Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-g4j75 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T06:55:29.420Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Large Industrial Firms and the Rise of Finance in Late Twentieth-Century America

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 September 2018

YOUN KI*
Affiliation:
Youn Ki received her PhD from the University of Chicago. She is an assistant professor of political science at Miami University, Ohio. Contact information: 328 Harrison Hall, Oxford, OH 45056. E-mail: kiy@miamioh.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This article examines the financialization of the U.S. economy in the late twentieth century, with a focus on the role of industrial firms in the transition. This article explores how American industrial leaders’ reactions to the economic shocks of the 1970s influenced the rise of finance in the United States. Specifically, this article analyzes how the restrictive postwar financial regime gave way to a new liberal one, often represented by two vital shifts in the 1970s: the resurgence of global finance and the turn to austerity. It also demonstrates how leading industrialists’ preferences toward particular financial policies gave rise to different coalitions that affected policy orientation. It contributes to the financialization literature by clarifying the distinctive role of industrialists in American financialization. Furthermore, by situating financialization in the broader socioeconomic context, this article highlights the intersections of two important changes in the history of U.S. capitalism: financialization and the disintegration of the New Deal regime.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author 2018. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Business History Conference. All rights reserved. 

The exponential growth of financial markets over the past several decades has generated broad scholarly and public interest in the phenomenon called “financialization.” In this article, financialization refers to “the increasing importance of financial actors, activities, and motives in the economy as opposed to industrial counterparts.” Throughout the article, I make distinctions between finance and financiers and industry and industrialists. The former denotes the profit-making activities and actors through the management of financial assets; the latter denotes the profit-making activities and actors involving the production or trade of commodities.Footnote 1 Despite a growing interest in financialization, analysts have yet to examine the role industrial firms played in the process. This article explores financialization in the wider context of industrial and socioeconomic shifts in the United States.

Specifically, this article examines how the restrictive postwar financial regime yielded to a new liberal one in late twentieth-century America. After World War II, the U.S. government was committed to providing a favorable economic environment for stable industrial growth. To this end, it not only endorsed regulations on international capital flows but also implemented substantial monetary interventions domestically, embracing a Keynesian approach. However, things changed drastically in the 1970s. The U.S. government began to advocate free movement of cross-border capital and denounced capital controls. It also shifted its monetary policy directions, adopting extreme austerity measures in the late 1970s, known as the “Volcker Shock.” These two shifts—the rise of international finance and U.S. monetary policy change—hastened the financialization of the U.S. economy by producing economic conditions conducive to financial expansion. Why did such policy changes happen in the 1970s?

This article focuses on leading American industrialists, demonstrating how their reactions to the economic turbulence of the 1970s facilitated financial regime changes. In the early postwar years, industrialists aligned with labor, offering support for restrictive financial policies to promote stable economic expansion. Conversely, financiers opposed the government’s heavy hand for fear of reduced business opportunities in the international markets and domestic inflationary pressures. However, industrialists changed their positions in the late 1960s and 1970s as they adopted new business strategies; namely, internationalization and flexible labor relations. Faced with declining profitability, large industrial corporations first accelerated foreign direct investment (FDI) in the late 1960s. As cross-border capital regulations impeded FDI, industrialists joined financiers in the fight for international capital mobility, adding pressure on the government to remove capital controls. In the early 1970s, the U.S. government abolished its capital controls and weakened international consensus on controls. Despite the successful efforts to promote overseas investment, U.S. firms continued to struggle in the 1970s, mainly due to powerful foreign competitors and increased economic volatility. The firms started to rethink the postwar capital–labor pact, concluding that the rigid industrial relations based on long-term, massive investment plans became a liability under the new environment of high competition and volatility. Finally, as American industrial leaders increased FDI and abandoned the capital–labor compromise in the 1970s, they withdrew their support of the Keynesian policies, advocating a classical austerity model by the late 1970s. Skyrocketing inflation threatened the dollar’s international reserve currency status, from which U.S.-based multinational corporations derived substantial competitive advantage. The firms hoped that austerity measures would save the dollar amid the currency crisis and undermine organized labor. Over the late 1970s and into the early 1980s, the entire U.S. business community—both industrialists and financiers—became strong backers of the Federal Reserve’s extreme contractionary policies.

The rise of global finance and domestic economic austerity catalyzed American financialization by directly benefiting U.S. financiers and creating propitious conditions for financial expansion in the economy. First, the liberalization of international finance augmented the centrality of Wall Street in the global markets, enriching and empowering American bankers. Also, austerity boosted financial profits by halting inflation. Second, given the increased mobility and volume of international finance, the austerity measures attracted a large amount of foreign capital into U.S. financial markets. The influx of capital was a great boon to the U.S. financial sector; it also made the U.S. economy prone to asset price bubbles.Footnote 2

This research complements existing studies by clarifying the distinctive role of industrial leaders in U.S. financialization and by offering detailed historical evidence. Ultimately, this study highlights the historical intersections of financialization and the disintegration of the New Deal regime in the United States. Recent studies of U.S. neoliberal revolution have emphasized the central role U.S. business played in the process. Kim Phillips-Fein documents how some business leaders who were outraged by Roosevelt’s New Deal struggled to fight back over several decades, culminating in Reagan’s victory.Footnote 3 Benjamin Waterhouse focuses on successful business mobilization of the 1970s, which catalyzed and shaped the “right turn” of the country.Footnote 4 Both studies effectively show how the perceived and real threats to business prerogatives during the 1930s and 1940s (Phillips-Fein) and the late 1960s and 1970s (Waterhouse) incited prominent business leaders and associations to build and expand a crusade to save America’s free enterprise system. My research similarly emphasizes business’s engagement in the transition of the postwar economic order, with a special focus on the financial pillars of the system. However, this article takes a slightly different approach, demonstrating how U.S. industrialists’ new business practices to tackle economic trouble of the late 1960s and 1970s led to changes in industrialists’ policy preferences. That is, in this article, the emphasis is on new business strategies, not on business’s crisis of confidence in the system. In addition, it shows how the unraveling of the postwar class-compromise and the industrialists’ disenchantment with interventionist financial policies created a new coalition between industrialists and financiers for financial reforms, laying the ground for financial expansion.

This article is organized as follows. I first survey the current financialization studies and discuss the contributions of this study to the literature. The following sections explore two key events in the 1970s that paved the way for the rise of finance in the United States: the resurgence of global finance, and the changes in domestic monetary policies. The final section discusses further implications and limitations of this study.

Financialization and Industrial Firms

Financialization studies have suggested industrial firms’ involvement in the rise of finance, yet they failed to specify the role firms played in the transition. Marxist theorists emphasized the deliberate actions of the capitalist class in financialization.Footnote 5 Giovanni Arrighi analyzes the recurrent cycles of accumulation in the capitalist world economy, which consists of two phases: material expansion and financial expansion. The material-expansion phase gives way to financial expansion when the returns from commodity production stagnate, prompting capitalists to shift their profit-making activities toward financial channels. Moreover, this change accelerates as the “blocs of governmental and business agencies” attempt to bring about system renewal in the face of a profitability crisis. For instance, Arrighi argues that U.S. capitalists successfully persuaded the government to create unprecedented economic austerity in the late 1970s, which catalyzed the financialization of the United States.Footnote 6 Gérard Duménil and Dominique Lévy also maintain that recent American financialization reflects capitalists’ victory in the class struggle. Marxist studies have overlooked the distinctive role of industrialists in financialization by analyzing the process at a high level of abstraction. Moreover, they do not provide empirical research on capitalist actions, instead simply “black-boxing” the process.Footnote 7 How was the collective action of the capitalist class possible? What did capitalists aim to achieve? My study seeks to fill this gap by carefully tracing U.S. business actors’ preferences toward particular financial policies over time. In line with the Marxist approach, I argue that business interests and their political actions mattered in the financial shift; yet, I focus on the internal cleavages within the business community in the early postwar years and subsequent convergence by the 1970s. Furthermore, this research stresses a fortuitous alliance between industrialists and financiers aimed at financial reforms. This was possible because the industrialists’ initiatives to rejuvenate industrial profits necessitated such changes.

Next, the literature on shareholderism places nonfinancial corporations in the center of the financialization analysis, examining how shareholder value has become a new paradigm for corporate behavior; “shareholder value” is the idea that maximizing the return to shareholders should be the primary goal of the firm.Footnote 8 The takeover boom, shareholder activism, and the reconceptualization of the firm from social institution to a nexus of contracts all affected the ascendance of shareholderism in the United States. In particular, shareholders in the 1980s and 1990s used sticks and carrots, from the threats of takeovers to the rewards of stock options, to induce managers to continually monitor a firm’s stock market performance. Corporate leaders first resisted but soon adjusted to the trend, starting to serve financial interests by boosting share prices and increasing dividend payments. This perspective effectively shows how financiers shaped the identity of the corporation, which, in turn, helped to fuel the financialization of the economy. However, it cannot (in fact, does not aim to) explain a few shifts critical to the rise of finance that occurred prior to the 1980s, such as the resurgence of global capital and U.S. monetary policy changes. Moreover, shareholderism studies characterize industrial leaders as passive reactors to financial shifts. Alternatively, my research demonstrates that industrialists actively engaged with financial changes in the 1970s, vigorously promoting global capital mobility and monetary changes. Furthermore, American industrialists contributed to the rise of finance without such “identity change”; that is, they promoted financial shifts not to maximize shareholder value but to help new business plans.

Greta Krippner enhances the understanding of U.S. financialization by providing a detailed historical account and elucidating the role of the state in it.Footnote 9 She claims that the U.S. government adopted “free market” policies to redress the domestic crisis of the 1970s, unintentionally generating macroeconomic environment favorable to financial growth. This article shares her enthusiasm for careful historical research; the difference is that it sheds light on the actors she largely omitted: business interests. By examining business activities, this article captures the transnational dimension of American financialization. Krippner recognizes the significance of the international financial development in explaining U.S. financialization, yet she treats the development as an exogenous shock. In contrast, I examine how leading U.S. firms and banks were heavily involved with the resurgence of global finance after WWII, which subsequently stimulated U.S. financial expansion. Also, I stress how special interests affected policy decisions. For instance, as to the 1979 Volcker Shock, I emphasize that the business community provided strong support for the Federal Reserve’s (Fed’s) extreme austerity measures during a severe recession, whereas Krippner focuses on why state actors chose the “monetarist” tactic to bring austerity to the economy.

The Resurgence of Global Finance

The Great Depression and World War II brought an end to a liberal international financial order that had flourished in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. International capital flows virtually disappeared after the Great Depression. Moreover, during the postwar Bretton Woods negotiations, Harry Dexter White and John Maynard Keynes, the delegates from the United States and Britain, respectively, argued strongly that controls on cross-border capital movement were necessary to preserve a state’s policy autonomy.Footnote 10

The issue of capital controls elicited varying responses across the U.S. business community. Financiers, especially large New York City bankers, strongly opposed cross-border capital controls because they would impede lucrative international business opportunities. The bankers also claimed that free capital movement imposes discipline on governments to correct unsound domestic policies. Prominent Wall Street figures like Winthrop Aldrich tried to influence the administration’s policy position by publicizing their argument and using personal ties to the Fed and the State Department.Footnote 11 In particular, the American Bankers Association (ABA) was on the frontline of the fight, drafting an alternative plan for international monetary cooperation. The ABA, founded in 1875, is the largest financial trade organization in the United States, representing the commercial banking sector. Although its members formally included both small and large banks, managers of the big banks dominated its leadership, such as, during the mid-1940s, Randolph Burgess of National City Bank of New York. The ABA’s plan championed free capital movement along with other suggestions for the new international financial system, which drew wide attention from policy makers as well as the business community. Indeed, 1945 congressional hearings regarding the Bretton Woods agreements were centered on the question of whether or not the current government proposal should be revised reflecting the ABA plan.Footnote 12

Conversely, the U.S. industrial sector was generally positive toward the government initiative for the international monetary system, including the state’s right to impose capital controls. First, U.S. industrial leaders were eager to promote foreign trade and worried that free cross-border capital flows could easily destabilize currencies, undermining the revival of foreign trade, as happened during the interwar years.Footnote 13 Moreover, given other countries’ strong demand for capital controls, a blind pursuit of free capital movement could undermine the collective efforts to establish a stable international economic order. Furthermore, some industrial leaders were sympathetic to Keynesian ideas, acknowledging the need to prevent international capital flows from inhibiting a state’s policy choices to achieve certain domestic goals. The different views of financiers and industrialists regarding capital controls are effectively demonstrated in the internal conflicts of the National Foreign Trade Council (NFTC), an organization representing international business interests concerned with trade, FDI, and banking. In the mid-1940s, the NFTC was divided on whether the Bretton Woods agreements should be ratified as drafted or modified as proposed by the ABA. The proponents of the ABA plan insisted on the “removal of exchange controls as rapidly as practicable,” whereas others wanted a more “flexible” approach toward the controls. The latter maintained that the proposed changes were “unnecessary” and would “destroy the progress already made in international cooperation.” They also argued, “No nation can be expected to limit its freedom of action with respect to its domestic social or political policies.”Footnote 14 In the end, the bankers were defeated, and the NFTC decided to support the adoption of the Bretton Woods Agreements Act as drafted, defending it at 1945 congressional hearings.Footnote 15

Within the American business community, the Committee for Economic Development (CED) was at the forefront of defending the Bretton Woods proposals. The CED, since its inception in 1942, represented the “liberal wing of Big Business,” fostering moderate, flexible Keynesian perspectives. It came to prominence during the war because it helped economic planning to prevent a postwar recession. The CED boasted a long list of business and industrial celebrities on its board, which worked with renowned scholars in a joint effort of economic research and policy making.Footnote 16 As to the capital controls under the Bretton Woods system, the CED stated, “We do not wish to interfere with the just right of peoples to deal as may seem to them proper with their own internal problems.” It also said, “We must accept for some time as a condition of orderly currency relationships within the framework of long-term self-interest to ourselves and others, the continuance of methods of exchange control.”Footnote 17 Other major business associations such as the U.S. Chamber of Commerce were not enthusiastic about the government plan, yet endorsed it so as not to delay postwar international cooperation. The Chamber is an umbrella association representing businesses of all sizes and a variety of industries and sectors, including manufacturing, mining, transportation, retail, and services. Founded in 1912, it became “the most successful national association” during the Progressive Era, having more than 1,500 state and local organizations from across the country by 1929.Footnote 18 Compared with the CED, the Chamber spoke for the more traditional, conservative side of the business community, especially with regard to fiscal, welfare, and labor policies, although it moderated its positions to some extent after World War II. During the Bretton Woods negotiations, the Chamber focused on stability in currencies, especially because it believed such stability was decisive to the revival of world trade. Accordingly, the Chamber took an ambivalent attitude toward capital controls, recommending the “ultimate” removal of exchange controls, yet admitting to the need to regulate “abnormal” movement of capital that could destabilize currencies.Footnote 19 At congressional hearings, it sided with the government rather than the ABA, supporting the government proposal as it was without substantial revisions.

