared. The Hansen J-test is the p-value of a test of exogeneity of the instruments. For the weak instrument test, a Cragg–Donald statistic in excess of the critical value indicates that a standard significance with nominal size of 5% has a maximal size of 10%.
The signs and significance levels of the coefficient for natural openness support the hypothesis that a higher trade share stemming from geographical differences reduces air pollution. The coefficient for natural openness is negative and statistically significant at the 5 per cent level for all three air pollutants. Using sample means, the point estimates imply that the natural openness elasticity is −0.55 for NO2, −0.56 for SO2 and −0.12 for PM. Of particular interest, our natural openness elasticities are of similar magnitude to estimates of the trade intensity elasticity using trade intensity, GDP, income per capita, capital labor ratio and their interaction terms à la Antweiler et al. (Reference Antweiler, Copeland and Taylor2001).Footnote 16 In addition, the signs and significance levels for the remaining variables are as generally predicted: greater democracy decreases all three air pollutants, there is an estimated EKC for NO2 and SO2, and greater congestion in the form of a higher area per capita increases PM concentrations.
The remainder of the paper estimates the individual impacts of natural openness and trade policy. Table 4 begins by including policy-induced openness. The Hansen J-test fails to reject the null of exogeneity, indicating instrument validity. As before, the highly significant first-stage F-statistics and high Shea partial R-squared indicate that the instruments are correlated with the endogenous variables. In addition, the Cragg–Donald statistics are above the critical value and thus the instruments are strong.
Table 4. Natural openness, policy-induced openness and air pollution
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-21586-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab5.jpg?pub-status=live)
Notes: The dependent variable is listed on the top. Each equation is estimated using OLS and 2SLS. Robust t-statistics are in parentheses. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5, and 10% level of confidence, respectively.
For 2SLS, natural openness, real GDP per capita and real GDP per capita squared are instrumented with lagged natural openness, fitted trade share, predicted real GDP per capita and predicted real GDP per capita squared. The Hansen J-test is the p-value of a test of exogeneity of the instruments. For the weak instrument test, a Cragg–Donald statistic in excess of the critical value indicates that a standard significance with nominal size of 5% has a maximal size of 10%.
The results show that natural openness reduces all three pollutants, while policy-induced openness decreases NO2 and SO2. The coefficients for natural openness imply a natural openness elasticity of −0.50 for NO2 and SO2 and −0.11 for PM. Similarly, the coefficients for policy-induced openness imply a trade policy elasticity of −0.35 for NO2 and −0.91 for SO2, but an insignificant trade policy elasticity for PM.
Table 5 uses trade policy indicators to measure trade policy. Once again, natural openness reduces all three air pollutants with elasticities of −0.50 and −0.11. The impact of trade policy, however, is uneven. On the one hand, higher import duty rates raise SO2 and PM emissions, while a higher black market premium increases SO2 concentrations. On the other hand, higher export duty rates reduce SO2 and PM emission, while a higher black market premium lowers PM concentrations.
Table 5. Natural openness, trade policy indicators and air pollution
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-30882-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab6.jpg?pub-status=live)
Notes: The dependent variable is listed on the top. Each equation is estimated using 2SLS. Robust t-statistics are in parentheses. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5, and 10% level of confidence, respectively. Natural openness, import duty share, export duty share, black market premium, real GDP per capita and real GDP per capita squared are instrumented with lagged natural openness, lagged import duty share, lagged export duty share, lagged black market premium, fitted trade share, predicted real GDP per capita and predicted real GDP per capita squared. The Hansen J-test is the p-value of a test of exogeneity of the instruments.
Tables 6a and 6b include the three trade policy indices (Sachs–Warner, Heritage and Fraser) and the price deviation measure (Dollar RER deviation) one at a time. Regardless of which trade policy measure is used, natural openness is found to reduce concentrations of all three air pollutions. With regards to trade policy, trade liberalization in the Sachs–Warner and Fraser indices lower SO2 levels, while trade liberalization in the Fraser index lowers NO2 concentrations. Neither the Heritage Trade Freedom index nor the Dollar RER index had a significant impact on any pollutant. Although some of the mixed results can be partially attributed to measurement error in the trade policy variables, the overall message in tables 5 and 6 is that trade policy has very little impact on air pollution.
