Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-b95js Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T16:33:15.878Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE ROLE OF FINANCES IN REPUBLICAN ROME - (J.) Tan Power and Public Finance at Rome, 264–49 bce. Pp. xxx + 214, fig. New York: Oxford University Press, 2017. Cased, £55, US$85. ISBN: 978-0-19-063957-0.

Review products

(J.) Tan Power and Public Finance at Rome, 264–49 bce. Pp. xxx + 214, fig. New York: Oxford University Press, 2017. Cased, £55, US$85. ISBN: 978-0-19-063957-0.

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 June 2018

David Hollander*
Affiliation:
Iowa State University
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Reviews
Copyright
Copyright © The Classical Association 2018 

T.’s monograph uses fiscal sociology to examine the relationship between power and money in the Middle and Late Republic. T. asks ‘How (and with what effect) did a relatively narrow elite succeed in annexing the spoils of so many people's industry without sacrificing social supremacy?’ (p. xiii). While acknowledging recent work on ‘thought processes, communicative interactions, and visual media’ (p. xiv), T. argues that ‘too little attention has been paid to the role of economic resources’ (p. xvi). A central idea is that the suspension of tributum after 167 bce allowed the state to pursue policies without the consent of its citizens (p. xxix).

The book is divided into two parts with the first part (comprising three chapters) focused on the extraction of revenue from Rome's provinces. Chapter 1, ‘Rich Rome, Poor State’, shows how private wealth grew in the period between 200 and 150 bce, but the state's resources failed to keep pace. T. argues that the Romans had a ‘peculiarly parsimonious approach to empire’ (p. 38). Chapter 2, ‘The Use and Abuse of Tax Farming’, seeks to explain Republican Rome's ‘devotion to tax farming’ (p. 42), a system that did not maximise potential revenue for the state. T. begins by comparing Roman tax farmers with others, including Mughal zamindars and Ottoman malikaneci, and showing that the publicani were ‘respectably – though far from completely – constrained in their operations’ (p. 54). He then argues that the Roman aristocracy favoured tax farming because it did not require any administrative expertise from Roman magistrates, ‘ensured that state revenues were paid directly to the treasury without the risk that aristocratic rivals would mismanage or embezzle them’ (p. 60) and capped gross taxation. In his discussion T. focuses on Gaius Gracchus’ establishment of tax farming for Asia Minor in 123 bce. Gracchus and others, he argues, wanted a tax system that safeguarded revenue from ‘aristocratic incompetence and venality’ (p. 63), but did not undermine the power of aristocrats. I am not, however, convinced by the argument (p. 64) that auctions would inoculate Roman elites ‘from the charge of defrauding the Roman people, because the amount squeezed from the provincials was of no consequence to the treasury's receipts’. If the profits were substantial enough or the squeezing extreme, the Roman people would surely begin to wonder why the state was not benefiting sufficiently. Chapter 3, ‘Profiteering in the Provinces’, turns to some of the ways Roman elites were able to extract private revenue from Roman subjects and allies. One popular method was to take advantage of their need to borrow money (to pay Rome) by offering them loans at high interest rates. As T. notes, ‘A one-off payment to the state became a perpetual source of income for private citizens’ (p. 78) through debt payments and then confiscation of the collateral, typically land. The chapter also considers the ways a governor could profit from his province by manipulating, for example, his grain allowances or ability to billet troops in a city. The central dynamic is that private profit stemmed from the use of state power.

Part 2 consists of three case studies of the changing relationship between state revenue and political power. Chapter 4, ‘The Power of Taxpayers in the First Punic War’, looks at the funding of the Roman military in its first war against Carthage. T. argues that, because the state relied heavily on the tributum to finance military operations, taxpayers were ‘empowered’ and refused, after early naval disasters, to pay for new fleets. In his discussion of the Roman decision to aid the Mamertines, which triggered the war, T. states that the Romans ‘cannot have been so daft that the prospect of a wider – and potentially naval – conflict never crossed their minds’ (p. 102). I find this particular claim less than convincing since history provides many examples of voters making fairly daft decisions. A number of Athenian decisions in the latter stages of the Peloponnesian War spring to mind. Chapter 5, ‘The Plight of Taxpayers in the Second Punic War’, turns to the question of how Rome coped with the severe financial and manpower strains caused by the Hannibalic War. T. argues that ‘the political elite did a remarkably good job of controlling politics’ (p. 142) during the war despite the continued importance of the tributum. There are a number of interesting observations here concerning Roman politics, but it is surprising that T. does not devote more attention to the introduction of the denarius system (see p. 138). Furthermore, I am not convinced by his claim that the tributum (coupled with conscription of some farm labour) would force certain farmers to work less of the land they owned (p. 125). Certainly, the loss of labour would cause difficulties but farmers had a range of options available to them (e.g. shifting from intensive to more extensive cultivation practices) that strike me as a more plausible reaction than simply ceasing to cultivate some of their property. Chapter 6, ‘The Death and Taxes of the Gracchi’, rounds out Part 2 by exploring why the reforms of Tiberius and Gaius Gracchus unleashed such a violent reaction. T. argues that the Gracchi's legislation, by ‘redistributing Roman resources through state instead of private networks’, constituted a ‘threat to the privileged identity of Roman aristocrats’ (p. 168).

A concluding chapter reviews the book's arguments while putting them into a broader historical context. T. suggests we need to pay more attention to the economy ‘when completing a portrait of Roman political life’ (p. 179). T. also provides a brief but interesting comparison with the history of twentieth-century Saudi Arabia, another state transformed by a relatively sudden influx of great wealth. Overall, this is a clearly written and convincingly argued work that offers many insights into Republican politics.