Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T02:59:33.844Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Comments on Arrow et al., ‘Sustainability and the measurement of wealth’

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 May 2012

Kirk Hamilton
Affiliation:
Development Research Group, The World Bank, 1818 H St. NW, Washington DC 20433, USA. Tel: 1-202-473-2053. Email: khamilton@worldbank.org
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Extract

The Arrow et al. paper is a welcome addition to a large literature on the linkage between asset values and social welfare. This literature has its roots in the concern about ‘greening’ the national accounts, but the paper shows how expanding the asset boundary beyond produced and natural goods could increase our measures of income, saving and wealth enormously. I will comment in turn on the wealth accounts, investment accounts and the treatment of CO2 emissions, using selected World Bank figures as a basis for comparison.

Type
Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

The Arrow et al. paper is a welcome addition to a large literature on the linkage between asset values and social welfare. This literature has its roots in the concern about ‘greening’ the national accounts, but the paper shows how expanding the asset boundary beyond produced and natural goods could increase our measures of income, saving and wealth enormously. I will comment in turn on the wealth accounts, investment accounts and the treatment of CO2 emissions, using selected World Bank figures as a basis for comparison.

Comprehensive wealth

Table 1 lays out the year 2000 wealth accounts for the United States, using figures from the paper and figures from The Changing Wealth of Nations (World Bank, 2011), expressed in year 2000 US$ and augmented by recent OECD figures on the value of human capital (Liu, Reference Liu2011).

Table 1. US wealth in 2000, US$ per capita

Source: Arrow et al. (Reference Arrow, Dasgupta, Goulder, Mumford and Oleson2012, table 5); World Bank (2011). Human capital figures for 2005 from Liu (Reference Liu2011) are back-cast to year 2000 using data on per capita income.

Implicit in the theorems linking savings and investment to changes in social welfare is an assumption that the accounting is complete – if assets are missing from the accounts, then the change in social welfare and sustainability of an economy may be over- or understated. Expanding the accounting of assets, as Arrow et al. do, is therefore inherently important. Looking at the table, most countries which produce asset accounts would be measuring total wealth as US$56–81 thousand per capita; for the handful of countries which include natural assets in the balance sheet, this measure expands to US$76–94 thousand per capita. This falls far short of comprehensive accounting as the other figures in the table reveal.

The discrepancies between Arrow et al. and World Bank (2011) for produced and natural capital are presumably linked to different data sources, and different assumptions about depreciation, lifetimes and discount rates. More interesting is the discrepancy in the value of human capital. Liu (Reference Liu2011) uses the Jorgenson–Fraumeni (Reference Jorgenson, Fraumeni, Lipsey and Tice1989) framework, which relies on projected figures on earnings by educational cohort, while Arrow et al. use the Mincer formula and average wages. Since the Jorgenson–Fraumeni methodology employs a much richer set of data to calculate the present value of labor income, it produces what is arguably the more accurate estimate of human capital. This suggests that the Mincer formulation should not be used blindly to value human capital, but further digging into the details of the calculations would be required to confirm this conclusion.

The big discrepancy between the two wealth accounts in table 1 is obviously the value of health in Arrow et al. Their calculation starts from the US value of a statistical life (VSL) of US$6.3 million, then converts this to a mean value of a life-year and multiplies by the discounted expected years of life to arrive at the total health capital.

While World Bank (2011) values damages from exposure to particulate matter pollution using VSL in its calculation of Adjusted Net Saving, the asset accounts stay closer to the System of National Accounts (SNA) boundary. In particular, as reported in table 1, by assuming constant returns to scale, a reasonably comprehensive measure of total wealth can be derived as the present value of future public and private consumption as measured in the SNA.Footnote 1 When the value of other assets, including human capital as calculated in Liu (Reference Liu2011), is subtracted from total wealth, the ‘intangible residual’ shown in table 1 is the asset equivalent of total factor productivity (TFP) – it implicitly values social capital, institutional quality and other unmeasured assets which support production in the economy.