The final version of the U.S. proposal partially accommodated the financial sector’s demand by removing mandatory cooperative controls, but the basic faith in capital control did not waver. The 1945 Articles of Agreement explicitly legitimized the right of states to control international capital movement. With a commitment to rebuild stable domestic and international economies, virtually all countries, including the United States, occasionally adopted capital controls in postwar years.

The Development of Euromarkets

Discouraged by war and controls, international capital movement remained very limited, apart from intergovernmental capital flows such as those created by the Marshall Plan in the early postwar years.Footnote 20 However, by the late 1950s, international private financial markets appeared, primarily in London, in the form of the Euromarket.Footnote 21 Euromarkets are where foreign currency is held and traded. For example, an exporter can deposit dollar earnings from trading with the United States at a bank outside the United States (Eurodollar); a U.S. company can issue and trade dollar-denominated bonds outside the United States (Eurobonds). Initially, Eurodollar markets emerged as the central banks of Europe, South-East Asia, and oil-producing countries in the Near East provided their excess dollars to other central banks. The Euromarket steadily grew throughout the late 1950s and early 1960s as the return to convertibility and the relaxation of exchange controls in Europe accelerated foreign trade and investment. In particular, large U.S. corporations aggressively expanded their operations in Western Europe to take advantage of the postwar boom.Footnote 22 Their foreign subsidiaries used Euromarkets as a place to keep retained earnings and to finance overseas operations.Footnote 23 Subsequently, U.S. banks followed their most important industrial customers, establishing physical facilities overseas in order to keep their business competitive with the host-country banks.Footnote 24 Accordingly, by the early 1960s, private firms and banks replaced central banks as the major players in the Euromarket. In its 1964 Quarterly Bulletin, the Bank of England reported that the primary source of funds in the Euromarket changed from the Deutsche Bundesbank, the Banca d’Italia, and the Swiss National Bank to commercial banks and companies, concluding, “It is safe to say that business concerns have been becoming more important.” It also emphasized that U.S. companies, both resident and subsidiaries abroad, were increasingly placing funds in the Euromarket.Footnote 25 Moreover, internationally oriented corporations grew into the dominant demanders of the fund in Euromarkets, along with various government entities that used Euromarkets for deficit financing.Footnote 26

Further transformations of the Euromarket occurred during the mid-1960s and early 1970s. Euromarkets grew very rapidly, between 20 and 50 percent every year, which well exceeded the growth of world trade and investment (Table 1). This discrepancy between the growth rates of the Euromarkets and those of trade and investment implies that the development of Euromarkets cannot be solely attributed to the expansion of the world economy. Also, with the explosive expansion of medium- and long-term Euromarkets—Eurobond and Eurocredit—the Euromarket turned from a short-term money market into a capital market. These dramatic changes were largely affected by the particular characteristics of U.S. capital controls and the subsequent changes in the financing practices of U.S. firms and banks.Footnote 27

Table 1 Trade, FDI, and Euromarkets, 1958–1976

Note: * World FDI represents the sum of the outward FDI stock of four countries: United States, Britain, Germany, and Japan. Figures are from 1960, 1964, 1971, and 1978, respectively.

Sources: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, “Values and Shares”; United Nations, Multinational Corporations; United Nations Centre on Transnational Corporations, Salient Features; Bank for International Settlement, Annual Report, 1969, 1974; Johnston, Economics, 38–39; Mendelsohn, Money on the Move, 67, 211.

The “dollar shortage” of the immediate postwar years turned into a “dollar glut” by the late 1950s as the United States accumulated external deficits. In the 1960s, the U.S. government undertook initiatives to curtail dollar outflows in order to ameliorate the balance-of-payments problem. In 1961 the Kennedy administration tried but failed to increase taxation on FDI because of the strong opposition from U.S.-based multinational corporations.Footnote 28 Deterred by resistance from leading industrialists, the administration switched the target. In 1963 the Interest Equalization Tax (IET), the first peacetime capital control program, was imposed on foreign securities sold in U.S. markets, damaging the securities industry. The tax also applied to dollar transactions abroad (Eurodollar) by U.S. banks’ foreign subsidiaries. Nevertheless, the international payment situation deteriorated, particularly due to Vietnam War-related expenditures, inducing the Johnson administration to take drastic actions. In 1965 the administration issued “voluntary” capital control guidelines for commercial banks and industrial firms to limit foreign loans and new FDI. The Fed reluctantly assumed the supervising job over the banks; the Commerce secretary established a Balance of Payments Advisory Committee, consisting of business leaders from the largest multinational corporations, to oversee FDI regulation.Footnote 29 To lessen business opposition, the government made a crucial concession in the controls—it allowed firms and banks to fund international business in overseas financial markets, including the Eurodollar market.Footnote 30 That is, U.S. firms could continue expanding FDI by getting loans or issuing bonds in international markets; banks could also simply shift their lending activities to foreign branches, thus bypassing the controls. The concession was a significant change considering that the IET of 1963 applied to Eurodollars. The Eurodollars were finally exempted from the tax program in 1967 only after banks persuaded the government that such exemption was necessary to meet the increasing financial needs of U.S. firms abroad since the imposition of 1965 voluntary controls.

In 1968 the Johnson administration tightened the controls further. On New Year’s Day 1968, Johnson issued an executive order that replaced voluntary controls on FDI with mandatory controls. The Fed also instituted new restrictions and strengthened old ones. Nevertheless, the administration preserved the exemption of Eurodollar transactions from U.S. capital controls.

The imposition of capital controls with a special exemption beginning in 1965 induced U.S. firms and banks to dramatically increase the use of the Euromarket as an alternative source of funds. On the National Industrial Conference Board’s (NICB) quarterly surveys on international business in 1968 and 1969, a large number of corporate executives reported that capital controls on FDI pushed their firms to borrow heavily abroad.Footnote 31 Indeed, the Commerce Department’s study on FDI showed that the share of foreign borrowing jumped from 2 percent in 1965 to more than 30 percent of the total sources of FDI in the late 1960s and into 1970 (Figure 1). For instance, foreign subsidiaries of General Motors (GM) increased the share of foreign loans up to 40 percent in the late 1960s (Figure 2). Similarly, U.S. banks began to depend substantially on offshore subsidiaries for foreign lending activities (Figure 3). They also opened new branches abroad to serve their customers, multinational corporations in particular.Footnote 32 For example, Chase Manhattan Bank, Provident National bank of Philadelphia, and Pittsburgh National Bank each opened branches abroad in 1968 to specialize in Euromarket loans to corporate borrowers.Footnote 33 As a result, U.S. firms and banks accelerated the expansion of Euromarkets in the late 1960s and early 1970s. Large U.S. firms became the largest issuers of the Eurobonds in 1968 (Figure 4). U.S. bank subsidiaries also dominated 45 percent of the foreign bank deposits in Britain in 1969, a striking increase from 15 percent in 1962.Footnote 34 With the massive influx of U.S. firms and banks into the market, the Euromarket experienced explosive growth (see Table 1).

Figure 1 Sources for FDI yearly, $bn (constant dollars, 1990=100).

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Foreign Direct Investment Program, 1972 and 1974.

Figure 2 GM foreign loans and shares of total current liabilities, $mm (constant dollars, 1990=100).

Source: General Motors, Annual Report, various years.

Figure 3 Foreign credits of US Banks (constant dollars, 1990=100).

Note: $bn on the left; % on the right.

Source: Brimmer, “Commercial Bank.”

Figure 4 Share of Eurobonds issued by U.S. companies. (%)

Source: World Financial Markets, various years (journal of the Morgan Guaranty Trust Company of New York).

Helleiner argues that the U.S. government exempted Euromarkets from the controls because of the administrators’ plans to improve the balance-of-payments situation by encouraging foreigners to hold onto dollars. He points to the fact that Treasury Secretary Dillon espoused this idea in the early 1960s. Dillon’s idea, however, was not converted into policy. Although the IET was created during his incumbency, it did not exempt Eurodollars. In fact, in the 1960s, U.S. government officials were divided on whether Euromarkets exacerbated the payments problem by attracting the dollar flows out of the United States or improved the situation by providing investors with incentives to invest in the dollars. Also, a closer look at the Foreign Relations of the United States, a comprehensive government document on international monetary and trade policy, reveals that the U.S. government did not consider the expansion of Euromarkets to be a direct means to redress the payments problem, while they carefully examined other initiatives such as capital controls, export subsidies, tourist taxes, and so on. The Euromarket was discussed only as a concession to the business community with respect to capital controls.Footnote 35

The development of Euromarkets signified the resurgence of global private finance, which had been devastated by the Great Depression and World War II. The rapid expansion of international finance destabilized the Bretton Woods system in the late 1960s. At the same time, another threat to the restrictive postwar financial system was looming due to discontent with capital controls.

Large U.S. Industrial Corporations and New International Financial Order

Although the Euromarkets offered breathing space, U.S. industrial leaders became increasingly agitated about capital controls because the controls impeded their efforts to expand overseas operations. Throughout the 1960s, large U.S. industrial corporations vigorously increased FDI, especially in the manufacturing sector and petroleum industry. The ratio of foreign to domestic manufacturing investment by U.S. corporations exceeded 0.2 by the mid-1960s and reached 0.3 by the early 1970s.Footnote 36 By 1970 the sales revenues of U.S. firms’ foreign subsidiaries and affiliates reached around $200 billion a year, equivalent to 20 percent of U.S. domestic production and more than five times the amount of U.S. exports.Footnote 37 In particular, large corporations were the obvious leaders in FDI; 3,400 firms were making direct investments of more than $100,000 per year, and 700 of the largest companies accounted for about 90 percent of all FDI outflows between 1965 and 1967.Footnote 38 Consequently, the imposition of capital controls provoked sharp criticism from the business community. As early as 1965, the International Economic Policy Association (IEPA), the advocate of the largest U.S.-based transnational firms, publicly opposed the controls at congressional hearings. Footnote 39 The NFTC followed suit in 1966.Footnote 40

The tightening of controls in 1968 incited wider opposition. The U.S. Chamber of Commerce and the National Association of Manufacturers (NAM), which were relatively quiet on the issue in the mid-1960s, now joined the attempts to thwart capital controls.Footnote 41 Although the two organizations drew the bulk of their membership from small firms and showed concern for firms of all sizes, their board members often came from large companies, often advocating the demands of big business.Footnote 42 In particular, the nation’s largest corporations dominated internal committees on international issues. For instance, the Chamber’s Special Advisory Panel on Balance of Payments consisted of corporations such as General Electric and Standard Oil. Moreover, the leadership of the Chamber and NAM made efforts to mobilize their members to support international enterprises in the late 1960s and early 1970s.Footnote 43 By the late 1960s, all major business associations such as the CED, Chamber, and NAM and individual corporations flooded congressional hearings to oppose capital controls.Footnote 44 At congressional hearings on the topic of foreign economic policy, John J. Powers, president of Chas. Pfizer & Co., who introduced himself as representing the views of the international manufacturing business, strongly denounced capital controls as damaging to the competitiveness of American firms.Footnote 45 In 1969 the House Committee on Foreign Affairs even announced resolutions calling for the president to terminate capital controls.Footnote 46 The industrialists finally joined the financial community, frequently represented by the ABA and the Investment Bankers Association, which had consistently fought against controls since the imposition of IET.Footnote 47

The U.S. business community then took matters one step further. By the late 1960s, it started to question the efficacy of the postwar international financial regime. Although it did not have a concrete idea about international regime change, industrial leaders emphasized the importance of international capital mobility. In 1968 the NAM stated that the international financial system should “facilitate the flow of investment, goods and people, not to impede it.”Footnote 48 Furthermore, a small number of astute firms actively engaged in the early efforts to shape a new monetary system. When prestigious international scholars and business representatives gathered for a 1969 conference to discuss the pros and cons of fixed versus floating exchange-rate systems, David Grove, chief economist at IBM, and John Watts, a top executive at Brown Brothers Harriman and Co., argued for greater flexibility on the premise that a more flexible regime would provide a better adjustment process, thereby obviating the need for capital controls.Footnote 49

In 1971 the Bretton Woods system finally collapsed.Footnote 50 Despite its efforts to redress the balance of payments situation, the United States continued to accumulate enormous debt from international and domestic commitments, such as the Vietnam War and welfare programs. Between the late 1960s and early 1970s, a large scale of short-term financial flows speculated against overvalued currencies, exacerbating the systemic crisis. Facing a potential run on gold, the United States closed the gold window in August 1971. In July 1972, the governors of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) set up the Committee on Reform of the IMF and Related Issues (The Committee of Twenty) to draft proposals for international monetary reform. One of the Committee of Twenty’s main agendas was the issue of international capital movement because speculative capital flows hastened the fall of the Bretton Woods system. After investigating the causes of the short-term capital flows of the late 1960s and early 1970s, the Committee of Twenty concluded that multinational firms and banks were responsible. In particular, the multinational firms were the main culprits. Their practices of “leads and lags,” the deviations from the usual timing of commercial payments and receipts, generated a substantial amount of destabilizing short-term flows.Footnote 51 The volume of international trade and payments was so large that the slightest change in the timing of payments resulted in enormous movements of capital. To handle the short-term capital flows, Europe and Japan suggested that the provisions on capital controls be strengthened. As speculative capital flows rapidly expanded and technological development made it easier to evade controls, conventional techniques such as unilateral capital controls and offsetting financing proved obsolete. Instead, European officials argued, countries should coordinate their capital control policies regarding foreign currency banking so that they could limit the amount of capital flows those foreign markets could finance.Footnote 52

