Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-l4dxg Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-06T12:14:11.051Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An institutional perspective on governance, power, and politics of financial risk

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 June 2017

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Avoidance of risk and increasing returns are the two main motivators in finance. Returns are better understood and perhaps more easily regulated than financial risk, which is a complex and slippery concept. Financial risk may be best conceived of as a complementary good, but the nature of this good varies as the size of the investment position scales up. That is, the effects of financial risk may be conceived of as a private good for a small financial actor, but becomes a club good, then a common pool, and occasionally a public good as the impact of the investment position's financial risk spreads to affect more of society. Examining banking history shows us that banks and bankers have offset risk while retaining returns through structuring financial products and investment vehicles as club goods, thereby enabling financial actors to jointly benefit from ownership while harming those outside the club walls. Not surprisingly, this capacity to push risk outside club walls has grown commensurate with the political influence of banks and bankers. Laying out governance strategies and concepts, I suggest that in some circumstances pervasive club good structures in finance may be employed to gather regulation-enhancing information, to better understand the networked nature of financial risk and to craft self-governance structures.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © V.K. Aggarwal 2017 and published under exclusive license to Cambridge University Press 

Introduction

Avoiding risk and increasing returns are the two main motivators in banking and finance. Organizational groupings have provided ways to lessen risks and increase potential returns. Organizing also increases the capacity to gather, retain, and transfer information, benefiting both group and group members and providing another guard against risk. Commercial and investment banks have long been the primary organizational structure in financial intermediation, and constitute, along with countries’ public financial institutions, the key nodes in financial intermediation networks.Footnote 1 Within these networks, banks and other financial institutions intermediate across both space and time. In space, a bank accepts deposits from those who have capital and make loans to those who require capital; in time this archetypal bank converts short-term deposits into long-term loans, engaging in “qualitative asset transformation.”Footnote 2 But qualitative asset transformation holds enormous inherent risks as asset/liability mismatches may strike banks and other financial intermediaries. When a systemic banking crisis occurs, these risks may overwhelm many banks.Footnote 3 As the interlinked nature of banking and financial intermediation has become more global in nature over the last two centuries, more banking and currency crises have occurred.Footnote 4

Selmier, Penikas, and Vasilyeva define risk as “the estimated exposure to a situation of uncertain outcome.”Footnote 5 Their argument is that financial risk may be privately-consumed in smaller manifestations, but as risk increases, it crosses certain boundary conditions and shifts, or transmutates, from a private good to a good shared with others. As financial networks grew,Footnote 6 financial risks sometimes expanded beyond a person or a bank, becoming a kind of common pool of financial risk. When this occurred, economic actors could not escape from this risk even if they were not participants in the initial investments or the financial contracting which sometimes led to systemic problems. This unwilling sharing of risk occurred through three channels: the intermediary nature of banks and financial institutions; the nature of financial networks;Footnote 7 and the growing political power of large banks.Footnote 8 That is to say, this unwilling sharing of financial risk arises through the growing power of financial intermediaries to push risk out of their corporate structure and onto society.Footnote 9 When systemic crises occur, financial risk becomes a public good or, better put, a public bad.

While financial risk insurance may be provided in some countries, the nature of that insurance is often murky as to who is being insured and for what risks the insurance contract is struck.Footnote 10 Recognizing that “banking crises are the train wrecks of finance,”Footnote 11 governments grew more willing to extend insurance. Banks and other financial intermediaries, cognizant of their increasing economic and political influence, came to count on both the insurance and the inherent capacity to survive. Expanding our understanding beyond the rather simple concept of too-big-to-fail (henceforth TBTF), Mishkin termed this result “too politically important to fail.”Footnote 12 But this only captures the result, not the mechanics of expansion of financial firms’ political influence and this extension of insurance to them. Proper governance structures cannot be constructed without understanding these mechanics.

To examine financial risk and understand the mechanics as to how financial intermediaries have been able to lower or externalize their risks, this paper proceeds in four sections. Section 1 proposes a goods typology to examine property rights of financial risk, introducing how financial risk may grow to affect others. Section 2 sketches how historically bankers organized into club structures to lower risk and to self-govern as banking grew into a global industry and governments responded. Section 3 uses the vignette of the Hunt Brothers’ attempt to corner the silver market to illustrate how financial risk may grow from a privately-consumed good to systemic risk levels, becoming a public bad. Section 4 concludes by examining how club discipline may be reintroduced into financial intermediation and under what conditions reintroduction may be possible.

1 Mapping a goods typology of financial risk

Property rights of financial goods and products are complex and often misunderstood. Part of this misunderstanding arises from a quasi-religious belief in self-regulating marketsFootnote 13 consisting solely of private goods—those goods whose property rights are individually owned and from which others may be barred from using or consuming. This belief—grounded in financial economics through the efficient market hypothesisFootnote 14 —tends to downplay the nature of financial markets as complex networks in which risks and returns are shared and transmitted under conditions of considerable informational asymmetry.

Complexity of the property rights of financial risk, and the instruments used to manage that risk, have challenged governance of financial transactions. We can put these challenges into focus by categorizing financial risks along axes defining legal rights of consumption and usage.Footnote 15 Four types of financial risk result, as shown in Table 1: risk as a private good borne solely by a buyer; risk shared through members of a club (although some members may have greater executive power over the underlying risk positions); common pools where risks are shared among a community but where “consumption of risk” may damage the common pool (as detailed below); and risk borne by a national citizenry and managed by a public entity. McNutt proposed that non-private goods are all simply different kinds of public goods determined by boundary conditions ranging from very local (club goods) to somewhat local (common pools) to nationalFootnote 16 (public goods, which are usually considered as part of a citizen's access within the boundaries of a nation-stateFootnote 17 ).

Table 1: Generic Goods typology and the Assumption of Risk

Source: author's conception of risk assignment, categorization from McNutt, Reference McNutt1999; Ostrom & Ostrom, Reference Ostrom, Ostrom and Savas1977.