Returning to the value of health capital in Arrow et al., the interpretation of the VSL merits careful consideration. Both Arrow et al. and Nordhaus (Reference Nordhaus2002) assume that it can serve as the value of health or healthfulness, but it arguably includes everything that people value in life – consumption of goods, leisure, enjoyment of environmental amenities, relationships with friends and family, and so on, in addition to good health. VSL is, after all, calculated as the willingness to pay to reduce the risk of death. VSL would seem to have much in common with V(t), the value of intergenerational wellbeing defined in expression (1) of Arrow et al. V(t) measures the discounted future flow of a very broad measure of utility.

If VSL is really dollar-valued V(t), then it is natural to think of it as the broadest measure of the per capita wealth of a nation, since it measures the present value of future generalized consumption.Footnote 2 An alternative accounting using the figures in Arrow et al. could therefore be as shown in table 1a. Here the intangible residual is the set of all assets beyond human, natural and produced capital which yield production services and services which make life worth living – and worth paying to preserve.

Table 1a is obviously rather speculative, but it makes the point that there is merit in thinking hard about what VSL is actually measuring.

Table 1a. Alternative US wealth in 2000, US$ per capita

Source: Author's calculations.

Investment

Health capital

Arrow et al. value investment in health capital as the mean value of a life-year (based on the VSL) times the discounted increase in life expectancy. This is clearly an outcome rather than an investment per se and it is worth considering what investments actually produce this outcome.

One point is clear, that the investments affecting life expectancy are typically in the past and diverse in nature. Childhood vaccination, prenatal care for mothers, higher income, improved knowledge about nutrition, declines in smoking, decreasing shares of dangerous jobs in the economy, enforcement of health and safety regulations in the workplace, reductions in environmental pollution, testing and control of toxic chemicals, and a wide range of other changes in the economy over preceding decades all contribute to increasing life expectancy. It seems challenging to define and measure the specific investments which produce better health outcomes far into the future.

Capital gains on natural resources

Arrow et al. note the theoretical contributions of Asheim (Reference Asheim1997) and Sefton and Weale (Reference Sefton and Weale1996) on this topic, and it is worth noting the work on theory and measurement of both Vincent et al. (Reference Vincent, Panayotou and Hartwick1997) and Hamilton and Bolt (Reference Hamilton and Bolt2004). While the latter two papers focus on exporters of natural resources, Arrow et al. correctly note that the same logic of adjusting saving to reflect exogenous price trends also applies to imports.

Arrow et al. firmly reject the assumption of an optimal economy at the outset of the paper, so it is surprising to find it appearing in the calculation of capital gains, where resource prices are assumed to rise at the rate of interest. Livernois (Reference Livernois2009) reviews a broad literature and finds virtually no empirical evidence for the Hotelling rule or, indeed, statistically significant rises in resource prices. Plausible explanations for this include the role of resource discoveries and technological change. While Livernois (Reference Livernois2009: 27) notes the strong rise in resource prices from 2001 to 2008, he also notes that these rates of growth were much too high to be consistent with the Hotelling rule and concludes that ‘… this, combined with the observation that commodity prices are highly volatile, suggests that it would be unwise to expect that prices will continue to rise unabated’.

Accounting for CO2 emissions

Arrow et al. present the theory and measurement of carbon dioxide emissions in their accounts, but there is no explicit discussion of property rights in their presentation. Of particular interest is the case where countries have the right not to be polluted by their neighbors.

Suppose there are N countries and that the damages that CO2 emissions from country k inflict upon country j in a specific year are given by d kj. The total emissions of CO2 by country k in the given year are e k, while the social cost of carbon is s. Now we can define the damages inflicted and the damages suffered by country k.

The total damage inflicted by country k is D k,

(1)
D_k = s \cdot e_k = \sum_{j = 1}^{N} d_{kj}\comma \; \eqno \lpar 1\rpar

while the total damage suffered by country k is M k,

(2)
M_k = \sum_{i = 1}^{N} d_{ik}.\eqno \lpar 2\rpar

If we assume the property right that each country has the right not to be polluted by its neighbors, and that compensation is therefore paid for damage inflicted, the deduction from the national savings of country k to account for global CO2 emissions is given by

(3)
-M_{k} - \lpar D_{k} - d_{kk}\rpar + \lpar M_{k} - d_{kk}\rpar = -D_{k}.\eqno \lpar 3\rpar

In the left-hand side of this expression the first term is the total damage that country k suffers from CO2 emissions, including its own; the second term is the payment country k makes to all other countries for damage inflicted; and the third term is the payment that country k receives from all other countries for the damage they have inflicted on it. The net result is that the deduction from the saving of country k just equals the total social cost of its emissions (expression (1)) – this is the valuation applied in Hamilton and Clemens (Reference Hamilton and Clemens1999)Footnote 3 and World Bank (2011).