The problem of international capital flows was also widely examined in the United States. Major news media outlets extensively discussed whether U.S.-based multinational firms and banks were responsible for the currency crises in the late 1960s and early 1970s.Footnote 53 The U.S. business community ardently defended itself against the charges of currency speculation, claiming that its management of foreign currencies was not speculative so much as “defensive” to protect the value of international investments.Footnote 54 In addition, facing efforts to toughen international provisions on capital controls, the U.S. business community hurriedly organized task forces to scrutinize reform of the international monetary regime. The CED placed the “reform of the international monetary system” high on its agenda for 1972 and published the outcome of that work as a statement entitled “Strengthening the World Monetary System” in 1973.Footnote 55 In it, the CED recommended that under the new international system, “every effort should be made to reduce or eliminate” restrictions on trade and capital transactions.Footnote 56 Considering that the CED was sympathetic to the capital controls instituted under Bretton Woods, this statement demonstrated a substantial change in its position. Similarly, the NAM formed a high-level Monetary Reform Task Force in 1972, and contended that the new monetary regime should discourage any governmental action to control cross-border capital flows.Footnote 57

The position of the U.S. government toward international capital movements was similar to that of the business community. In early 1972, the Wall Street Journal reported that the multinationals found “potent new friends in the White House,” which was finishing a comprehensive study on MNCs.Footnote 58 As the Journal expected, the study defended the firms, declaring that “destructive, predatory motivations do not characterize the sophisticated international financial activities of most MNCs, even though much of the funds which flow internationally during the crisis doubtlessly is of MNC origin.”Footnote 59 On the question of capital controls, the United States disagreed with other countries’ suggestions to impose “comprehensive restrictions” on international capital movement. Instead, through Treasury Secretary George Shultz’s speech at IMF’s 1972 annual meeting and Nixon’s Economic Report in early 1973, the U.S. government proclaimed that controls on capital transactions “should not be encouraged and certainly should not be required.”Footnote 60 This statement represented a significant shift in the American attitude toward capital controls, considering that the U.S. government had recommended mandatory cooperation with controls during the Bretton Woods negotiations. Subsequently, the United States abolished its own control programs in 1974. Regarding the United States’ enthusiasm for free capital movement, scholars have emphasized the government’s new international monetary strategy, the Republican administration, and the influx of neoliberal economists into the government.Footnote 61 These factors were no doubt important, yet business mobilization also played a crucial role. Indeed, Paul Volcker, Under Secretary of the Treasury for International Monetary Affairs, from 1969 to 1974, recalls that one “pressing” reason for the removal of controls was business demands.Footnote 62

The United States’ strong support for free capital movement in the early 1970s signified a turning point in the globalization of finance. First, the United States shaped the basic tone of post-Bretton Woods framework regarding international capital mobility by successfully blocking European and Japanese initiatives to strengthen cross-border capital controls by weakening provisions on controls. The Committee of Twenty’s Final Report of 1974 allowed for, but did not oblige, cooperative controls among the countries. Furthermore, it called for strict discipline; for instance, capital controls to sustain inappropriate exchange rates, which had been widely used under the Bretton Woods system, were forbidden.Footnote 63 The basic tenet of the new regime differed greatly from that of the old, when capital controls were considered both “inevitable and indeed desirable.”Footnote 64 Second, given the fast-growing international capital markets, innovative techniques to avoid controls, and the United States’ support of cross-border capital mobility, other countries soon realized that unilateral capital controls were largely ineffective; moreover, the economic and political costs related to capital controls grew enormously in the increasingly open economy. Europeans and Japanese abolished their controls throughout the 1980s and 1990s.Footnote 65

The resurgence of global finance, in turn, catalyzed U.S. financialization. First, as the world’s leading bankers, U.S. financiers benefitted tremendously from the business opportunities that liberalized international financial markets provided. International investors were attracted to the U.S. financial market due to its unrivaled size and liquidity, as well as the dollar’s special role in the world economy.Footnote 66 Second, with increased mobility, international finance gained the ability to potentially inundate or dry national financial markets. As discussed in the following section, the austerity measures of the 1970s attracted large amount of foreign capital into the United State, expanding its financial markets. Finally, increased capital movement, combined with floating exchange rates, raised economic uncertainty and promoted financial speculation.Footnote 67

The Change in U.S. Monetary Policy

The Great Depression and World War II brought changes to the domestic economic order, too. The “laissez-faire” doctrine yielded to the idea of an interventionist state. The U.S. government increasingly committed itself to the goals of economic growth and full employment, which were to be achieved by active fiscal and monetary policies. As early as 1937, President Roosevelt endorsed deficit spending to stabilize the economy.Footnote 68 The postwar administrations also undertook substantial monetary interventions, maintaining interest rates at an artificially low level in order to support the growth agenda.Footnote 69

The establishment of a Keynesian regime was initially challenged, but was generally accepted by the U.S. business community by the late 1940s, particularly among the large industrial firms.Footnote 70 The CED rejected the doctrine of annually balanced budgets, espousing active counter-cyclical measures to moderate economic fluctuations.Footnote 71 Even the conservative U.S. Chamber of Commerce agreed: “We do not question that compensatory fiscal policy may provide at times a useful, and even necessary measure of contracyclical action. The day has passed when [the] government can deal with depression simply by whistling or wringing its hands, and this device should be included in the armory of weapons it can deploy.”Footnote 72 In turn, the country’s new orientation toward economic growth helped big business and organized labor to develop collaborative industrial relations. An exemplary case of this exists between GM and the United Auto Workers (UAW). GM undertook massive expansion programs to exploit the booming car market after the war. To ensure stability in the investment, GM forged the first multiyear union contract with the UAW in 1948, providing workers with higher pay and better benefits.Footnote 73

However, not everyone in the business community was happy with the growth agenda. The financial sector constantly cautioned that overly stimulative measures could lead to inflation, the Number 1 enemy of financial asset holders.Footnote 74 The debate surrounding volatile economic situations in the late 1940s effectively demonstrates the different views between industry and finance toward macroeconomic policy (Figure 5). Experiencing severe recession and inflation, U.S. business was divided on the causes of and solutions for inflation. At 1946 congressional hearings, Henry Ford II, of Ford Motors, identified “scarcity” as the cause of inflation, claiming: “The way to prevent inflation is to produce goods for people.”Footnote 75 Ralph Flanders, of the CED, also bolstered the collaborative efforts of “management, labor and government to increase productivity.”Footnote 76 The NAM, despite having been a virulent critic of an interventionist government throughout the Progressive Era and New Deal years, put more emphasis on production than on a tight budget.Footnote 77 The banking community took a different approach. Representing the Committee on Public Debt Policy, Randolph Burgess, vice chairman of the National City Bank of New York, urged taking control of the government budget and debt to curb inflation. The committee comprised eight bankers, three academics, and one industrial leader; the eight bankers came from diverse backgrounds, ranging from large commercial banks, to savings banks, and to insurance companies.Footnote 78

Figure 5 U.S. macroeconomic changes, 1944–1985.

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Gross Domestic Product; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer Price Index; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Unemployment Rate.

The Beginning of Stagflation: Late 1960s–Early 1970s

The postwar Golden Age of capitalism started to falter by the late 1960s. The U.S. government’s heavy domestic and international spending brought inflationary pressures to the economy and destabilized the international monetary system. Facing the overheating of the economy and the balance of payments crisis, the business community demanded an economic cooling. However, as the economy began a downturn in the early 1970s, industry and finance took distinct paths.

The U.S. financial community attributed disturbing economic conditions in the late 1960s to Keynesian policies. The ABA bolstered the “classical remedies” of the state-initiated recession to solve the international imbalances. Under the traditional gold standard system, countries with substantial deficits were pressured to deflate the economy, dampening the demand for imports while improving export competitiveness. The ABA contended that the increase in unemployment, the “obvious costs” of the austerity measures, should not prevent the use of such measures.Footnote 79 The industrial sector also demanded tight budgets and a decrease in the money supply, although it also cautioned against economic stagnation. The U.S. Chamber of Commerce asked the administration “to fight inflation persistently, but not so drastically as to raise the overall unemployment.”Footnote 80 Moreover, industrialists recommended curtailing external debt primarily by reducing international engagements such as foreign aid and NATO commitments rather than contracting the domestic economy.Footnote 81

With the economic slowdown of 1970–1971, the attitudes of financiers and industrialists diverged. Despite economic stagnation, financiers continued to uphold strong contractionary policies against the administration’s plan to ease fiscal and monetary restraints. For instance, Donald Regan, president of Merrill Lynch, Pierce, Fenner, & Smith, testified before Congress that eighteen months of restraint “has brought with it no small degree of hardship. … I am afraid, however, that we shall have to sustain that hardship for a while longer.”Footnote 82 Similar testimonies were made by numerous representatives of various financial institutions and associations, encompassing investment banking, commercial banking, and the insurance industry, such as Salomon Bros & Hutzler, the Bank of America, the ABA, the National Association of Mutual Savings Banks, and the Life Insurance Association of America.Footnote 83 Conversely, industrialists called for the resumption of economic growth. Frank Murphy, of General Electric (GE), strongly criticized that “overly restrictive credit and fiscal policies have remained in place too long.”Footnote 84 The CED, Chamber, and NAM also called for a substantial easing of the austerity measures of 1968–1969.Footnote 85 Organized labor urged the government to adopt expansionary policies to trigger economic growth.Footnote 86 The Nixon administration promptly responded to signs of an economic downturn and the demands of industry and labor by adopting expansionary fiscal and monetary policies in 1971 and 1972.

American Industrialists’ New Business Strategies and New Policy Positions

By the mid-1970s, large U.S. industrial corporations started to withdraw their support of the postwar growth regime and push for austerity. The firms’ changed positions toward macroeconomic policies reflected their new strategies to restore industrial profits.

As U.S. private sector profitability, particularly in manufacturing, fell sharply in the 1970s, firms tried to overcome the difficulties by accelerating overseas production and abandoning the postwar capital–labor pact. First, large U.S. firms increased their reliance on FDI. For instance, IBM derived 30 percent of its income from FDI in 1965, and 49 percent in 1974; Ford derived 12 percent from FDI in 1965, and 49 percent in 1974.Footnote 87 In fact, the profitability of manufacturing FDI finally surpassed that of domestic manufacturing production in the 1970s (Table 2). Even the companies that had served foreign customers primarily through exports showed greater interest in FDI by the late 1970s. For example, GE substituted FDI for exports because of foreign trade barriers and high domestic labor costs.Footnote 88

Table 2 Domestic and overseas profit rates, percent

Source: Ceyhun, “Multinational Corporations,” 57.

Industrial firms’ increasing involvement in international business, especially in FDI, made them sensitive to the dollar crisis. These firms had benefitted from the dollar’s special role in international business because they had easy access to the international reserve currency; moreover, strong dollars allowed them to purchase foreign materials and labor cheaply.Footnote 89 As the dollar received massive speculative attacks in the late 1970s, these firms began to demand that the government keep the dollar stable and strong.Footnote 90 For instance, GE reacted differently to the dollar crisis of the late 1970s than that of the late 1960s, as it had shifted its international strategies from exports in the 1960s to FDI in the 1970s. At NAM’s 1968 meeting, GE opposed urgent actions to support the dollar, instead defending the government’s expansionary policies.Footnote 91 However, by the late 1970s, Reginald Jones, chairman and CEO of GE, urged President Carter to adopt a series of policies “aimed at shoring up the sagging value of the dollar in international markets.”Footnote 92 Similarly, Ford Motor valued the dollar’s stability more than export competitiveness by the late 1970s. At 1978 congressional hearings, Senator Javits observed, “You would rather have a stable dollar with a lessening of inflation … even though this particular fall in the dollar has helped your competitive situation.” John Deaver, representing Ford, answered, “That is correct.”Footnote 93 Ford executives supported Carter’s programs to “bolster the value of the dollar.”Footnote 94

Second, industrialists deserted the postwar capital–labor pact. The internationalization strategy helped U.S. firms to restore profits to some extent; yet, it did not entirely solve the problem of intensifying foreign competition. Moreover, growing cross-border capital movement created an unforeseen problem: increased economic volatility. These problems induced U.S. industrialists to reassess labor relations. In the early postwar years, the firms needed multiyear contracts with unions to ensure stability in long-term, massive investments; they could also afford generous pay and benefits, simply passing higher labor costs to customers. However, the situation had changed. The U.S. industrialists now had to compete with fast-growing foreign manufacturers from Germany and Japan, where labor costs were only 60 percent and 25 percent, respectively, of that in the United States by 1970.Footnote 95 Also, the increased economic volatility of the 1970s led firms to pursue flexibility in the production process and labor markets.Footnote 96 As a result, the postwar class compromise was abandoned. Employers increasingly denied workers’ petitions for union representation and illegally fired workers for union activities in the 1970s.Footnote 97 Even large industrial corporations, the exemplars of collaborative industrial relations, joined the movement. GM expanded its factories into regions where both organized labor support and wages were low.Footnote 98 In 1976, UAW Vice President Irving Bluestone criticized GM’s new national contract as “the harshest” proposal he had seen in more than a quarter-century.Footnote 99 U.S. industrialists also defeated a labor reform bill in 1977, which would have facilitated unionization. The Business Roundtable, which consisted of the CEOs of the largest corporations, had previously taken a relatively conciliatory stance toward organized labor. Now, it joined more conservative groups such as the Chamber and NAM, effectively killing the labor reform bill.Footnote 100

The souring relationship between big business and organized labor prevented their cooperation in anti-inflation efforts. As the Ford and Carter administrations struggled to avoid the two extreme choices of economic austerity and mandatory price controls, the former being the first choice of financiers and the latter the first choice of organized labor, they tried to persuade capital and labor to voluntarily cooperate in limiting price increases. However, the “voluntary” solution was doomed to fail. Not only did U.S. business organizations lack the ability to convince their members to resist price increases but also business and organized labor were antagonistic toward each other. For example, even though the Business Roundtable promised to support Carter’s voluntary control programs in 1978, Irving Shapiro, the CEO of DuPont and a leading member of the Roundtable, said that his company would raise prices if necessary.101Also, ongoing capital–labor relations during the 1970s did not allow for voluntary cooperation. After the bitter defeat in labor law reform fights, UAW President Douglas Fraser resigned from a labor–management committee Carter had created to encourage cooperation in inflation and major economic issues, in a show of “disappointment with the Carter Administration and anger at the business community.”Footnote 102 Waterhouse compares the United States with Germany, noting that “institutionalized corporatism” promoted cooperation between capital and labor in Germany in anti-inflation efforts, while the absence of corporatism prevented coordination in the United States.Footnote 103

Finally, by the mid-1970s, some U.S. industrial firms started to embrace the “classical remedy” for the inflation problem: austerity. Keynesian macroeconomic policies became less effective in the increasingly globalized world economy. Moreover, expansionary measures would empower labor by lowering unemployment, which was exactly what industrialists wanted to avoid in the 1970s. In a period of heightened international competition and volatility, rigid labor relations became a liability; also, the firms could no longer afford the high price of labor. Conversely, austerity would generate a sharp recession in the economy, weakening organized labor as well as bringing down labor costs.