Viewing boundary conditions merely in geographic terms is becoming increasingly inaccurate in finance or in broader economic terms. As Schwartz argues in this special issue, modern corporations’ capacity to create club goods (he prefers the term “franchise goods”) is directly dependent on acquiring and protecting intellectual property rights and shifting risks out into the broader public. In other words, contesting property right boundaries to lower costs, while capturing greater profits, has become important to corporations’ strategies.

Future costs and profits have grown more difficult to estimate in finance due to increasingly complex financial productsFootnote 18 and more comprehensive financial market governance which includes implicit forms of insurance.Footnote 19 This complicates understanding inherent financial risks, which are sometimes shared and transmitted without all actors being fully cognizant of these risksFootnote 20 or wishing to accept the risk.Footnote 21 This lack of understanding occurs because the capacity to offset risk requires the risk holder to estimate her exposure to an outcome which may be uncertain to her. Knight's famous distinction between business risk and uncertainty is partially predicated upon information asymmetry; if information is available, and the risk holder can access that information, then risk can be probabilistically estimated. Estimation enables insurance contracting,Footnote 22 so risk may also be taken on through underwriting an insurance contract and offset by buying one.Footnote 23 But such contracts are inherently based on the writer's and buyer's estimation of risk and on their understanding of the property rights surrounding that risk. In other words, the actor seeking insurance against risk, or writing an insurance contract to take on risk, needs to estimate what is owned and how it is owned or controlled.

Table 2 below is a two-by-two-by-two cube showing financial products and structures employed in managing risks. Both financial products, as well as institutional arrangements, are employed to obtain profits and manage risks. The top layer presents Products and Services, the bottom layer presents Institutional arrangements. The cube shows the extensive presence of club goods and club good structures in finance, which serve to share riskFootnote 24 while concurrently concentrating profit.Footnote 25 The Cube allows us to visualize how financial risk may have started as a private good on the Products and Services layer, but then be transmutated into any of the four types of Institutional arrangements on the lower layer. Some of these transmutation paths—which involve changes in property rights—are sketched in this paper.

Table 2: 2 × 2 × 2 Cube of financial products and structures employed in managing risk

Sources: General typology constructed from author's works, Ostrom & Ostrom, Reference Ostrom, Ostrom and Savas1977, Weimar & Vining, Reference Weimer and Vining2005.

Club structures are often used by corporate and financial actors to push risk out into society (public bads), thereby capturing return without compensating for risk. Such property right structures, part and parcel of banking's institutional history for millennia, may evolve into vehicles which destabilize markets and economies, enable rent-seeking, and weaken regulatory outcomes. A club can be defined as “a voluntary group deriving mutual benefits from sharing one or more of the following [categories]: production costs, the members’ characteristics, or a good characterized by excludable benefits.”Footnote 26 Members obtain profit or risk-minimization benefits, or both, through joint ownership of a financial product or a portfolio of financial products. There are three factors which complicate members’ incentives in such a club. One, the good obtained may be perceived as beneficial by some but not by others within the club good structure, as conditioned by individual risk preferences. Two, benefits are not necessarily equal within the club's “walls”; although all may benefit, often some get more than others. And three, assuming shared rationality, responsibility, and information access across club members is sometimes not an accurate depiction of the information sets of all members within the financial club in question.

All three of these factors obtain in part because of informational and power asymmetries: Not all within the “walls” have the same information and, even when they do, they may not have the same influence or legal status.Footnote 27 This is increasingly the case in modern financial intermediation, where larger investment firms may exert considerable influence on the corporations in which they invest.Footnote 28 There is nothing inherently nefarious about these asymmetries, per se. But negotiations over information access and interpretation provide incentives to advocate for influence and legal status. Young, Marple, and HeilmanFootnote 29 map out social ties between financial institutions and the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), finding that tighter social ties lead to more advocating and lobbying to influence SEC regulations. This influence of social ties engenders a “stronger effect on structurally prominent firms” as well as the SEC.Footnote 30 Prominence not only conditions influence, but also conditions the ways in which financial risk positions taken on may manifest in different types of financial goods and structures.

In a private financial transaction as shown in the top box in Table 2, risk is born by the buyer. For the purposes of governance and even consumption, risk may be considered as a complementary good which comes packaged with the primary good acquired or shared.Footnote 31 The seller may offer guarantees regarding the good, but these guarantees actually constitute another, separable good which may or may not come packaged with the primary good purchased.Footnote 32 Risk-sharing increases as the number of joint consumers or users increases, from club members to members of a common pool resource (CPR) to those enjoying a public good within boundaries.

To illustrate how the nature of risk as a good may change—that is, how the property rights surrounding financial risk may change—consider a representative investor, Josephine. Josephine does not acquire risk directly, but obtains it through acquiring some other good such as a technology stock. The nature and type of this complementary good is conditioned by the size of the risk position acquired and by the initial state obtaining when it is acquired.Footnote 33

Josephine's investment position and her risk position are conditioned by her network status within a financial network structure. If Josephine is an average individual investor, the risk that accompanies her acquisition of a technology stock would be a private good (top left box in Table 2). She alone bears the risk. If Josephine is a senior partner in a hedge fund and takes a large position in that technology stock, then the financial risk acquired affects all who work in her hedge fund due to the club good structure of the hedge fund, in that all who work at Josephine's fund share in gains and losses through their compensation and employment.Footnote 34 Note that Josephine's actions have changed the property rights around the underlying investment risk to a club good structure embedded at an institutional level (bottom back box in Table 2). Moreover, if other firms observe Josephine's behavior and begin to emulate it, then their additional risk encumbrance creates a new, expanded club consisting of those other firms and employees exposed to the financial risk contained in the technology stock.

If Josephine's hedge fund investments are of such size that market-wide or international effects may occur if the value of her assets expands or contracts, then embedded financial risk is more accurately typed as a common pool or even a public good or bad, depending on the outcome of the underlying investment. A prominent modern example would be the collapse of Long-term Capital Management in 1998. Expanding risk may cause regulatory problems and social costs on firms, and in domestic and international markets. Governance challenges surrounding such risks arise through engaging in behavior which may take advantage of an implicit insurance policyFootnote 35 which enables an actor to consume risk without requiring specified and direct payment.Footnote 36 This implicit insurance policy is sometimes described as evidence of moral hazard,Footnote 37 but may in fact be broader in origin, scope and effect than this term implies. Part of the externality which an archetypal public good addresses may be considered a manifestation of risk.