Clearly, if no property rights apply to transboundary pollution, then the deduction from the saving of country k is just the total damage it suffers, M k. This is the value calculated by Arrow et al.

These options for the treatment of CO2 emissions (or, more generally, any transboundary pollutants) are analogous to the difference between GDP and GNP. In one case you measure all the value added within a country; in the second case you account for the flows of factor payments according to whether they accrue to domestic or foreign owners.

One could argue that assuming the property right behind expression (3) is unrealistic. But it is precisely this property right which is the basis for the entire body of international environmental law. It is enshrined in the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), which states that ‘States have, in accordance with the Charter of the United Nations and the principles of international law, the sovereign right to exploit their own resources pursuant to their own environmental and developmental policies, and the responsibility to ensure that activities within their jurisdiction or control do not cause damage to the environment of other States or of areas beyond the limits of national jurisdiction …’. All countries are signatories to the UNFCCC, with only Andorra and the Holy See opting for observer status.

Conclusions

In the introduction to this commentary I described Arrow et al. as a welcome addition to the literature on asset accounting and social welfare. Their attempt to be as comprehensive as possible in their accounting is important, as is the rigor with which they approach the problem. My comments on the paper serve to highlight some of the rich avenues for further research which the paper has opened.

Footnotes

1 Arrow et al. suggest that World Bank (2011) assumes a positive constant growth rate of future consumption in calculating total wealth, which is incorrect. It suffices to assume that the growth rate is constant, whether positive, negative or zero.

2 The main difference between VSL and V(t) is that VSL is only measuring the value of life to the current generation. But if mean expected years of life is 35 years and the pure rate of time preference is 1.5 per cent, then generations beyond the current one only have a 3 per cent weight in V(t).

3 Hamilton and Clemens (Reference Hamilton and Clemens1999) use the social cost of carbon from Fankhauser (Reference Fankhauser1994).

References

Arrow, K.J., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L.H., Mumford, K.J., and Oleson, K. (2012), ‘Sustainability and the measurement of wealth’, Environment and Development Economics 17(3).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asheim, G. (1997), ‘Adjusting green NNP to measure sustainability’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 99: 355370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fankhauser, S. (1994), ‘Evaluating the social costs of greenhouse gas emissions’, Energy Journal 15(2): 157184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, K. and Bolt, K. (2004), ‘Resource price trends and development prospects’, Portuguese Economic Journal 3: 8597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, K. and Clemens, M. (1999), ‘Genuine saving in developing countries’, World Bank Economic Review 13(2): 333356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jorgenson, D.W. and Fraumeni, B.M. (1989), ‘The accumulation of human and non-human capital, 1948–1984’, in Lipsey, R.E. and Tice, H.S. (eds), The Measurement of Savings, Investment, and Wealth, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Liu, G. (2011), ‘Measuring the stock of human capital for comparative analysis: an application of the lifetime income approach to selected countries’, OECD Statistics Working Paper No. 2011/06, OECD Publishing.Google Scholar
Livernois, J. (2009), ‘On the empirical significance of the Hotelling rule’, Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 3(1): 2241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nordhaus, W.D. (2002), ‘The health of nations: the contribution of improved health to living standards’, NBER Working Paper No. 8818, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sefton, J. and Weale, M.R. (1996), ‘The net national product and exhaustible resources’, Journal of Public Economics 61: 2147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vincent, J., Panayotou, T., and Hartwick, J. (1997), ‘Resource depletion and sustainability in small open economies’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 33: 274286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank (2011), The Changing Wealth of Nations: Measuring Sustainable Development in the New Millennium, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. US wealth in 2000, US$ per capita

Figure 1

Table 1a. Alternative US wealth in 2000, US$ per capita