Continuing Stagflation and the Beginning of a New Coalition: Mid-1970s

During the severe recession of 1974–1975, some industrial leaders started to break away from the postwar growth alliance with organized labor, while others remained loyal. On the one hand, influential industrialists such as Henry Ford II, Reginald Jones, and David Grove advocated expansionary fiscal and monetary policies, welcoming Carter’s stimulus package. Henry Ford II pleaded in front of Congress in 1975: “We must not be so frightened by the perils of inflation that we do too little too late to restore economic growth.”Footnote 104 The CED also demanded “clearly stimulative” monetary and fiscal policies.Footnote 105 In a similar vein, the Business Roundtable and leading manufacturers, including U.S. Steel and Westinghouse, emphasized productivity to control inflation.Footnote 106

On the other hand, the Chamber and NAM were more cautious. For example, in 1975, the Chamber claimed that both “recession and inflation” were centural problems, and vacillated between stimulative and contractionary measures.Footnote 107 Heath Larry, chairman of the Board of Directors of NAM, stated to the press in 1977: “The NAM pledges its support to the new Administration in any reasonable efforts to deal with the twin problems of a sluggish economy and unemployment. But we would, however, express strong reservations about any significant reliance upon either forced stimulation of aggregate demand.”Footnote 108 At the other end of the spectrum were financiers and internationally oriented industrialists who vociferously argued that the nation would have to bear the costs of the recession to fight inflation effectively. The ABA, along with leading investment banks such as Merrill Lynch and Salomon Bros., opposed Carter’s stimulus programs.Footnote 109 The NFTC recommended that the United States avoid high inflation because the government had a “special responsibility” to uphold a strong dollar in the current international monetary system.Footnote 110

U.S. Business Community and the Volcker Shock: Late 1970s–Early 1980s

The economy quickly recovered from the 1974–1975 recession, but inflation rose from 5.8 percent in 1976, to 6.5 percent in 1977, and to 7.6 percent in 1978, while the unemployment rate dropped below 6 percent by 1978. U.S. businesses then started to call for macroeconomic policy restraint. In the late 1970s, both financiers and industrialists openly insisted that the nation should endure the pain of economic recession in order to bring prices down.

By 1978 the U.S. business community turned away from expansionary policies and toward intense and radial austerity. At 1978 congressional hearings on the topic of the world economy, Walter Wriston, chairman of Citicorp, argued that the international economic instability stemmed from the U.S. government’s stimulative monetary policies. He further insisted, “We must stop pretending that it is possible to fine tune our economy.” Instead, he advocated for a “fundamental turn” in national policy away from pursuing higher growth.Footnote 111 The industrialists agreed with the financiers. In April 1978 Thomas Murphy, chairman of GM, maintained that the inflation problem could “only be resolved” by fiscal and monetary restraints.Footnote 112 NAM’s Board of Directors unanimously adopted the “statement on inflation” in October 1978, which requested the government’s “unqualified commitment” to tighten budgets and money supply.Footnote 113 Compared to this radical position, the Chamber’s response was moderate. While it also demanded an “all-out effort” from the administration to curb inflation, it also cautioned about the likelihood of a recession.Footnote 114 Conversely, organized labor asked Carter to use mandatory price controls instead of unemployment to end inflation.Footnote 115 By late 1978, the Carter administration deserted its failed approach to inflation, a simple persuasion to moderate prices and wages, announcing in its place a series of anti-inflation programs. The administration proposed tougher fiscal and monetary restraints; it also introduced formal wage and price guidelines with specific quantitative constraints. Nevertheless, these policies did not stabilize the economy.

Stagflation reached its climax in 1979. The inflation rate rose above 10 percent while the economy grew by less than 1 percent in the first half of 1979. Moreover, economic forecasts pointed toward an oncoming recession and an even higher inflation rate. During congressional hearings in 1979, prominent economists clashed over the direction of national economic policy. For instance, in February 1979, Martin Feldstein, of Harvard University, demanded more economic slack to reduce inflation. Lester Thurow, of MIT, conversely, worried that recent monetary and fiscal measures were “completely inappropriate” and would only deepen the recession.Footnote 116 Major media outlets also had different views. While the Wall Street Journal castigated Fed Chair Miller for being soft on inflation, the New York Times saw the nation as facing a recession as well as inflation.Footnote 117 Similarly, the public was split on how to tackle stagflation. Although Americans demanded strong anti-inflation measures, they did not want to curb inflation by causing severe recession. About half of the public was still open to wage and price controls, particularly Democratic voters.Footnote 118

Unlike the academics, media, and general public, U.S. industry and finance leaders agreed that ending inflation was best served by engineering a recession. This time, industrialists stuck to their demands for austerity despite the onset of a recession. In March 1979, the NAM said, “The war against inflation will truly be a test of the nation’s moral fiber. Are we fully prepared to meet that test—or are we proceeding on the assumption that a war against inflation can be a war without casualties?” It repeated the same argument in its multiple publications.Footnote 119 U.S. Chamber of Commerce chairman Shearon Harris also emphasized that the “acid test” for the nation’s anti-inflation policy would be “what actions are taken if the U.S. slips into a recession.”Footnote 120 The NYC Chamber of Commerce claimed that the Fed should be the “supplier of restraint of last resort” because of the short-term inflexibility of the budget.Footnote 121 The NFTC continued its appeal for monetary and fiscal discipline to stabilize the dollar through its annual policy declarations.Footnote 122 More moderate business organizations such as the CED and Business Roundtable joined the crusade, calling for budgetary and monetary restraints at congressional hearings.Footnote 123 Meanwhile, the financial community upheld its credo. The ABA insisted that the government adopt more restrictive monetary and fiscal policies and maintain them even when the economy enters into recession; the American Council of Life Insurance agreed.Footnote 124 Representatives from various financial intermediaries—ranging from Morgan Stanley and Co., to Prudential Insurance Co., and to North Carolina National Bank—swarmed congressional hearings to demand austerity.Footnote 125

Finally, in 1979, the Carter administration showed its strong determination to end inflation. In early 1979, Michael Blumenthal, secretary of the Treasury, and Charles Schultze, chair of the Council of Economic Advisers, pressed the Fed to tighten further the money supply. However, Fed Chair Miller was reluctant to do so due to widespread anticipation of an imminent recession.Footnote 126 In an effort to reboot his economic measures, Carter reshuffled his cabinet in summer 1979, replacing Miller with Paul Volcker. Volcker was one of the few members of the Federal Open Market Committee, the locus of monetary policy-making, who opposed Miller’s views and advocated more restrictive direction.Footnote 127 The Wall Street Journal welcomed the appointment, calling it a “balm for business,” whereas the New York Times expressed reservations.Footnote 128 When Volcker adopted extremely contractionary measures, known as the “Volcker Shock,” in October 1979, the business community strongly endorsed the approach.Footnote 129 The NAM appealed that “this is strong medicine and, as we have already seen, it has distressing side effects. Furthermore, one dose won’t cure us of inflation and we will have to be taking this medicine for a long time into the future.”Footnote 130 Also, individual business leaders of GE, du Pont, Sears, and others showed positive responses.Footnote 131 However, there were also voices of concern. Lane Kirkland, of the AFL-CIO, called it “the wrong move at the wrong time.”Footnote 132

Volcker staunchly upheld his tight monetary policies during the early 1980s, causing interest rates to rise to almost 20 percent in 1981. Consequently, the U.S. economy slipped into the most severe contraction since the 1930s, with unemployment exceeding 10 percent in summer 1981. Despite the deep recession, Volcker recalls, “There was substantial support in the country for a tough stand against inflation, for all the real pain and personal dislocation that seemed to imply.”Footnote 133 In particular, the U.S. business community stood firmly behind the Fed’s extreme monetary policies.Footnote 134 In 1980 the CED claimed in front of Congress that “policy makers must not yield to the temptation to abandon monetary restraint or government spending limits,” even as the recession continued.Footnote 135 William Niskanen, of Ford Motors, while recognizing that the U.S. auto industry was experiencing a recession, emphasized that “fiscal, monetary, and regulatory policies should be directed to longer term objectives, rather than to specific relief during a recession.”Footnote 136 In May 1980 George Hagedorn, of NAM, was delighted that “our political leaders finally appear willing to accept the recession which seems inescapable as a step toward curbing inflation.”Footnote 137 In 1981 James Binns, chairman of NAM’s Board of Directors, proudly reported to its members that the newly elected U.S. president promised to shun stopgap measures, but instead would continue fiscal and monetary restraints.Footnote 138 Similarly, at 1981 congressional hearings, Richard Rahn, vice present and chief economist of the Chamber, encouraged Congress to support the Fed’s actions.Footnote 139 In 1982 NAM relentlessly upheld its support for a balanced budget and an “independent Fed.”Footnote 140 Of course, bankers stood with the industrialists. For instance, the ABA stated in front of Congress in 1980 that the monetary authority should enjoy “freedom from political pressures.”Footnote 141 In 1981 the American Council of Life Insurance stressed the importance of anti-inflation policies, regardless of the strong resistance against such fight.Footnote 142 In his recent study on the independence of the Federal Reserve, Conti-Brown notes that Paul Volcker built his own “independent political base” during his first term: U.S. business. Even after the severe recession, Reagan had to reappoint Volcker as Fed Chair in fear of the reactions from the market.Footnote 143

At last, inflation was halved to 6.2 percent in 1982 from its peak of 13.5 percent in 1980. However, the deep recession following the Volcker Shock transformed the U.S. economy in many ways. Small firms, exporters, and interest-rate-sensitive industries such as construction and automobile were hit hard. In addition, the unprecedented level of unemployment substantially weakened the bargaining position of labor unions.Footnote 144 Most important to this article’s argument, the extreme austerity facilitated the rise of finance in the United States. As the austerity measures reduced inflation, financial profits rebounded. High interest rates also attracted a large amount of foreign capital into the U.S. financial markets, enriching U.S. financiers as well as creating an economic environment conducive to financial bubbles by expanding available credit in the economy. Scholars have indicated that the Volcker Shock signified a paradigm shift in U.S. monetary policy.Footnote 145 Since the late 1970s, the Fed has prioritized price stability over full employment. From 1961 to 1965, the average real interest rates were 2.7 percent and 1.8 percent, long-term and short-term, respectively; however, the rates rose to 7 percent and 4.8 percent between 1981 and 1985, and 4.2 percent and 3.3 percent between 1996 and 2000.Footnote 146 As Keynes once noted, the “contractionary bias” has served financial interests well.

Coda

This article analyzed how industrial leaders engaged in American financialization, and focused on new business practices and business politics. It also demonstrated how the financial transition was interwoven with the unraveling of the postwar class-compromise between big business and organized labor and the concurrent emergence of industrialist–financier alliance. Prominent industrialists, once strong supporters of the New Deal order, changed their attitude toward labor relations and Keynesian economics as they applied new business strategies to deal with economic turmoil during the 1960s and 1970s.

In addition, this research contributes to the business history literature by offering new perspectives on important historical events such as the collapse of the Bretton Woods system and the Volcker Shock. First, historians have extensively examined the role of industrial firms in globalization, but have underestimated their role in the key incidents leading to financial globalization, such as the international monetary changes during the early 1970s.Footnote 147 This research demonstrated that multinational firms’ practice of “leads and lags” critically destabilized the postwar Bretton Woods system. Also, while studies have emphasized U.S. firms’ reactions to U.S. capital controls, this research goes further, showing that major business associations organized task forces to investigate and influence international monetary reforms. This study calls for further research on the role of business actors in the transformation of international monetary systems. Also, this article characterizes American business’s support of the Volcker Shock differently from studies that emphasize the class-based divisions of unemployment versus inflation trade-off.Footnote 148 Specifically, my research delves into the internal rift within the business community, revealing that industrialists were much more patient with expansionary policies than were financiers, at least until the 1970s.Footnote 149 That is, “class” alone cannot explain U.S. industrial leaders’ changing policy preferences over time; instead, the industrialists’ new business agendas in the 1970s influenced their policy positions. Surely, as current studies correctly indicate, U.S. business’s distaste for price controls and concern about hyperinflation affected their attitude toward austerity policies. My research complements these studies by demonstrating that changes in business strategies also mattered.

Finally, this article’s limitations and caveats should be discussed. In focusing on explaining the role of leading industrialists in American financialization, this article inevitably omits attention to many actors and issues considered critical in the literature. For instance, researchers have indicated that major state and government entities were central to the development of Euromarkets. The American and British governments allowed market participants a great degree of freedom in Euromarkets, even though they had tools to regulate the markets; also, central banks, state agencies, and local governments were main suppliers and demanders of the funds in the markets.Footnote 150 What this research intends to show is that U.S. industrial firms grew into major players, along with governments and bankers, in the Euromarkets during the 1960s and early 1970s, which had significant implications for the fate of the Bretton Woods system. In a similar vein, my research does not claim that the business backing of monetary restraint was the sole or most important factor behind the Volcker Shock. The extraordinary level of inflation, international dollar crisis, and the rise of “monetarist” approach were all responsible for the event.Footnote 151 Additionally, my emphasis on the political power of business does not imply that business unity guarantees policy changes to their benefit.Footnote 152 For example, although both industrial and financial leaders opposed consumer credit controls in the early 1980s, the Carter administration implemented them to appease certain groups such as labor unions.Footnote 153 A more modest claim of this article is that the U.S. business community showed its firm commitment to austerity during a severe recession, significantly helping the Fed to maintain drastic monetary policies.