Systemic risk has likely increased since the financial crisis, as financial economists Admati and Hellwig note, “the consequences of letting a large bank fail are probably more severe today than in the case of Lehman Brothers in 2008, but saving them might cripple their countries.”Footnote 38 The next section sketches how and why financial risk came to be shared so completely within a world wherein “economic liberalism…evolved into a veritable faith in man's secular salvation through a self-regulating market.”Footnote 39 Information and technology conjoined with economic development to change the nature of financial risk. As banking changed from a relationship between private banks and clients to a community of bankers and clients, then into emerging national and international financial networks, financial risk underwent a process of transmutation from private and club goods toward systemic risk forms akin to CPRs and public goods.

2 An Institutional history perspective on risk in banking

Modern finance and banking consist of highly-networked ecologiesFootnote 40 but, in fact, banking and financial contracting have long been economic activities in which financial risk and reward were shared across networks. Club structures have been quite common over the history of banking.Footnote 41 Financial actors have employed two club forms to share risk among a larger number of actors: The first is creation of larger structures that distribute risk across a membership whose members are compensated through possible profit-sharing, as shown in the Products and Services layer of Table 2’s cube. These include private equity, venture capital partnerships, and mutual funds. The second form consisted of governance structures whose purpose was to manage risk and contagion within the members of that structure. Table 2 lists, on the Institutional level, some of these modern forms of banking clubs such as banking partnerships; bank clearing houses; banks which can access the Federal Reserve “window” for funding; and systemically-important financial institutions (SIFIs). In the construction of club forms on both levels, bankers and financiers have learned over two centuries how to “socialize” risk in order to lower their probability of collapse.

The dominant strain of modern international commercial and investment banking throughout the worldFootnote 42 can be traced back to the Atlantic Trade after the Napoleonic Wars.Footnote 43 As this trade expanded, some merchants took on financial obligations outside their own trading houses through credit extension. These merchants became merchant bankers as they migrated toward a purer form of financing business while leaving the physical movement of cotton, iron, and wool to others.Footnote 44 Reputation and trust were essential in a world where “Anglo-American merchant-bankers achieved monetary gain by lending the prestige of their name without lending any money whatsoever in most cases.”Footnote 45 High levels of risk were distributed across the network to offset risk exposure to the longer-term nature of lending, shipping risks, exposure to uncertain commodity prices and the intense competition: Scottish merchant banks, for instance, were willing to “face almost any risk for the sake of the difference between 4 percent at home and 4 ½ percent across the Atlantic.”Footnote 46

Boot, Greenbaum, and ThakorFootnote 47 argue risk was managed in banking partnerships by employing two forms of capital: (1) the partners’ financial capital within the firm and (2) human capital which was “liquefied through accessing the partners’ networks of contacts.”Footnote 48 But human capital is more accurately viewed as consisting of two parts: reputation gained through interactions with clients, fellow bankers, the general public and governments, and informational capital. Informational capital consisted of partners’ tacit knowledge concerning clients and other bankers in the nineteenth century; as the twentieth century progressed, more and more extensive financial market information was garnered through transactions and through processing power.Footnote 49 Reputational and informational forms of capital were both critical in protecting financial capital through risk discovery,Footnote 50 minimization, and avoidance.

Within networks, merchant banks were club good structures which established boundaries delineated by family ties or through strong co-religionist or cultural linksFootnote 51 to manage financial risk (as shown in Table 2, lower back box). Financial risk began to move outside these merchant banks almost with their establishment, but remained within clubs wherein merchant banks were members. These clubs spread risk-bearing tasks across a number of merchant banks using instruments such as structured syndicates to create partial ownership of ships and shipping ventures.Footnote 52 This practice extended earlier trading and financing arrangements which had arisen in Venice, the Ottoman Empire, and on the Indian subcontinent.Footnote 53 Another instrument distributing risk was the sophisticated syndication of enormous bond issues necessary to finance both sides during the Napoleonic Wars.Footnote 54 War bond issues stimulated a “two-way system of raising and simultaneously spending vast sums of money [which] acted like a bellows, fanning the development of western capitalism and of the nation-state itself,”Footnote 55 highlighting the strategic nature of banking to governments.

As industrial development required more capital, latter nineteenth-century banking operations spread risks through both long-lasting and one-off partnerships, setting the foundations for more sophisticated, pan-industry syndication efforts to share financial risk. Some efforts pooled the expertise of investment bankers (the direct descendants of merchant banks) with capital-endowed insurance companies.Footnote 56 Financial innovations like these created new ways to distribute risk across a broader range of actors. This in turn increasingly interconnected actors not only through creditor-debtor relationships but through complex risk-sharing arrangements, creating early CPRs of financial risk through broader syndication pools.

As these networks developed and deepened, traditional partnerships proved inadequate in both risk management and in capital adequacy terms. Partnerships carried insufficient capital as needs for railroad financing grew in the second half of the nineteenth century.Footnote 57 In response to capital requirements and increasing risks, some banking firms grew very rapidly between the late nineteenth century and the onset of the Great Depression.Footnote 58 As an example, National City Bank of New York (predecessor to Citibank) grew from a president and two clerks in the 1890s to 500 employees by the beginning of World War I, then rapidly expanded outside the United States so that by 1917 there were some 1,600 domestic employees and 600 employees stationed overseas.Footnote 59 As global interlinkages in the financial network grew, American and German banks responded to such growthFootnote 60 by putting pressure on banks in other parts of the world: The amalgamation of twenty small private banks into “Barclays Bank in 1896 [occurred in London] at the very moment when the private deposit bank was receiving its last blow.”Footnote 61