Table 6a. Natural openness, trade policy indices and air pollution
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-52654-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab7.jpg?pub-status=live)
Table 6b. Natural openness, trade policy indices and air pollution
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-49390-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab8.jpg?pub-status=live)
Notes: The dependent variable is listed on the top. Each equation is estimated using 2SLS. Robust t-statistics are in parentheses. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5, and 10% level of confidence, respectively. Natural openness, trade policy, real GDP per capita and real GDP per capita squared are instrumented with lagged natural openness, lagged trade policy, fitted trade share, predicted real GDP per capita and predicted real GDP per capita squared. The Hansen J-test is the p-value of a test of exogeneity of the instruments.
Domestic environmental policies play a critical role in determining environmental outcomes and also in linking trade to the environment. Therefore, some of the estimated impact of natural trade and/or the lack of impact of trade policy could be a byproduct of domestic environmental policy. To test for this possibility, we add a measure of domestic environmental policy or pollution abatement policy. The environmental policy measures are Domestic Environmental Stringency index (CIESIN and YCELP, 2010) and Environmental tax (OECD, 2008). The pollution abatement policies are Pollution abatement and control expenditures (OECD, 2008) and restrictions on coal-fired power plants (Lovely and Popp, Reference Lovely and Popp2011). Note that the Environmental tax and Pollution abatement and control expenditures data are available only for OECD countries and thus reduce our sample size. These environmental policy measures have been used before and are described in appendix A.
Tables 7a and 7b show the results for natural openness, trade policy and environmental policy. In controlling for differences in environmental policy in general and pollution abatement policies in particular, natural openness continues to lead to decreases in all three air pollutants. The coefficient for natural openness is negative in each regression and significant at 10 per cent in most instances. Moreover, the fall in significance of natural openness with Environmental tax and Pollution abatement and control expenditures can be at least partially attributed to the reduction in the sample size.
Table 7a. Natural openness, trade policy, environmental policy, and air pollution
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-21926-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab9.jpg?pub-status=live)
Table 7b. Natural openness, trade policy, pollution abatement policy, and air pollution
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-33056-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tab10.jpg?pub-status=live)
Notes: The dependent variable is listed on the top. Each equation is estimated using 2SLS. Robust t-statistics are in parentheses. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1, 5, and 10% level of confidence, respectively. Natural openness, trade policy, real GDP per capita and real GDP per capita squared are instrumented with lagged natural openness, lagged trade policy, fitted trade share, predicted real GDP per capita and predicted real GDP per capita squared. The Hansen J-test is the p-value of a test of exogeneity of the instruments.
5. Conclusions
In this paper, we examined the individual effects of natural openness and trade policy on air pollution. We posited that natural openness is more likely to have beneficial effects than trade policy due to differences in theoretical trade costs, empirical importance and strategic link to environmental policy. We then found that natural openness reduces air pollution, while trade-policy openness has a limited impact on the environment.
There are two important limitations of our study. First, our small sample size reduces the power of our statistical tests and raises the possibly of influential outliers. Second, the use of our reduced-form equation (3) prevents us from acquiring individual estimates of trade-induced scale, composition and technique effects.
Nevertheless, our results indicate that ‘natural’ geographic and endowment differences play a more important role than deliberate trade policy decisions in explaining the trade and environment link. With regards to trade costs, our results suggest that reductions in transportation, distribution and export entry costs and not trade policy itself are behind the environmental benefits of trade openness. We do not interpret this to mean that the liberalization of trade policy has no impact or should be abandoned. However, our results do suggest that some of the virtuous benefits of trade on the environment have already been realized by countries exploiting their natural geographic advantages in trade.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-78152-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tabU1.jpg?pub-status=live)
Notes: WDI, World Development Indicators; PWI, Penn World Tables 6.2.
![](https://static.cambridge.org/binary/version/id/urn:cambridge.org:id:binary-alt:20160921141546-31145-mediumThumb-S1355770X11000271_tabU2.jpg?pub-status=live)