Footnotes

1. This article follows Epstein’s and Krippner’s definitions of financialization. Epstein, Financialization; Krippner, Capitalizing on Crisis.

2. Krippner, Capitalizing on Crisis, 51–57; Gowan, Global Gamble.

3. Phillips-Fein, Invisible Hands.

4. Waterhouse, Lobbying America.

5. Magdoff and Sweezy, Stagnation; Arrighi, Long Twentieth Century; Duménil and Lévy, Capital Resurgent.

6. Arrighi, Long Twentieth Century, 9, 314.

7. For similar criticism, see van der Zwan, “Making Sense,” 106.

8. Fligstein, Transformation of Corporate Control; Fligstein, Architecture of Markets; Lazonick and O’Sullivan, “Maximizing Shareholder Value”; O’Sullivan, Contests for Corporate Control; Davis, Managed by the Markets.

9. Krippner, Capitalizing on Crisis.

10. Horsefield, International Monetary Fund, 13, 63–67.

11. Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance, 39–40.

12. United States, Bretton Woods Agreements Act.

13. Barry Eichengreen noted that the restoration of international trade was the “tonic” to invigorate Bretton Woods. Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital, 97.

14. Acc. 2345, Series IV, Box 130, Bulletin No. 1064, Hagley Museum and Library (HML).

15. United States, Bretton Woods Agreements Acts, 1262.

16. For more on the CED, see Schriftgiesser, Business Comes of Age.

17. United States, Bretton Woods Agreements, 1259. See also CED, Bretton Woods Proposals.

18. Waterhouse, Lobbying America, 51–52.

19. Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America (Chamber), Post-War Readjustments, 13, 16; Chamber, International Financial Problems, 28; Acc. 1960, Series I, Box 3, Board of Directors meeting, May 5–6, 1944, HML.

20. Mendelsohn, Money on the Move, 207; Bryant, International Financial Intermediation, 62.

21. For the history of the Euromarket, see Versluysen, Political Economy; Schenk, “Origins of the Eurodollar”; Battilossi and Cassis, European Banks; Burn, Re-Emergence of Global Finance.

22. Between 1945 and the mid-1960s, the United States accounted for about 85 percent of all new FDI outflows. Jones, “Multinationals from the 1930s to the 1980s,” 88.

23. Kindleberger, American Business Abroad, 10; Wilkins, Maturing of Multinational Enterprise, 382; Jones, “Multinationals from the 1930s to the 1980s,” 93.

24. Kapstein, Governing the Global Economy, 33; Battilossi, “Financial Innovation,” 169; Burn, Re-Emergence of Global Finance, 138.

25. Bank of England, Quarterly Bulletin, 105. The Bank of England notes that the knowledge of the “uses” of the funds is rather “sketchy.”

26. Versluysen, Political Economy, 39; Burn, Re-Emergence of Global Finance, 24–29.

27. The expansion of Euromarkets in the late 1960s was also affected by U.S. credit crunches of 1966 and 1969. The Fed’s tight monetary policy caused money market rates to rise above the Regulation Q ceiling on bank deposits, triggering an outflow of deposits from banks—the so-called disintermediation. U.S. banks subsequently raised Eurodollars through their foreign branches, which pushed up Eurodollar interest rates dramatically. However, after 1969, U.S. banks did not resort to the Eurodollar market for domestic use because of the emergence of alternative funding sources such as commercial paper and the Fed’s imposition of reserve requirements on Eurodollar borrowing. Also, the impact of disintermediation seems to have been confined to the short-term Eurocurrency market (e.g., three-month Eurodollar deposits) for the specific years of credit crunches). See Sylla, “United States Banks and Europe,” 65–66; Schenk, “International Financial Centers,” 93–94; Battilossi, “Banking with Multinationals,” 108–109.

28. United States, President’s 1961 Tax Recommendations.

29. Foreign Relations of the United States (FRUS), Documents 47 and 52. Document 47 shows that Commerce Secretary Connor originally planned to require the firms to report their FDI plans to him, but dropped the requirement after meeting with the Advisory Committee.

30. FRUS, Document 45 and 162.

31. National Industrial Conference Board, Managing International Business.

32. United States Tariff Commission, Implications of Multinational Firms, 43. See also Battilossi, “Banking with Multinationals,” 103, 108–109.

33. “Chase Bank to Open Subsidiary in Geneva For Eurodollar Lending,” Wall Street Journal, August 1, 1968; “Nassau Units Opened By Provident National, Pittsburgh National,” Wall Street Journal, May 27, 1968; Kelly de Escobar, Bankers and Borders, 23; Burn, Re-Emergence of Global Finance, 29.

34. Bank of England, Quarterly Bulletin.

35. FRUS, Document 91. Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance, 90–91. Schenk, “International Financial Centers,” 89–90; Burn, Re-Emergence of Global Finance, 143; FRUS, Documents 33, 45, and 61.

36. Brenner, Economics of Global Turbulence, 59.

37. United States, 1970 Economic Report of the President, 539.

38. Hawley, Dollars & Borders, 92.

39. United States, Balance of Payments, 1965.

40. Hawley, Dollars & Borders, 80. See also Acc. 2345, Series II, Box 5, National Foreign Trade Council (NFTC) Board Minutes, 1968–1972, HML.

41. The Chamber and the NAM were critical of the controls, but remained cooperative with the government into the mid-1960s. See United States, January 1965 Economic Report of the President.

42. Smith, American Business and Political Power, 40–42, 49; Phillips-Fein, Invisible Hands, 14.

43. For example, the associations published pamphlets to explain the benefits of foreign trade, FDI, and multinational corporations in the early 1970s. Acc. 1411, Series IX, Box 160, “Could Foreign Competition Take My Job?” (U.S. Chamber of Commerce), HML. William R. Pollert, “Foreign Direct Investment and the Multinational Corporation: The Facts and the Myths,” NAM Reports, April 1972. NAM Reports was the journal of National Association of Manufacturers.

44. The CED also changed its position from reserved criticism to outright opposition. See CED, Dollar and the World Monetary System, 19.

45. United States, Foreign Economic Policy for the 1970s.

46. United States, Review of Balance of Payments Policies; United States, Foreign Direct Investment Controls.

47. Hawley, Dollars & Borders, Chapter 3; Conybeare, United States Foreign Economic Policy, 106–108.

48. Acc. 1411, Series I, Box 26, joint meeting of International Economic Affairs committee and Money/Credit/Capital Formation Committee, April 18, 1968, HML.

49. Bergsten and Halm, Approaches to Greater Flexibility.

50. For the fall of Bretton Woods, see Odell, U.S. International Monetary Policy; Gowa, Closing the Gold Window.

51. Committee of Twenty, International Monetary Reform, 78–94.

52. De Vries, International Monetary Fund, 50; Toniolo, Central Bank Cooperation, 465–468.

53. “World of Finance: How Multinational Firm Protects Its Flanks In Monetary Dealings,” Wall Street Journal, August 20, 1971; “Talk of the Globe: Many Critics Charge Multinational Firms Create Money Crises,” Wall Street Journal, April 19, 1973; “Currency Crisis Can Be Easily Triggered By Multinational Firms, U.S. Study States,” Wall Street Journal, February 13, 1973.

54. Acc. 1411, Comments on the International Activities of U.S. Multinational Corporations, submitted to Subcommittee on International Trade and Commission on Finance, U.S. Senate, January 19, 1973, HML.

55. CED, Report of Activities.

56. CED, Strengthening the World Monetary System, 26.

57. Acc. 1411, Series IX, Box 160, The International Monetary System, submitted by International Economic Affairs Committee, at the Board of Directors meeting, September 16, 1974, HML. The Chamber also emphasized international monetary stability without direct controls. Acc. 1960, Series I, Box 4, Report to the Board of Directors, by Banking and Monetary Policy Committee, February 16, 1971, and November 6, 1972, HML.

58. “High-Level Friends: Nixon Moves to Help Multinational Concerns Offensively, Defensively,” Wall Street Journal, January 13, 1972.

59. United States Tariff Commission, Implications of Multinational Firms, 9.

60. Economic Report of the President Transmitted to the Congress, January 1973.

61. Hawley, Dollars & Borders, 106–107; Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance, 111–121.

62. Volcker and Gyohten, Changing Fortunes, 107.

63. De Vries, International Monetary Fund, 167, 170–171.

64. Dam, Rules of the Game, 249.

65. Goodman and Pauly, “Obsolescence of Capital Controls.”

66. Gowan, Global Gamble.

67. Arrighi, Long Twentieth Century; Krippner, Capitalizing on Crisis, 51–57.

68. Blyth, Austerity, 189.

69. Duménil and Lévy, “Costs and Benefits”; Guttmann, “Money and Credit in Regulation Theory”; Major, “Fall and Rise of Financial Capital.”

70. Phillips-Fein, Invisible Hands; Collins, Politics of Economic Growth; Blyth, Great Transformations.

71. CED, CED Digest; CED, Taxes and the Budget; CED, Monetary and Fiscal Policy.

72. Chamber, Program for Sustaining Employment, 25.

73. For industrial relations during early postwar years, see Edwards, Garonna, and Tödtling, Unions in Crisis; Brody, Workers in Industrial America; Collins, Politics of Economic Growth.

74. Kirshner, “Keynes, Capital Mobility”; Epstein and Ferguson, “Monetary Policy”; Greider, Secrets of the Temple.

75. United States, 1946 Extension of the Emergency Price Control, 127.

76. CED, Fiscal Policy. Also see United States, 1946 Extension of the Emergency Price Control.

77. United States, 1946 Extension of the Emergency Price Control; United States, Current Price Developments. About NAM’s history, see Waterhouse, Lobbying America; Phillips-Fein, Invisible Hands.

78. United States, Current Price Developments. The eight banks were National City Bank of New York, New York Life Insurance Co., American Security & Trust Co., First National Bank of Chicago, Bowery Savings Bank, New England Mutual Life Insurance Co., Burlington Savings Bank, and Mutual Life Insurance Co. of New York.

79. American Bankers Association, Cost of World Leadership, 69–70. For similar testimonies from large banks such as the Chase Manhattan Bank and the First National City Bank, see United States, 1968 Economic Report of the President; United States, Review of Balance of Payments Policies.

80. United States, 1969 Economic Report of the President, 934. See also CED, Fiscal and Monetary Policies.

81. National Association of Manufacturers (NAM), Can We Muddle Through?; CED, National Economy and the Vietnam War.

82. United States, 1970 Midyear Review of the State of the Economy, 49.

83. Ibid.; United States, 1970 Economic Report of the President.

84. United States, 1970 Economic Report of the President, 294–297.

85. Ibid; Economic Prospects and Policies; Acc. 1960, Series I, Box 3, Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America, Board of Directors meetings, June 19, 1970, and February 25–26, 1971, HML.

86. United States, Need for a More Balanced Policy; United States, 1970 Midyear Review of the State of the Economy.

87. Bergsten, American Multinationals, 11.

88. United States, Export Policy, 112.

89. While exporters favor a weak home currency, international investors, including FDI, prefer a strong home currency. See Frieden, “Invested Interests.”

90. Traditional exporters were indeterminate regarding the issue. James Collins, representing the American steel industry, testified that steel industry had “mixed emotions” about dollar depreciation. Rather than actively engaging in dollar politics, old industries—becoming increasingly protectionist—sought remedies in specific trade rules such as the escape clause and anti-dumping laws. United States, Decline of the Dollar, 58–66. For trade politics, see Chorev, Remaking U.S. Trade Policy.

91. NAM, Can We Muddle Through?

92. “GE Urges Carter To Step Up Voltage of Inflation Fight,” Wall Street Journal, April 26, 1979.

93. United States, Decline of the Dollar, 30–34.

94. “Ford Profit Fell 28.2% in Quarter,” New York Times, February 16, 1979.

95. Brenner, Economics of Global Turbulence, 112, 125.

96. Piore and Sabel, Second Industrial Divide; Herrigel, Manufacturing Possibilities.

97. Brenner, Economics of Global Turbulence, 166.

98. “UAW Rejected at GM Plant in Georgia, Fueling ‘Southern’ Issue in Bargaining,” Wall Street Journal, September 7, 1976.

99. “Initial Offers by GM, Ford Stress Ways To Curb Costs,” Wall Street Journal, July 28, 1976. For similar struggles at GE and Westinghouse, see “GE Plant Workers Choose Union,” Wall Street Journal, January 14, 1977; “Westinghouse Willing to Risk Strike Loss to Move Its Labor Costs in Line With GE’s,” Wall Street Journal, July 18, 1979.

100. Edwards and Podgursky, “Unraveling Accord,” 47; Phillips-Fein, Invisible Hands, Ch. 9; Waterhouse, Lobbying America, Ch. 3.

101. “Inflation Plan Criticized: Carter’s Wage-Price Policy Is Met With Doubt by Business and Labor Anti-Inflation Moves Encounter Skepticism Of Business and Labor,” Wall Street Journal, April 13, 1978.

102. “UAW Chief Quits Labor–Management Unit,” Washington Post, July 20, 1978.

103. Waterhouse, Lobbying America, 138–139.

104. United States, 1975 Economic Report of the President, 615; United States, Current Economic Situation; Biven, Jimmy Carter’s Economy.

105. United States, 1975 Economic Report of the President, 894; United States, 1976 Economic Report of the President; CED, Progress toward Recovery; CED, Fighting Inflation and Promoting Growth.

106. United States, Oversight on Economic Stabilization; United States Incomes Policy Legislation.

107. Acc. 1960, Series I, Box 3, Board of Directors meeting, February 20–21, 1975, and February 21–22, 1974; November 7–8, 1974, HML; United States, 1977 Economic Report: Hearings.

108. Acc. 1411, Series 13, Box 245, Board of Directors meeting, February 15–16, 1977, HML.

109. United States, 1976 Economic Report of the President; United States, 1977 Economic Report of the President.

110. Acc. 2345, Box 137, “Policy Declaration of the National Foreign Trade Council,” 1977, HML.

111. United States, 1978 Economic Report of the President, 571–572.

112. “Inflation Plan Criticized,” Wall Street Journal. See also United States, 1978 Economic Report of the President.