While much of this creeping institutionalization during the first two-thirds of the nineteenth century occurred through private institutions, this changed in the last third of the century. Capie, Goodhart, and Schnadt suggest that 1873 may be a “natural dividing line for a history of central banking,” and this inflection point in central banks institutionalization and expanding roles is also an inflection point in governance of financial risk.Footnote 62 Wars in the Americas, Asia, and especially Europe had convinced governments of the need to raise money, but government-established central banking and the international links between those central banks were still just emerging and often ad hoc.Footnote 63 Issuance of fiat currencyFootnote 64 provided a public good at the Products and Services layer as shown in Table 2. Pulled by ideas developed by Bagehot, Jevons, and others, and pushed by a series of financial crises,Footnote 65 European central banks began to take on the role of Lender of Last Resort (LOLR).Footnote 66 Governments recognized that the aggregation of actors willing to take on risk in financial markets constituted not only a kind of common pool resource which could be tapped in times of war, but also could be employed for national economic development. To support this resource, governments began to provide the institutional level public goods of central banking (Table 2, lower front-most box). Spreading establishment of central banks indicated that governments believed that bank clearinghouses could not extend common pool resources of financial risk consistently, or nationally, and so provision of common pools and public goods in finance became institutionalized.

Bank clearinghouses had developed to process bankers’ drafts which were drawn on member banks. Their growth and expansion into self-governance provide examples of complex institutional risk-sharing arrangements which sometimes crossed national boundaries in their provision of common pools of financial risk. Nair details how Chettiar bankers established clearinghouses which spanned across the Bay of Bengal and much of coastal Southeast Asia toward the end of the nineteenth century.Footnote 67 Chettiar banking houses lent through an extended banking club which set interest rates and imposed discipline. Similarly, rates set within bankers’ clubs in the City—a square mile of London that was the world's financial center in the nineteenth century—not only allowed local clearing operations, but also affected rates globally as telegraph networks wove the financial world together.Footnote 68 In essence, extended clubs provided access to extended common pools of financial risk.

Dowd argues that clearinghouses were structured as banking clubs while additionally providing a public good in the form of confidence in banking systems through “the ability of the clearinghouse to protect the integrity of the banks by controlling the risks they take.”Footnote 69 But disciplining member banks and collectively-arranging rescue operations were, by design, localized with varying geographic spread.Footnote 70 The considerable challenges facing clearinghouses revolved around regulatory issues, capital adequacy within the local system, and the requirement for strict enforcement. Participating banks had to be within reasonable daily traveling distances in nineteenth-century terms in order to clear transactions.

Clearinghouses could deal with less severe banking panics, and sometimes suspended member banks.Footnote 71 But there were cases where panics necessitated significant outside helpFootnote 72 or even led to the chaotic dissolution of the clearinghouse. In effect, as the network grew in size and complexity, geographic limits on the common pool of financial risk necessitated new governance structures for these emerging networks. As communication, transportation, and financial linkages increased, the resultant financial risk from larger financial networks could not be managed by clearinghouses,Footnote 73 and they became more reluctant to commit to more distant banks as shown in the 1907 financial crisis in the United States.Footnote 74 As financialization brought banking to a more central, more politically-powerful position in the early twentieth century, some banks within the local clearinghouses grew to sizes much greater than others, and these larger banks sometimes left the clearinghouses.Footnote 75 The above-mentioned complexity of the network and expanding common pools of financial risk combined with larger banks’ concern over risk exposure to weaker banks within the clearinghouse impelled their exit. These larger financial institutions’ concentrations of capital and political power increased their importance to governments as their critical position in networks came to be understood and even embraced. And as non-bank actors, which were outside the clearinghouses, became more prominent, financial risk in the network grew. The primary catalyst for the 1907 financial crisis was the collapse of the Knickerbocker Trust, which was not a bank.Footnote 76

Governments, recognizing the power and risk accumulating within larger banks and the increasing financialization within national economies, realized that ad hoc club-like structures like clearinghouses were too local, too vulnerable, and too weak in enforcement power to effectively deal with systemic financial risk in industrializing economies. Clearinghouses gave way to powerful, government-run central banking institutions.Footnote 77 The international ambitions of U.S. banks in the early twentieth century, their increased local and global interconnectedness, and recurrent banking crises played a major role in the U.S. government's decision to centralize monetary governance. This culminated in the founding of the U.S. Federal Reserve Bank in 1913.Footnote 78 The last “club-like” central banking was conducted through the Bank of England, which was finally, fully converted into a government unit in 1944.Footnote 79 To provide better oversight of countries’ banking system and economies, and better manage fiat currencies (note the public goods and institutions mentioned in Table 2, foremost two boxes), central banks were established in Latin America, Asia, and Africa; advice and consultancy of economists from the Bank of England and the U.S. Federal Reserve led to many central banks being established in the image of the Bank of England, the Federal Reserve, or an amalgam of the two.Footnote 80

Systemic financial risk has remained a challenge, and such risk arises not only through banks but through the shadow banking institutions as well. The Hunt Brothers’ attempt to corner the silver market showed the emerging global nature of financial risk. This story also illustrates how the manifestation of financial risk depends on position size.

3 Cornering the Silver Market: The Hunt brothers Illustrate Global Systemic Risk

For drama and illustration of the transmutation of financial risk, few vignettes provide a picture of systemic financial risk like that of the Hunt Brothers and their attempt to corner the silver market between 1974 and 1980. Table 2 helps to illustrate this path of transmutation. In the mid-1970s, the Brothers acquired an estimated $20 million in physical silver, but realized that they could not have much effect on market prices by acquiring silver in physical form.Footnote 81 They switched strategies to buying silver futures in order to increase their leverage and to more quickly gain a significant position. Other large speculators bet against them and, initially, succeeded in deflating the rising silver price. Undeterred, the Brothers continued to acquire silver positions through the futures markets.Footnote 82 At this stage these inherent financial risks constituted private goods personally taken on by the Brothers as well as assumed by their family's privately-held oil company.