113. Acc. 1411, Series 13, Box 245, Board of Directors meeting, October, 20–21,1978, HML.

114. Acc. 1960, Series I, Box 3, Board of Directors meeting, June 23, 1978, HML; United States, President’s New Anti-Inflation Program.

115. Johnson, Government of Money, 164, 177; United States, 1979 Economic Report of the President.

116. United States, Conduct of Monetary Policy. For economists’ diverse views, see United States, Stagflation; United States 1979 Economic Report of the President.

117. “Mr. Miller’s Gamble,” Wall Street Journal, April 24, 1979; “A Conservative Choice: Volcker Expected to Calm Monetary Fear Abroad, But Some See Political Conflict on Domestic Policy,” New York Times, July 26, 1979.

118. Johnson, Government of Money, 27; Waterhouse, Lobbying America, 137.

119. George Hagedorn, “Reflections on the War against Inflation,” Enterprise, March 1979. See also Enterprise, February, May, June, and December 1979. Enterprise was the journal of the National Association of Manufacturers.

120. Acc. 1960, Series IV, Publications, Washington Report, January 22, 1979; see also Washington Report, December 11,1978, February 5, 1979; Acc. 1960, Series I, Box 3, Board of Directors meeting, November 15, 1979, HML. Washington Report was the journal of U.S. Chamber.

121. United States, 1979 Economic Report of the President, 17.

122. Acc. 2345, Box 137, “Policy Declaration of the National Foreign Trade Council,” 1979, HML.

123. United States, 1979 Economic Report of the President; United States, Impact of Inflation.

124. United States, 1979 Economic Report of the President.

125. United States, Stagflation; United States, Impact of Inflation; United States, Federal Reserve’s First Monetary Policy.

126. Biven, Jimmy Carter’s Economy, 143–144. Biven notes, “It may be the only time in the history of the United States that an administration has pressed the central bank to move into a more restrained posture” (143).

127. “Monetary Policy Left Unchanged By Fed Panel: But 4 Members at Meeting In March Had Advocated More Restrictive Moves,” Wall Street Journal, April 23, 1979.

128. “Balm for Business: Volcker’s Nomination As Chairman of the Fed Is Being Widely Hailed Cheers for the Conservative,” Wall Street Journal, July 26, 1979; “A Conservative Choice,” New York Times, July 26, 1979.

129. Greider, Secrets of the Temple, 121; Johnson, Government of Money, 177; Karier, Great Experiments, 43.

130. George Hagedorn, “Prognosis for the 1980s: Curing Inflation Will Be Slow and Painful,” Enterprise, December 1979.

131. Karier, Great Experiments, 43; “Support Mr. Volcker,” Wall Street Journal, October 8, 1979.

132. Johnson, Government of Money, 177.

133. Volcker and Gyohten, Changing Fortunes, 176.

134. The Fed’s actions occasionally drew criticism from the Carter and Reagan administrations and Congress, but no one intervened. Volcker and Gyohten, Changing Fortunes, 176; Krippner, Capitalizing on Crisis, 119; Bailey and Schonhardt-Bailey, “Volcker Revolution of 1979.”

135. CED, Fighting Inflation. See also United States, 1980 Economic Report of the President.

136. United States, Regional Impact of an Economic Slowdown, 11.

137. Enterprise, May 1980; see also Enterprise, February, June, and September 1980. Acc. 1411, Series 13, Box 246, Board of Directors meetings, January 17–19, 1980, HML.

138. Enterprise, March 1981. See also Acc. 1411, Series 13, Box 246, Board of Directors meetings, January 23–24, 1981, HML.

139. United States, 1981 Economic Report of the President. See also United States, 1980 Economic Report of the President.

140. Acc. 1411, Series 13, Box 246, “Fiscal policy position as adopted by the NAM Board of Directors,” February 5, 1982 HML

141. United States, 1980 Economic Report of the President, 3.

142. United States, 1981 Economic Report of the President.

143. Conti-Brown, Power and Independence, 189.

144. Ruben, “Industrial Relations.”

145. Conti-Brown, Power and Independence; Duménil and Lévy, Capital Resurgent; Krippner, Capitalizing on Crisis; Morgan, “Monetary Metamorphosis.”

146. Duménil and Lévy, “Costs and Benefits,” 604.

147. See Jones, “Globalization.”

148. Waterhouse, Lobbying America; Duménil and Lévy, “Costs and Benefits.”

149. Indeed, some researchers have suggested diverging interests between industry and finance toward macroeconomic policies. See Epstein, “Domestic Stagflation,” 145–146; Martin, Shifting the Burden, 36; Palley, “Deflationary Monetary Policy,” 165.

150. Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance; Versluysen, Political Economy; Schenk, “Origins of the Eurodollar”; Battilossi and Cassis, European Banks; Burn, Re-Emergence of Global Finance.

151. Helleiner, States and the Reemergence of Global Finance; Strange, Casino Capitalism; Karier, Great Experiments.

152. See Smith, American Business and Political Power.

153. Biven, Jimmy Carter’s Economy, 247.

References

Bibliography of Works Cited

American Bankers Association. The Cost of World Leadership: An Analysis of the United States Balance-of-Payments Problem. New York: American Bankers Association, 1968.Google Scholar
Arrighi, Giovanni. The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins of Our Times. 2nd ed. London: Verso, 2010.Google Scholar
Bank of England. Quarterly Bulletin. London: Bank of England, 1964.Google Scholar
Battilossi, Stefano, and Cassis, Youssef, eds. European Banks and the American Challenge: Competition and Cooperation in International Banking under Bretton Woods. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Bergsten, C. Fred. American Multinationals and American Interests. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1978.Google Scholar
Bergsten, C. Fred, and Halm, George Nikolaus. Approaches to Greater Flexibility of Exchange Rates: The Bürgenstock Papers. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1970.Google Scholar
Biven, W. Carl. Jimmy Carter’s Economy: Policy in an Age of Limits. The Luther Hartwell Hodges Series on Business, Society, and the State. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Blyth, Mark. Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Blyth, Mark. Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brenner, Robert. The Economics of Global Turbulence: The Advanced Capitalist Economies from Long Boom to Long Downturn, 1945–2005. London: Verso, 2006.Google Scholar
Brody, David. Workers in Industrial America: Essays on the Twentieth Century Struggle. 2nd ed. New York: Oxford University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Bryant, Ralph C. International Financial Intermediation. Studies in International Economics. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1987.Google Scholar
Burn, Gary. The Re-Emergence of Global Finance. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America. A Program for Sustaining Employment. Report of Committee on Economic Policy. 2nd ed. Washington, DC: Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America, 1947.Google Scholar
Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America. International Financial Problems, 1944.Google Scholar
Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America. Post-War Readjustments: Bulletin. Washington, DC: Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America, 1943.Google Scholar
Chorev, Nitsan. Remaking U.S. Trade Policy: From Protectionism to Globalization. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, Robert M. More: The Politics of Economic Growth in Postwar America. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. The Bretton Woods Proposals, a Statement on National Policy. New York: CED, 1945.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. CED Digest. New York: CED, 1947.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Fighting Inflation and Promoting Growth: A Statement on National Policy. New York: CED, 1976.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Fighting Inflation and Rebuilding a Sound Economy, a Statement. New York: CED, 1980.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Fiscal and Monetary Policies for Steady Economic Growth; a Statement on National Policy by the Research and Policy Committee of the Committee for Economic Development. New York: CED, 1969.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Fiscal Policy to Fight Inflation, a Statement on National Policy. New York: CED, 1946.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Greater Economic Stability. New York: CED, 1948.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Progress toward Recovery of the Economy: CED Symposium. New York: CED, 1975.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Report of Activities. New York: CED, 1971–1972.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Strengthening the World Monetary System. New York: CED, 1973.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Taxes and the Budget, a Program for Prosperity in a Free Economy. New York: CED, 1947.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. The Dollar and the World Monetary System. New York: CED, 1966.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. The National Economy and the Vietnam War; a Statement on National Policy by the Research and Policy Committee of the Committee for Economic Development. New York: CED, 1968.Google Scholar
Committee of Twenty. International Monetary Reform: Documents of the Committee of Twenty. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1974.Google Scholar
Conti-Brown, Peter. The Power and Independence of the Federal Reserve. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conybeare, John A. C. United States Foreign Economic Policy and the International Capital Markets: The Case of Capital Export Countries, 1963–1974. New York: Garland Publishing, 1988.Google Scholar
Dam, Kenneth W. The Rules of the Game: Reform and Evolution in the International Monetary System. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Davis, Gerald F. Managed by the Markets: How Finance Reshaped America. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.Google Scholar
De Vries, Margaret Garritsen. The International Monetary Fund, 1972–1978: Cooperation on Trial. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1985.Google Scholar
Duménil, Gérard, and Lévy, Dominique. Capital Resurgent: Roots of the Neoliberal Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry J. Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System. 2nd ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald A. Financialization and the World Economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2005.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. The Architecture of Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First-Century Capitalist Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Gowa, Joanne S. Closing the Gold Window: Domestic Politics and the End of Bretton Woods. Cornell Studies in Political Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Gowan, Peter. The Global Gamble: Washington’s Faustian Bid for World Dominance. London: Verso, 1999.Google Scholar
Greider, William. Secrets of the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country. New York: Simon and Schuster, 1987.Google Scholar
Hawley, James P. Dollars & Borders: U.S. Government Attempts to Restrict Capital Flows, 1960–1980. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1987.Google Scholar
Helleiner, Eric. States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From Bretton Woods to the 1990s. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Herrigel, Gary. Manufacturing Possibilities Creative Action and Industrial Recomposition in the United States, Germany, and Japan. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horsefield, J. Keith, ed. The International Monetary Fund, 1945–1965: Twenty Years of International Monetary Cooperation. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1969.Google Scholar
Johnson, Peter A. The Government of Money: Monetarism in Germany and the United States. Cornell Studies in Political Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Johnston, R. B. The Economics of the Euro-Market: History, Theory, and Policy. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Kapstein, Ethan B. Governing the Global Economy: International Finance and the State. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Karier, Thomas Mark. Great Experiments in American Economic Policy: From Kennedy to Reagan. Westport, CT: Praeger, 1997.Google Scholar
Kelly de Escobar, Janet. Bankers and Borders: The Case of American Banks in Britain. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company, 1977.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles Poor. American Business Abroad; Six Lectures on Direct Investment. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Krippner, Greta R. Capitalizing on Crisis: The Political Origins of the Rise of Finance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Magdoff, Harry, and Sweezy, Paul M.. Stagnation and the Financial Explosion. New York: Monthly Review Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Martin, Cathie Jo. Shifting the Burden: The Struggle over Growth and Corporate Taxation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Mendelsohn, Stefan. Money on the Move: The Modern International Capital Market. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1980.Google Scholar
National Association of Manufacturers. Can We Muddle Through? Dollars, Gold and the Payments Problem. New York: NAM, 1968.Google Scholar
National Industrial Conference Board. Managing International Business. New York: National Industrial Conference Board, 1968 and 1969.Google Scholar
Odell, John S. U.S. International Monetary Policy: Markets, Power, and Ideas as Sources of Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Sullivan, Mary. Contests for Corporate Control: Corporate Governance and Economic Performance in the United States and Germany. New York: Oxford University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Phillips-Fein, Kim. Invisible Hands: The Making of the Conservative Movement from the New Deal to Reagan. New York: W. W. Norton & Company, 2009.Google Scholar
Piore, Michael J., and Sabel, Charles F.. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books, 1984.Google Scholar
Schriftgiesser, Karl. Business Comes of Age; the Story of the Committee for Economic Development and Its Impact upon the Economic Policies of the United States, 1942–1960. New York: Harper, 1960.Google Scholar
Smith, Mark A. American Business and Political Power: Public Opinion, Elections, and Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strange, Susan. Casino Capitalism. Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1986.Google Scholar
Toniolo, Gianni. Central Bank Cooperation at the Bank for International Settlements, 1930–1973. Studies in Macroeconomic History. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005.Google Scholar
United Nations. Multinational Corporations in World Development. New York: United Nations, 1973.Google Scholar
United Nations Centre on Transnational Corporations. Salient Features and Trends in Foreign Direct Investment. New York: United Nations, 1983.Google Scholar
Versluysen, Eugene. The Political Economy of International Finance. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Volcker, Paul A., and Gyohten, Toyoo. Changing Fortunes: The World’s Money and the Threat to American Leadership. New York: Times Books, 1992.Google Scholar
Waterhouse, Benjamin C. Lobbying America: The Politics of Business from Nixon to NAFTA. Politics and Society in Twentieth-Century America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Wilkins, Mira. The Maturing of Multinational Enterprise: American Business Abroad from 1914 to 1970. Harvard Studies in Business History. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailey, Andrew, and Schonhardt-Bailey, Cheryl. “Does Deliberation Matter in FOMC Monetary Policymaking? The Volcker Revolution of 1979.” Political Analysis 16 (4): 404427.Google Scholar
Battilossi, Stefano. “Financial Innovation and the Golden Ages of International Banking: 1890–81.” Financial History Review 7, no. 2 (2000): 141175.Google Scholar
Battilossi, Stefano. “Banking with Multinationals: British Clearing Banks and the Euromarkets’ Challenge, 1958–1976.” In European Banks and the American Challenge: Competition and Cooperation in International Banking under Bretton Woods, edited by Battilossi, Stefano and Cassis, Youssef, 103134. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Ceyhun, Fikret. “Multinational Corporations and the U.S. Economic Crisis: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.” Review of Radical Political Economics 29, no. 4 (1997): 4291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duménil, Gérard, and Lévy, Dominique. “Costs and Benefits of Neoliberalism.” Review of International Political Economy 8, no. 4 (December 1, 2001): 578607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, Richard, and Podgursky, Michael. “The Unraveling Accord: American Unions in Crisis.” In Unions in Crisis and Beyond: Perspectives from Six Countries, edited by Edwards, Richard, Garonna, P., and Tödtling, Franz, 1460. Dover, MA: Auburn House Publishing Company, 1986.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald. “Domestic Stagflation and Monetary Policy.” In The Hidden Election: Politics and Economics in the 1980 Presidential Campaign, edited by Ferguson, Thomas and Rogers, Joel, 141195. New York: Pantheon Books, 1981.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald, and Ferguson, Thomas. “Monetary Policy, Loan Liquidation, and Industrial Conflict: The Federal Reserve and the Open Market Operations of 1932.” Journal of Economic History 44, no. 4 (1984): 957983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, Jeffry A. “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance.” International Organization 45, no. 4 (1991): 425451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodman, J. B., and Pauly, L. W.. “The Obsolescence of Capital Controls—Economic Management in an Age of Global Markets.” World Politics 46, no. 1 (1993): 5082.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guttmann, Robert. “Money and Credit in Regulation Theory.” In Regulation Theory: The State of the Art, edited by Boyer, Robert and Saillard, Yves, 5763. London: Routledge, 2002.Google Scholar
Jones, Geoffrey. “Multinationals from the 1930s to the 1980s.” In Leviathans: Multinational Corporations and the New Global History, edited by Chandler, Alfred D. and Mazlish, Bruce, 81104. Cambridge: Cambridge, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Geoffrey. “Globalization.” In The Oxford Handbook of Business History, edited by Jones, Geoffrey and Zeitlin, Jonathan, 141168. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirshner, Jonathan. “Keynes, Capital Mobility and the Crisis of Embedded Liberalism.” Review of International Political Economy 6, no. 3 (1999): 313337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazonick, William, and O’Sullivan, Mary. “Maximizing Shareholder Value: A New Ideology for Corporate Governance.” Economy and Society 29, no. 1 (2000): 1335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Major, Aaron. “The Fall and Rise of Financial Capital.” Review of International Political Economy 15, no. 5 (2008): 800825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Iwan W. “Monetary Metamorphosis: The Volcker Fed and Inflation.” Journal of Policy History 24, no. 4 (2012): 545571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palley, Thomas. “The Institutionalization of Deflationary Monetary Policy.” In Money, Financial Institutions, and Macroeconomics, edited by Cohen, Avi Jonathan, Hagemann, Harald, and Smithin, John N., 157174. Recent Economic Thought Series. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1997.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruben, George. “Industrial Relations in 1980 Influenced by Inflation and Recession.” Monthly Labor Review 104, no. 1 (1981): 1520.Google Scholar
Schenk, Catherine R. “International Financial Centers, 1958–1971.” In European Banks and the American Challenge: Competition and Cooperation in International Banking under Bretton Woods, edited by Battilossi, Stefano and Cassis, Youssef, 74102. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Schenk, Catherine R. “The Origins of the Eurodollar Market in London: 1955–1963.” Explorations in Economic History 35, no. 2 (1998): 221238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sylla, Richard. “United States Banks and Europe: Strategy and Attitudes.” In European Banks and the American Challenge: Competition and Cooperation in International Banking under Bretton Woods, edited by Battilossi, Stefano and Cassis, Youssef, 5373. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
van der Zwan, Natascha. “Making Sense of Financialization.” Socio-Economic Review 12, no. 1 (2014): 99129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Economic Report of the President Transmitted to the Congress , January 1973. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1973.Google Scholar
Foreign Relations of the United States. International Monetary and Trade Policy, edited by Duncan, Evan, Patterson, David S., and Yee, Carolyn, Vol. VIII, 19641968. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1998.Google Scholar
United States. 1946 Extension of the Emergency Price Control and Stabilization Acts of 1942, as Amended. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency, House of Representatives, Seventy-Ninth Congress, Second Session, on H.R. 5270, a Bill to Amend the Emergency Price Control Act of 1942, as Amended, and the Stabilization Act of 1942, as Amended, and for Other Purposes. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1946.Google Scholar
United States. A Foreign Economic Policy for the 1970s. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1970.Google Scholar
United States. A Review of Balance of Payments Policies. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, First Session. January 13, 14, and 15, 1969. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969.Google Scholar
United States. Balance of Payments, 1965. Hearings, Eighty-Ninth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1965.Google Scholar
United States. Bretton Woods Agreements Act. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency, United States Senate, Seventy-Ninth Congress, First Session, on H. R. 2211, a Bill to Provide for the Participation of the United States in the International Monetary Fund and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1945.Google Scholar
United States. Conduct of Monetary Policy, pursuant to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, P.L. 95-523: Hearings before the Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs, House of Representatives, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session, February 21 and 22, 1979. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. Current Economic Situation and Outlook: Hearing before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, Ninety-Fourth Congress, Second Session, September 22, 1976. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976.Google Scholar
United States. Current Price Developments and the Problem of Economic Stabilization. Hearings before the Joint Committee on the Economic Report, Congress of the United States, Eightieth Congress, First Session, pursuant to Sec. 5 (A) of Public Law 304, 79th Congress. Pt. 1. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1947.Google Scholar
United States. Economic Prospects and Policies. Hearings, Ninety-Second Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1971.Google Scholar
United States. Export Policy: Hearing before the Subcommittee on International Finance of the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session, February 6, 1978. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
United States. Federal Reserve’s First Monetary Policy Report for 1979: Hearing before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session… February 20 and 23, 1979. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. Foreign Direct Investment Controls. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, First Session on House Concurrent Resolutions 85 and 86. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969.Google Scholar
United States. Impact of Inflation on the Economy: Hearings before the Task Force on Inflation of the Committee on the Budget, House of Representatives, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. Incomes Policy Legislation, 1975: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Economic Stabilization of the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing, House of Representatives, Ninety-Fourth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975.Google Scholar
United States. Inflation: The Need for a More Balanced Policy Mix. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, Second Session, on S. Res. 357, Expressing the Sense of the Senate on Inflation. March 10, 11, and 12, 1970. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1970.Google Scholar
United States. January 1965 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Eighty-Ninth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1965.Google Scholar
United States. Oversight on Economic Stabilization: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Production and Stabilization of the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, Ninety-Third Congress, Second Session, on Renewal and Suggested Modifications of the Economic Stabilization Act Which Expires on April 30, 1974. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1974.Google Scholar
United States. President’s 1961 Tax Recommendations: Hearings before the Committee on Ways and Means, House of Representatives, Eighty-Seventh Congress, First Session, on the Tax Recommendations of the President Contained in His Message Transmitted to the Congress, April 20, 1961. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1961.Google Scholar
United States. Regional Impact of an Economic Slowdown, the Michigan Picture: Hearings before the Committee on the Budget, United States Senate, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session, July 19, 1979—Detroit, Mich., August 30, 1979–Flint, Mich. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1980.Google Scholar
United States. Stagflation: Hearings before the Special Study on Economic Change of the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session, April 30, and May 7 and 9, 1979. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. The 1968 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninetieth Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1968.Google Scholar
United States. The 1969 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969.Google Scholar
United States. The 1970 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office 1970.Google Scholar
United States. The 1970 Midyear Review of the State of the Economy. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office 1970.Google Scholar
United States. The 1974 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Third Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1974.Google Scholar
United States. The 1975 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Fourth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975.Google Scholar
United States. The 1976 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Fourth Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976.Google Scholar
United States. The 1977 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Fifth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977.Google Scholar
United States. The 1978 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
United States. The 1979 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. The 1980 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Seventh Congress. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. The 1981 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Seventh Congress, First Session. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1981.Google Scholar
United States. The Decline of the Dollar: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Foreign Economic Policy of the Committee on Foreign Relations, United States Senate, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session, February 22, June 22, and July 24, 1978. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
United States. The President’s New Anti-Inflation Program: Hearing before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session… November 3, 1978. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
United States Department of Commerce. Foreign Direct Investment Program. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1972 and 1974.Google Scholar
United States Tariff Commission. Implications of Multinational Firms for World Trade and Investment and for U.S. Trade and Labor; Report to the Committee on Finance of the United States Senate and Its Subcommittee on International Trade on Investigation No. 332–69, under Section 332 of the Tariff Act of 1930. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1973.Google Scholar
Enterprise (journal of National Association of Manufacturers)Google Scholar
NAM Reports (journal of National Association of Manufacturers)Google Scholar
New York TimesGoogle Scholar
Wall Street JournalGoogle Scholar
Washington PostGoogle Scholar
Washington Report (journal of U.S. Chamber of Commerce)Google Scholar
World Financial Markets (journal of Morgan Guaranty Trust Company of New York)Google Scholar
Bank for International Settlement. Annual Reports, 1931–1936. http://www.bis.org/publ/arpdf/archive/Google Scholar
Brimmer, Andrew. “Commercial Bank Lending Abroad and the U.S. Balance of Payments.” Speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, March 16, 1972. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/scribd/?item_id=10406&filepath=/files/docs/historical/federal%20reserve%20history/bog_members_statements/brimmer_19720316.pdfGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Gross Domestic Product, http://www.bea.gov/national/Index.htmGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Price Index, http://www.bls.gov/cpi/tables.htmGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Unemployment Rate, https://data.bls.gov/timeseries/LNS14000000Google Scholar
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. Values and Shares of Merchandise Exports and Imports, Annual, 1948–2012, http://unctadstat.unctad.org/wds/TableViewer/tableView.aspx?ReportId=101Google Scholar
Hagley Museum and Library (HML), Wilmington, DE.Google Scholar
American Bankers Association. The Cost of World Leadership: An Analysis of the United States Balance-of-Payments Problem. New York: American Bankers Association, 1968.Google Scholar
Arrighi, Giovanni. The Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power, and the Origins of Our Times. 2nd ed. London: Verso, 2010.Google Scholar
Bank of England. Quarterly Bulletin. London: Bank of England, 1964.Google Scholar