Typically a buyer of futures contracts “unwinds” her position by selling her contract at a profit as expiry approaches, if the price of the underlying commodity increased over the holding period. The original seller of the contract may purchase an equivalent contract to unwind his position. In this case no physical silver changes hands. But in early 1980s the Brothers demanded physical delivery rather than unwind their futures positions,Footnote 83 arranged for warehousing space to store the silver, and continued to buy future contracts by pledging assets in their family oil company. Silver prices spiked in January of 1980, as physical delivery could not be made due to shortages. Even before this point was reached, financial risks tied to silver had become a club good—investors, speculators, and companies which used silver in industrial operations were severely affected as can be gleaned from Chart 1’s top half showing silver's 100-year price trend.

Sources: http://www.macrotrends.net/1470/historical-silver-prices-100-year-chart; http://www.macrotrends.net/1441/gold-to-silver-ratio (Accessed June 15, 2016).

Chart 1: 100 year trends for Silver Price and Gold/Silver ratio [CPI-adjusted]

While commodity prices experience volatile price swings throughout cycles, the effect of the Brothers’ buying was unusually large. The bottom half of Chart 1 demonstrates this through the 100-year, gold-to-silver price ratio, indicating that by the later 1970s silver prices were registering their highest prices compared with gold over this century. The only time silver had risen this high against gold was in the post-WW I depression and during the artificially-low gold prices in the emergent inflation of the late 1960s, when the price of gold was still directly tied to the U.S. dollar. The Brothers had cornered the global silver market, causing a huge disruption in other commodities. At this time many futures contract writers who had sold a contract but did not have the physical silver could not deliver, and a huge panic ensued.

Over these six years, the Brothers’ risk position had grown from a private good (when they were a smaller buyer of the physical metal) to a club good as industrial users of silver, such as film companies, were unwillingly pulled into the risk pool created through their speculation. Their continued buying in the market transmutated the risk position into a common pool as the financial risk affected all market participants. The Brothers’ speculation impaired both usage and even access to the futures markets as a resource to manage risk exposures to silver and other commodities. In the end, the pool of risk became a public “bad” as economic disruption caused by spikes in other commodities became more severe.

The Brothers were finally stopped when their banks called in the loans used to acquire all that silver.Footnote 84 After a nine-year legal battle, the Brothers paid a large fine, lost a significant portion of their family oil company and were barred for life from trading in the American commodity markets.Footnote 85 As one might imagine, their banks were concerned not only with the economic implications of the Brothers’ speculative actions and the banks’ resulting financial risks. As regulatory sanctions and legal cases mounted up against the Brothers, their bankers were subjected to additional scrutiny. And other customers’ opinions on the sagacity of lending to the Brothers may also have influenced the banks. So regulatory concerns, potential damage to reputation, and risk exposure to the Brothers all weighed on the minds of their bankers. Some readers might suggest that this vignette shows that the system worked by countering and ultimately punishing the Brothers. But that is an incomplete conclusion. That the Brothers’ actions became the prime factor in a fivefold increase in the price of silver, boosting other commodity prices, and damaging trust and reputation in the financial system and in the banks themselves. Their actions also showed that governing financial markets required understanding that underlying financial risks can shift from private to club to common pool to public good. That is, financial markets are not simply markets, per se.

4 Can club good structures be used to govern financial risk?

We are now trusting as many people as we ought to trust, and as yet there is no wild excess of misplaced confidence which would make us trust those whom we ought not to trust.Footnote 86

Bagehot's analysis of stability in the City'sFootnote 87 credit markets sketched in the network parameters of trust, confidence and risk which existed within the world's financial center circa 1873. A century later, the network had grown to a global size wherein counter-party risk was more difficult to uncover and in which informal clubs and common pools of risk could arise without participators’ acquiescence or even knowledge.

Financial intermediaries continued to employ two forms of clubs to minimize, avoid, or disperse risks: creating larger organizations to engineer and manage investment opportunities, and self-governing through organizations which disciplined members and enabled them to balance their books through clearing and transfer operations. The first form spawned a large and diverse number of organizational iterations, including syndicates, mutual funds, private equity firms and venture capital funds, multiline financial conglomerates, and diversified insurance companies, as detailed in Table 2 on both the Products and Services layer and on the Institutional layer, while the second form has been underdeveloped and sometimes turned to financial firms’ benefit rather than to their governance.

As previously noted, benefits and access to information are not necessary equal within the club walls, those making decisions for the club may have higher risk preferences, and larger firms and greater financial capital often translated into greater compensation. These complicating factors became interrelated and fed on each other in the latest financial crisis and its aftermath.Footnote 88 A string of successes compounded the difficulty in untangling success factors but confirmed in the minds of some financiers that personal skill was the determinant factor. With bonuses determined on production, deal closure, and trading success, the bonus recipient was incentivized to produce, close deals, or trade more,Footnote 89 and “pushing the envelope” became routine.Footnote 90 Implicit or explicit insurance from government sources further altered the banker's or trader's perception of risk, thereby pushing her/him toward more risk-accepting transaction patterns.Footnote 91 The Term Securities Lending Facility provides a case in point. The American Government bought risk-encumbered assets of banks and insurance companies, acting as an ex-post provider of insurance by taking on some banks’ assets, thereby increasing banks’ reserves and enhancing the quality of their remaining assets. Financial firms and “regulatory agencies…mistook crisis insurance for ordinary insurance.”Footnote 92

But these financial firms are staffed with bankers and financiers who had become “slaves of the market” due,Footnote 93 in part, to a perverse incentive structure where they face a “compensation function that is convex in returns, that is, one that encourages risk taking because the upside is significant, while the downside is limited.”Footnote 94 Acharya, Mehran, and Sundaram propose an incentive methodology to align the risk in a bank or financial institution with its organization structure (as a club): require incentive compensation in cash which vests over a longer term and, if the bank enters a predefined period of “stress,” the cash accounts would revert to the bank.Footnote 95 This method is an improvement on the so-called “malus” (that is, bonus clawbacks) proposals made after the onset of the financial crisis.Footnote 96

Regulators also face perverse internal incentives. Financial economist and Bundesbank Board Member Beatrice Weder di Mauro wrote: “As soon as crisis strikes, the optimal choice for policymakers differs from the pre-announced policy, the authorities will usually offer support. The banks anticipate this behaviour and run even more risks as a result.”Footnote 97 The larger the financial institution became, the greater the government's support. Enabled by technology and empowered through capital concentration, some banks and financial institutions grew to great size and became TBTF.Footnote 98 Banks paid premiums well over recognized value to acquire other banks in order to become members of the TBTF “club” and obtain a lower cost-of-capital.Footnote 99 The public good provided by government management of banking stability has been turned into a club good. When Schwartz notes that “choice of [the term] ‘clubs’ distracts attention away from the issue of what exactly creates the excludability that distinguishes a club good from a public good,”Footnote 100 we can answer that the excludability comes from lowered financial risk and greater return, in the case of TBTF.

The systemic financial risks engendered by those in the TBTF club have been addressed in two ways since the crisis began: through requiring the largest financial institutions to pay a “SIFI premium”—an additional layer of core capital for the largest financial institutions—and through application of the Volcker Rule, which requires some separation of proprietary trading from other banking operations in and, in some cases, beyond the United States.Footnote 101 Both the SIFI premium and application of the Volcker Rule are conditioned by the power of the central banking authorities to apply them. Negotiations surrounding rules and restrictions applied within and beyond national borders are subject to political jostling.Footnote 102 Those negotiating international regulatory efforts keep one eye on domestic interests and the other on stability in international markets.Footnote 103 The resulting political interplay clouds critical international efforts such as when and how to launch LOLR operations.

Kindleberger argues that LOLR in its ideal form is emblematic of a pure public good.Footnote 104 But LOLR operations are by their very nature political, as the hegemon (since WWII, the United States) must decide how and where to intervene and how to finance the intervention. Turmoil resulting in the aftermath of the 2007 global financial crisis was rough, as evidenced by the People's Bank of China's Vice Chairman's comment: “The international community should not overlook the risks arising from the international monetary system and pay adequate attention to surveillance over the countries that issue the world's major currencies.”Footnote 105 Her pique—and that of the Chinese government—was echoed by other countries at what was seen as U.S. currency manipulation. But the Federal Reserve believed it had to radically inflate its balance sheet in order to act like a LOLR.

The second form of clubs to minimize, avoid, or disperse risks proved in the latest financial crisis to vary considerable in risk management effectiveness. The more influential member organizations relied in part on the social ties of their individual employees to influence regulation and governance.Footnote 106 While some self-regulating organizations have been established to good effect, other self-regulating organizations serve more as talking shops and lobbying centers rather than centers of discipline and self-governance.

The LIBOR (London Interbank Overnight Rate) scandal in 2012 showed how club governance could fail, but also provides a lesson in how it might succeed. LIBOR is the rate at which banks lend to each other in overnight London markets and is used as a benchmark guide for setting the prices of millions of financial contracts including swaps, forward contracts, loans, and repurchase agreements. The LIBOR rate was established each day by polling a small number of banks (sixteen for the three-month LIBOR) then taking the average of the middle banks. That is, the highest and lowest quartiles of banks’ responses were removed and the middle half's responses were then averaged.Footnote 107 The scandal in 2012 erupted when it was found that traders at a few banks had conspired to artificially fix rates. LIBOR-fixing is very important to global finance for the information it provides, and clearly the banks involved in LIBOR-fixing constitute a club which benefits from privileged access. The British Bankers’ Association had been tasked with the daily polling and calculations required, a duty now given over to exchange operator ICE.Footnote 108

Chiu argues that “Regulators have the option of turning LIBOR into a public good, [but that] may in fact be counterproductive to achieving the preservation of LIBOR and the restoration of market confidence surrounding the benchmark.”Footnote 109 As outside observers do not have access to the same level of information, the simplest governance mechanism is to force those banks participating in the club to self-police and, if a conspiracy is uncovered, to report. Failing to report would be dealt with by expulsion from the club and/or large fines. In fact, significant fines have been levied with good effect.Footnote 110

Clubs in banking can be used as disciplining organizations: The question is should they be used. Mishkin's comment that financial firms grow to become “too politically important to fail” is germane here as political power is one factor behind financial intermediaries’ capacity to push risk out of their corporate structure onto society. How this has occurred—through evolution of property rights structures—is a factor in growing power of financial institutions yet also may provide a stick to reintroduce club discipline.

As government support is sometimes necessary and profits are higher for those in the club, threatened expulsion when self-regulation fails is a powerful stick. This requires combining microprudential regulatory frameworks with macroprudential supervision. Governmental supervisory efforts cannot really “focus on a single risk at an individual institution”Footnote 111 because the informational asymmetries within financial intermediaries are already so great that it is difficult for those outside, no matter how powerful, to adequately supervise. Rather, governments should reinforce club discipline within financial firms and within the industry clubs spanning firms, imposing self-governance in selected sectors as well as enforcing microprudential regulation. Holding financial intermediaries accountable for their own and their partners’ actions and thereby reimposing risks inherent in reputational capital is possible, but would require a balance of governmental regulation with imposed self-regulation where governments would intervene and punish upon evidence of transgression.

Footnotes

1 Greenbaum and Thakor (Reference Greenbaum and Thakor1995); The New York Times, 30 January 2010, Paul Volcker, “How to Reform Our Financial System.”

2 Boot, Greenbaum, and Thakor (Reference Boot, Greenbaum and Thakor1993); Greenbaum and Thakor (Reference Greenbaum and Thakor1995).

3 Aliber and Kindleberger (Reference Aliber and Kindleberger2015); Barth, Caprio, and Levine (Reference Barth, Caprio and Levine2005); Rajan (Reference Rajan2006).

4 Reinhart and Rogoff (Reference Reinhart and Rogoff2009).

5 Selmier, Penikas, and Vasilyeva (Reference Selmier, Penikas and Vasilyeva2014), 123, following Holton (Reference Holton2004), 22–23.

9 Alessandri and Haldane (Reference Alessandri and Haldane2009); Bhidé (Reference Bhidé2009); Polanyi (Reference Polanyi1944), 6–15 and 130–2.