Battilossi, Stefano, and Cassis, Youssef, eds. European Banks and the American Challenge: Competition and Cooperation in International Banking under Bretton Woods. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Bergsten, C. Fred. American Multinationals and American Interests. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1978.Google Scholar
Bergsten, C. Fred, and Halm, George Nikolaus. Approaches to Greater Flexibility of Exchange Rates: The Bürgenstock Papers. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1970.Google Scholar
Biven, W. Carl. Jimmy Carter’s Economy: Policy in an Age of Limits. The Luther Hartwell Hodges Series on Business, Society, and the State. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Blyth, Mark. Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Blyth, Mark. Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brenner, Robert. The Economics of Global Turbulence: The Advanced Capitalist Economies from Long Boom to Long Downturn, 1945–2005. London: Verso, 2006.Google Scholar
Brody, David. Workers in Industrial America: Essays on the Twentieth Century Struggle. 2nd ed. New York: Oxford University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Bryant, Ralph C. International Financial Intermediation. Studies in International Economics. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1987.Google Scholar
Burn, Gary. The Re-Emergence of Global Finance. Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave Macmillan, 2006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America. A Program for Sustaining Employment. Report of Committee on Economic Policy. 2nd ed. Washington, DC: Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America, 1947.Google Scholar
Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America. International Financial Problems, 1944.Google Scholar
Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America. Post-War Readjustments: Bulletin. Washington, DC: Chamber of Commerce of the United States of America, 1943.Google Scholar
Chorev, Nitsan. Remaking U.S. Trade Policy: From Protectionism to Globalization. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, Robert M. More: The Politics of Economic Growth in Postwar America. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. The Bretton Woods Proposals, a Statement on National Policy. New York: CED, 1945.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. CED Digest. New York: CED, 1947.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Fighting Inflation and Promoting Growth: A Statement on National Policy. New York: CED, 1976.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Fighting Inflation and Rebuilding a Sound Economy, a Statement. New York: CED, 1980.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Fiscal and Monetary Policies for Steady Economic Growth; a Statement on National Policy by the Research and Policy Committee of the Committee for Economic Development. New York: CED, 1969.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Fiscal Policy to Fight Inflation, a Statement on National Policy. New York: CED, 1946.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Greater Economic Stability. New York: CED, 1948.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Progress toward Recovery of the Economy: CED Symposium. New York: CED, 1975.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Report of Activities. New York: CED, 1971–1972.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Strengthening the World Monetary System. New York: CED, 1973.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. Taxes and the Budget, a Program for Prosperity in a Free Economy. New York: CED, 1947.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. The Dollar and the World Monetary System. New York: CED, 1966.Google Scholar
Committee for Economic Development. The National Economy and the Vietnam War; a Statement on National Policy by the Research and Policy Committee of the Committee for Economic Development. New York: CED, 1968.Google Scholar
Committee of Twenty. International Monetary Reform: Documents of the Committee of Twenty. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1974.Google Scholar
Conti-Brown, Peter. The Power and Independence of the Federal Reserve. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conybeare, John A. C. United States Foreign Economic Policy and the International Capital Markets: The Case of Capital Export Countries, 1963–1974. New York: Garland Publishing, 1988.Google Scholar
Dam, Kenneth W. The Rules of the Game: Reform and Evolution in the International Monetary System. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Davis, Gerald F. Managed by the Markets: How Finance Reshaped America. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2009.Google Scholar
De Vries, Margaret Garritsen. The International Monetary Fund, 1972–1978: Cooperation on Trial. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1985.Google Scholar
Duménil, Gérard, and Lévy, Dominique. Capital Resurgent: Roots of the Neoliberal Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry J. Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System. 2nd ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald A. Financialization and the World Economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2005.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. The Architecture of Markets: An Economic Sociology of Twenty-First-Century Capitalist Societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Gowa, Joanne S. Closing the Gold Window: Domestic Politics and the End of Bretton Woods. Cornell Studies in Political Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Gowan, Peter. The Global Gamble: Washington’s Faustian Bid for World Dominance. London: Verso, 1999.Google Scholar
Greider, William. Secrets of the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country. New York: Simon and Schuster, 1987.Google Scholar
Hawley, James P. Dollars & Borders: U.S. Government Attempts to Restrict Capital Flows, 1960–1980. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1987.Google Scholar
Helleiner, Eric. States and the Reemergence of Global Finance: From Bretton Woods to the 1990s. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Herrigel, Gary. Manufacturing Possibilities Creative Action and Industrial Recomposition in the United States, Germany, and Japan. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2010.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horsefield, J. Keith, ed. The International Monetary Fund, 1945–1965: Twenty Years of International Monetary Cooperation. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 1969.Google Scholar
Johnson, Peter A. The Government of Money: Monetarism in Germany and the United States. Cornell Studies in Political Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Johnston, R. B. The Economics of the Euro-Market: History, Theory, and Policy. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Kapstein, Ethan B. Governing the Global Economy: International Finance and the State. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Karier, Thomas Mark. Great Experiments in American Economic Policy: From Kennedy to Reagan. Westport, CT: Praeger, 1997.Google Scholar
Kelly de Escobar, Janet. Bankers and Borders: The Case of American Banks in Britain. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company, 1977.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles Poor. American Business Abroad; Six Lectures on Direct Investment. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Krippner, Greta R. Capitalizing on Crisis: The Political Origins of the Rise of Finance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Magdoff, Harry, and Sweezy, Paul M.. Stagnation and the Financial Explosion. New York: Monthly Review Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Martin, Cathie Jo. Shifting the Burden: The Struggle over Growth and Corporate Taxation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991.Google Scholar
Mendelsohn, Stefan. Money on the Move: The Modern International Capital Market. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1980.Google Scholar
National Association of Manufacturers. Can We Muddle Through? Dollars, Gold and the Payments Problem. New York: NAM, 1968.Google Scholar
National Industrial Conference Board. Managing International Business. New York: National Industrial Conference Board, 1968 and 1969.Google Scholar
Odell, John S. U.S. International Monetary Policy: Markets, Power, and Ideas as Sources of Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Sullivan, Mary. Contests for Corporate Control: Corporate Governance and Economic Performance in the United States and Germany. New York: Oxford University Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Phillips-Fein, Kim. Invisible Hands: The Making of the Conservative Movement from the New Deal to Reagan. New York: W. W. Norton & Company, 2009.Google Scholar
Piore, Michael J., and Sabel, Charles F.. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books, 1984.Google Scholar
Schriftgiesser, Karl. Business Comes of Age; the Story of the Committee for Economic Development and Its Impact upon the Economic Policies of the United States, 1942–1960. New York: Harper, 1960.Google Scholar
Smith, Mark A. American Business and Political Power: Public Opinion, Elections, and Democracy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strange, Susan. Casino Capitalism. Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 1986.Google Scholar
Toniolo, Gianni. Central Bank Cooperation at the Bank for International Settlements, 1930–1973. Studies in Macroeconomic History. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005.Google Scholar
United Nations. Multinational Corporations in World Development. New York: United Nations, 1973.Google Scholar
United Nations Centre on Transnational Corporations. Salient Features and Trends in Foreign Direct Investment. New York: United Nations, 1983.Google Scholar
Versluysen, Eugene. The Political Economy of International Finance. New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Volcker, Paul A., and Gyohten, Toyoo. Changing Fortunes: The World’s Money and the Threat to American Leadership. New York: Times Books, 1992.Google Scholar
Waterhouse, Benjamin C. Lobbying America: The Politics of Business from Nixon to NAFTA. Politics and Society in Twentieth-Century America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Wilkins, Mira. The Maturing of Multinational Enterprise: American Business Abroad from 1914 to 1970. Harvard Studies in Business History. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailey, Andrew, and Schonhardt-Bailey, Cheryl. “Does Deliberation Matter in FOMC Monetary Policymaking? The Volcker Revolution of 1979.” Political Analysis 16 (4): 404427.Google Scholar
Battilossi, Stefano. “Financial Innovation and the Golden Ages of International Banking: 1890–81.” Financial History Review 7, no. 2 (2000): 141175.Google Scholar
Battilossi, Stefano. “Banking with Multinationals: British Clearing Banks and the Euromarkets’ Challenge, 1958–1976.” In European Banks and the American Challenge: Competition and Cooperation in International Banking under Bretton Woods, edited by Battilossi, Stefano and Cassis, Youssef, 103134. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Ceyhun, Fikret. “Multinational Corporations and the U.S. Economic Crisis: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.” Review of Radical Political Economics 29, no. 4 (1997): 4291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duménil, Gérard, and Lévy, Dominique. “Costs and Benefits of Neoliberalism.” Review of International Political Economy 8, no. 4 (December 1, 2001): 578607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, Richard, and Podgursky, Michael. “The Unraveling Accord: American Unions in Crisis.” In Unions in Crisis and Beyond: Perspectives from Six Countries, edited by Edwards, Richard, Garonna, P., and Tödtling, Franz, 1460. Dover, MA: Auburn House Publishing Company, 1986.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald. “Domestic Stagflation and Monetary Policy.” In The Hidden Election: Politics and Economics in the 1980 Presidential Campaign, edited by Ferguson, Thomas and Rogers, Joel, 141195. New York: Pantheon Books, 1981.Google Scholar
Epstein, Gerald, and Ferguson, Thomas. “Monetary Policy, Loan Liquidation, and Industrial Conflict: The Federal Reserve and the Open Market Operations of 1932.” Journal of Economic History 44, no. 4 (1984): 957983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, Jeffry A. “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance.” International Organization 45, no. 4 (1991): 425451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodman, J. B., and Pauly, L. W.. “The Obsolescence of Capital Controls—Economic Management in an Age of Global Markets.” World Politics 46, no. 1 (1993): 5082.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guttmann, Robert. “Money and Credit in Regulation Theory.” In Regulation Theory: The State of the Art, edited by Boyer, Robert and Saillard, Yves, 5763. London: Routledge, 2002.Google Scholar
Jones, Geoffrey. “Multinationals from the 1930s to the 1980s.” In Leviathans: Multinational Corporations and the New Global History, edited by Chandler, Alfred D. and Mazlish, Bruce, 81104. Cambridge: Cambridge, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Geoffrey. “Globalization.” In The Oxford Handbook of Business History, edited by Jones, Geoffrey and Zeitlin, Jonathan, 141168. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirshner, Jonathan. “Keynes, Capital Mobility and the Crisis of Embedded Liberalism.” Review of International Political Economy 6, no. 3 (1999): 313337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazonick, William, and O’Sullivan, Mary. “Maximizing Shareholder Value: A New Ideology for Corporate Governance.” Economy and Society 29, no. 1 (2000): 1335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Major, Aaron. “The Fall and Rise of Financial Capital.” Review of International Political Economy 15, no. 5 (2008): 800825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Iwan W. “Monetary Metamorphosis: The Volcker Fed and Inflation.” Journal of Policy History 24, no. 4 (2012): 545571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palley, Thomas. “The Institutionalization of Deflationary Monetary Policy.” In Money, Financial Institutions, and Macroeconomics, edited by Cohen, Avi Jonathan, Hagemann, Harald, and Smithin, John N., 157174. Recent Economic Thought Series. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1997.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruben, George. “Industrial Relations in 1980 Influenced by Inflation and Recession.” Monthly Labor Review 104, no. 1 (1981): 1520.Google Scholar
Schenk, Catherine R. “International Financial Centers, 1958–1971.” In European Banks and the American Challenge: Competition and Cooperation in International Banking under Bretton Woods, edited by Battilossi, Stefano and Cassis, Youssef, 74102. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Schenk, Catherine R. “The Origins of the Eurodollar Market in London: 1955–1963.” Explorations in Economic History 35, no. 2 (1998): 221238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sylla, Richard. “United States Banks and Europe: Strategy and Attitudes.” In European Banks and the American Challenge: Competition and Cooperation in International Banking under Bretton Woods, edited by Battilossi, Stefano and Cassis, Youssef, 5373. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
van der Zwan, Natascha. “Making Sense of Financialization.” Socio-Economic Review 12, no. 1 (2014): 99129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Economic Report of the President Transmitted to the Congress , January 1973. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1973.Google Scholar
Foreign Relations of the United States. International Monetary and Trade Policy, edited by Duncan, Evan, Patterson, David S., and Yee, Carolyn, Vol. VIII, 19641968. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1998.Google Scholar
United States. 1946 Extension of the Emergency Price Control and Stabilization Acts of 1942, as Amended. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency, House of Representatives, Seventy-Ninth Congress, Second Session, on H.R. 5270, a Bill to Amend the Emergency Price Control Act of 1942, as Amended, and the Stabilization Act of 1942, as Amended, and for Other Purposes. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1946.Google Scholar
United States. A Foreign Economic Policy for the 1970s. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1970.Google Scholar
United States. A Review of Balance of Payments Policies. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, First Session. January 13, 14, and 15, 1969. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969.Google Scholar
United States. Balance of Payments, 1965. Hearings, Eighty-Ninth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1965.Google Scholar
United States. Bretton Woods Agreements Act. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency, United States Senate, Seventy-Ninth Congress, First Session, on H. R. 2211, a Bill to Provide for the Participation of the United States in the International Monetary Fund and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1945.Google Scholar
United States. Conduct of Monetary Policy, pursuant to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, P.L. 95-523: Hearings before the Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs, House of Representatives, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session, February 21 and 22, 1979. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. Current Economic Situation and Outlook: Hearing before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, Ninety-Fourth Congress, Second Session, September 22, 1976. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976.Google Scholar
United States. Current Price Developments and the Problem of Economic Stabilization. Hearings before the Joint Committee on the Economic Report, Congress of the United States, Eightieth Congress, First Session, pursuant to Sec. 5 (A) of Public Law 304, 79th Congress. Pt. 1. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1947.Google Scholar
United States. Economic Prospects and Policies. Hearings, Ninety-Second Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1971.Google Scholar
United States. Export Policy: Hearing before the Subcommittee on International Finance of the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session, February 6, 1978. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
United States. Federal Reserve’s First Monetary Policy Report for 1979: Hearing before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session… February 20 and 23, 1979. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. Foreign Direct Investment Controls. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, First Session on House Concurrent Resolutions 85 and 86. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969.Google Scholar
United States. Impact of Inflation on the Economy: Hearings before the Task Force on Inflation of the Committee on the Budget, House of Representatives, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. Incomes Policy Legislation, 1975: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Economic Stabilization of the Committee on Banking, Currency and Housing, House of Representatives, Ninety-Fourth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975.Google Scholar
United States. Inflation: The Need for a More Balanced Policy Mix. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, Second Session, on S. Res. 357, Expressing the Sense of the Senate on Inflation. March 10, 11, and 12, 1970. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1970.Google Scholar
United States. January 1965 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Eighty-Ninth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1965.Google Scholar
United States. Oversight on Economic Stabilization: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Production and Stabilization of the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, Ninety-Third Congress, Second Session, on Renewal and Suggested Modifications of the Economic Stabilization Act Which Expires on April 30, 1974. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1974.Google Scholar
United States. President’s 1961 Tax Recommendations: Hearings before the Committee on Ways and Means, House of Representatives, Eighty-Seventh Congress, First Session, on the Tax Recommendations of the President Contained in His Message Transmitted to the Congress, April 20, 1961. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1961.Google Scholar
United States. Regional Impact of an Economic Slowdown, the Michigan Picture: Hearings before the Committee on the Budget, United States Senate, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session, July 19, 1979—Detroit, Mich., August 30, 1979–Flint, Mich. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1980.Google Scholar
United States. Stagflation: Hearings before the Special Study on Economic Change of the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session, April 30, and May 7 and 9, 1979. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. The 1968 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninetieth Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1968.Google Scholar
United States. The 1969 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969.Google Scholar
United States. The 1970 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office 1970.Google Scholar
United States. The 1970 Midyear Review of the State of the Economy. Hearings, Ninety-First Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office 1970.Google Scholar
United States. The 1974 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Third Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1974.Google Scholar
United States. The 1975 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Fourth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1975.Google Scholar
United States. The 1976 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Fourth Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976.Google Scholar
United States. The 1977 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Fifth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977.Google Scholar
United States. The 1978 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
United States. The 1979 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Sixth Congress, First Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. The 1980 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Seventh Congress. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979.Google Scholar
United States. The 1981 Economic Report of the President. Hearings, Ninety-Seventh Congress, First Session. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1981.Google Scholar
United States. The Decline of the Dollar: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Foreign Economic Policy of the Committee on Foreign Relations, United States Senate, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session, February 22, June 22, and July 24, 1978. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
United States. The President’s New Anti-Inflation Program: Hearing before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session… November 3, 1978. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978.Google Scholar
United States Department of Commerce. Foreign Direct Investment Program. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1972 and 1974.Google Scholar
United States Tariff Commission. Implications of Multinational Firms for World Trade and Investment and for U.S. Trade and Labor; Report to the Committee on Finance of the United States Senate and Its Subcommittee on International Trade on Investigation No. 332–69, under Section 332 of the Tariff Act of 1930. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1973.Google Scholar
Enterprise (journal of National Association of Manufacturers)Google Scholar
NAM Reports (journal of National Association of Manufacturers)Google Scholar
New York TimesGoogle Scholar
Wall Street JournalGoogle Scholar
Washington PostGoogle Scholar
Washington Report (journal of U.S. Chamber of Commerce)Google Scholar
World Financial Markets (journal of Morgan Guaranty Trust Company of New York)Google Scholar
Bank for International Settlement. Annual Reports, 1931–1936. http://www.bis.org/publ/arpdf/archive/Google Scholar
Brimmer, Andrew. “Commercial Bank Lending Abroad and the U.S. Balance of Payments.” Speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, March 16, 1972. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/scribd/?item_id=10406&filepath=/files/docs/historical/federal%20reserve%20history/bog_members_statements/brimmer_19720316.pdfGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Gross Domestic Product, http://www.bea.gov/national/Index.htmGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer Price Index, http://www.bls.gov/cpi/tables.htmGoogle Scholar
U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Unemployment Rate, https://data.bls.gov/timeseries/LNS14000000Google Scholar
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. Values and Shares of Merchandise Exports and Imports, Annual, 1948–2012, http://unctadstat.unctad.org/wds/TableViewer/tableView.aspx?ReportId=101Google Scholar
Hagley Museum and Library (HML), Wilmington, DE.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Trade, FDI, and Euromarkets, 1958–1976

Figure 1

Figure 1 Sources for FDI yearly, $bn (constant dollars, 1990=100).Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Foreign Direct Investment Program, 1972 and 1974.

Figure 2

Figure 2 GM foreign loans and shares of total current liabilities, $mm (constant dollars, 1990=100).Source: General Motors, Annual Report, various years.

Figure 3

Figure 3 Foreign credits of US Banks (constant dollars, 1990=100).Note: $bn on the left; % on the right.Source: Brimmer, “Commercial Bank.”

Figure 4

Figure 4 Share of Eurobonds issued by U.S. companies. (%)Source: World Financial Markets, various years (journal of the Morgan Guaranty Trust Company of New York).

Figure 5

Figure 5 U.S. macroeconomic changes, 1944–1985.Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis, Gross Domestic Product; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Consumer Price Index; U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Unemployment Rate.

Figure 6

Table 2 Domestic and overseas profit rates, percent