10 Congleton (Reference Congleton2012); Hughes and Mester (Reference Hughes and Mester1993); Penikas (Reference Penikas2012).

11 Barth, Caprio, and Levine (Reference Barth, Caprio and Levine2005), 26.

12 Mishkin (Reference Mishkin2006).

14 Efficient markets theory, based on concepts of frictionless markets composed of atomistic agents whose market participation internalizes risk, has been accepted to the point where it became performative. These concepts are now undergoing intense debate within financial economics, although earlier works like Barth, Caprio, and Levine, (Reference Barth, Caprio and Levine2005), van Horne (Reference van Horne1985), and Rajan (Reference Rajan2006) had already questioned some underlying assumptions.

16 McNutt (Reference McNutt1999).

17 Public goods are actually not fully defined by citizenship. If a Brazilian citizen goes to Japan, she would be protected by Japan's national defense merely by being within Japanese boundaries. If Japan is attacked, the Japanese Self Defensive Forces would not exclude her from the public defense umbrella provided within Japan's national boundaries.

18 Allen and Santomero (Reference Allen and Santomero1997); van Horne (Reference van Horne1985).

19 Congleton (Reference Congleton2012); Goodhart (Reference Goodhart2010); The Economist, 1 October 2009, Beatrice Weder di Mauro, “The Dog That Didn't Bark,” http:// www.economist.com/node/14539774.

20 May Levin, and Sugihara (Reference May, Levin and Sugihara2008); Rajan (Reference Rajan2006).

24 Dowd (Reference Dowd1994); Gorton and Mullineaux (Reference Gorton and Mullineaux1987).

26 Sandler and Tschirhart (Reference Sandler and Tschirhart1997), 335.

28 Fichtner, Heemskerk, and Garcia-Bernardo (Reference Fichtner, Heemskerk and Garcia-Bernardo2017).

29 Young, Marple, and Heilman (Reference Young, Marple and Heilman2017); also see Tsingou (Reference Tsingou2015).

30 Young et al. (Reference Young, Marple and Heilman2017), 353.

31 Selmier, Penikas, and Vasilyeva (Reference Selmier, Penikas and Vasilyeva2014).

32 Selmier (Reference Selmier, Oatley and Winecoff2014), 332, conceptualizes “the idea of financial goods defined as indivisible units, and financial products as amalgamations of one or more financial goods…a share could be divided into component parts that we might term financial goods. For instance, the dividend stream, voting rights, and fractional company ownership are separable components, combined to form the financial product that constitutes a share.”

33 Initial conditions may significantly increase the risk taken whether the actor is aware of that increased risk position or not. Consider adding to an investment position through leverage when the investment market in question is already highly-valued. The actor may assume the risk position encumbered is lower than it actually may be.

34 Penikas (Reference Penikas2012); Selmier, Penikas, Vasilyeva (Reference Selmier, Penikas and Vasilyeva2014).

35 The New York Times, 30 January 2010, Paul Volcker, “How to Reform Our Financial System”; The Economist, 1 October 2009, Beatrice Weder di Mauro, “The Dog That Didn't Bark,” http:// www.economist.com/node/14539774.

36 Congleton (Reference Congleton2012); Selmier, Penikas, Vasilyeva (Reference Selmier, Penikas and Vasilyeva2014).

38 Admati and Hellwig (Reference Admati and Hellwig2013) 12.

39 Polanyi (Reference Polanyi1944), 131.

42 Hayes and Hubbard (Reference Hayes and Hubbard1990); Selmier (Reference Selmier2013).

44 Dorfman (Reference Dorfman1951); Hidy (Reference Hidy1941); Morrison and Wilhelm (Reference Morrison and Wilhelm2008).

45 Hidy (Reference Hidy1941), 58.

46 W. T. Jackson quoted in Chapman (Reference Chapman1984), 98.

47 Boot, Greenbaum, and Thakor (Reference Boot, Greenbaum and Thakor1993).

48 Selmier (Reference Selmier2013), 13.

50 Discovery used here in the economic sense of discerning price or factor value.

53 Frank (Reference Frank1998), 68–72; Fratianni and Spinelli (Reference Fratianni and Spinelli2006); Nair (Reference Nair2016).

54 Buchinsky and Polak (Reference Buchinsky and Polak1993); Kennedy (Reference Kennedy1987) 76–84; Rasler and Thompson (Reference Rasler, Thompson and Midlarsky2000).

55 Kennedy (Reference Kennedy1987), 77.

56 Chapman (Reference Chapman1984), 87–9.

57 Chapman (Reference Chapman1984); Ferguson (Reference Ferguson1999), 56–61, 84–87.

58 For further explanations see Selmier (Reference Selmier2013), 15–25.

59 Cleveland and Huertas (Reference Cleveland and Huertas1985), 32, 89–91.

60 Einzig (Reference Einzig1935); Ferguson (Reference Ferguson1999), 95; Tilly (Reference Tilly1989).

61 Cassis (Reference Cassis1985), 218.

62 Capie, Goodhart, and Schnadt (Reference Capie, Fischer, Goodhart and Schnadt1994), 10.

63 Eichengreen (Reference Eichengreen1996); Gallarotti (Reference Gallarotti1995).

64 Cohen (Reference Cohen1998), 27–31, 125–34; Helleiner (Reference Helleiner2002).

66 Polanyi argues this was a political move (Reference Polanyi1944), 215, “In the last resort, impaired self-regulation of the market led to political intervention,” but your author argues for a more complex battery of reasons.

67 Nair (Reference Nair2016).

69 Dowd (Reference Dowd1994), 294; see also Salter and Tarko (Reference Salter and Tarko2017, in this special issue).

70 See Moen and Tallman (Reference Moen and Tallman1999); Wicker (Reference Wicker2000).

71 Dowd (Reference Dowd1994); Gorton and Mullineaux (Reference Gorton and Mullineaux1987).

72 Moen and Tallman (Reference Moen and Tallman1999).

73 Goodhart (Reference Goodhart1987); Gorton and Mullineaux (Reference Gorton and Mullineaux1987).

74 Wicker (Reference Wicker2000).

75 Gorton and Mullineaux (Reference Gorton and Mullineaux1987); Moen and Tallman (Reference Moen and Tallman1999).

76 Moen and Tallman (Reference Moen and Tallman1999); Wicker (Reference Wicker2000).

79 Tilly (Reference Tilly1989), 197.

81 Physical silver refers to silver in metal form, such as coin, bars, ounces or tons, agreed to be delivered from a mine, refinery or dealer. Silver futures refers to a financial contract in which the buyer has the right to demand delivery of the physical good at, or over, a specified period in the future at a specified price. The buyer obtains only an option to pay for the silver, but does not yet own the “underlying” silver on which the financial futures contract is written. The seller of the contract need not have position of the physical silver underlying the contract.

82 Abolafia and Kilduff (Reference Abolafia and Kilduff1988), 184–5.

83 Meaning the seller of the futures contract must deliver the amount of silver specified in the contract, and cannot “unwind” the position.

84 The Economist, 26 January 1980a. “Over-Exposed.” 70–71. Accessed March 8, 2013, on The Economist Historical Archive; The Economist, 10 May 1980b. “Kismet, Nelson.” Accessed March 8, 2013, on The Economist Historical Archive. The banks were not only concerned about the economic implications of Brothers’ massive attempt to corner the silver market, but also the regulatory sanctions and legal cases mounting up against the Brothers’ actions. One can also suppose that the network effects of the silver price spike on their other customers also influenced the banks.

85 The New York Times, 21 December 1989, Kurt Eichenwald, “2 Hunts Fined and Banned from Trades.”

86 Bagehot (Reference Bagehot1873), 148.

87 Of this centuries-old financial heart of London, Chapman wrote ((Reference Chapman1984), 180): “this parochial square mile did not change very much until after the Second World War.”

88 Bhidé (Reference Bhidé2009).

90 Vanity Fair, August 2009., Michael Lewis, “The Man Who Crashed the World,” 98–105.

91 Goodhart (Reference Goodhart2010).

92 Congleton (Reference Congleton2012), 408–9.

93 Bell and Hindmoor (Reference Bell and Hindmoor2015).

94 Rajan (Reference Rajan2006), 515.

95 Acharya, Mehran, and Sundaram (Reference Acharya, Mehran and Sundaram2016).

96 See arguments presented in Hakenes and Schnabel (Reference Hakenes and Schnabel2014), as to why malus schemes are not effective incentive methods.

97 The Economist, 1 October 2009, Beatrice Weder di Mauro, “The Dog That Didn't Bark,” http:// www.economist.com/node/14539774.

98 Selmier (Reference Selmier2013); The New York Times, 30 January 2010, Paul Volcker, “How to Reform Our Financial System.”

99 Brewer and Jagtiani (Reference Brewer and Jagtiani2013); Hughes and Mester (Reference Hughes and Mester1993).

100 Schwartz (Reference Schwartz2017), 195.

101 Cukierman (Reference Cukierman2013); The New York Times, 30 January 2010, Paul Volcker, “How to Reform Our Financial System.”

102 Culpepper and Reinke (Reference Culpepper and Reinke2014).

103 Oatley and Nabors (Reference Oatley and Nabors1998); Quaglia (Reference Quaglia2017).

104 Aliber and Kindleberger (Reference Aliber and Kindleberger2015); see also Bagehot (Reference Bagehot1873); Goodhart (Reference Goodhart1987).

105 Hu (Reference Hu2009).

107 Hou and Skeie (Reference Hou and Skeie2014).

108 Chiu (Reference Chiu2016).

109 Footnote Ibid., 196.

References

Abolafia, Michael F. and Kilduff, Martin. 1988. “Enacting Market Crisis: The Social Construction of a Speculative Bubble.” Administrative Science Quarterly 33(2): 177–93.Google Scholar
Acharya, Viral, Mehran, Hamid, and Sundaram, Rangarajan K.. 2016. “Cash Holdings and Bank Compensation.” Economic Policy Review 22(1): 7783.Google Scholar
Admati, Anat and Hellwig, Martin. 2013. The Bankers' New Clothes: What's Wrong with Banking and What to Do about It. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Alessandri, Piergiorgio and Haldane, Andrew G.. 2009. “Banking on the State.” Bank of England working paper.Google Scholar
Allen, Franklin and Babus, Ana. 2009. “Networks in Finance.” In The network challenge: strategy, profit, and risk in an interlinked world, edited by Kleindorfer, Paul R. and Wind, Yoram. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Wharton School.Google Scholar
Allen, Franklin and Santomero, Anthony M.. 1997. The Theory of Financial Intermediation. Journal of Banking and Finance 21: 14611486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aliber, Ron Z. and Kindleberger, Charles P.. 2015. Manias, panics and crashes: a history of financial crises, seventh edition. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bagehot, Walter. 1873. Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market. London: Henry S. King and Co. Google Scholar
Barth, James. R., Caprio, Gerard Jr., and Levine, Ross. 2005. Rethinking Bank Regulation: Till Angels Govern. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bell, Stephen and Hindmoor, Andrew. 2015. “Masters of the universe but slaves of the market: Bankers and the great financial meltdown.” The British Journal of Politics and International Relations 17(1), 122.Google Scholar
Bhidé, Amar. 2009. “An Accident Waiting to Happen.” Critical Review 21(2–3): 211247.Google Scholar
Boot, Arnaud W. A. 2000. “Relationship Banking: What Do We Know?Journal of Financial Intermediation 9:725.Google Scholar
Boot, Arnaud W. A., Greenbaum, Stuart I, and Thakor, Anjan. 1993. “Reputation and Discretion in Financial Contracting.” American Economic Review 83: 1165–83.Google Scholar
Brewer, Elijah and Jagtiani, Julapa. 2013. “How Much Did Banks Pay to Become Too-Big-To-Fail and to Become Systemically Important?Journal of Financial Services Research 43(1): 135.Google Scholar
Broz, J. Lawrence. 1997. The International Origins of the Federal Reserve System. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Buchinsky, Moshe and Polak, Ben. 1993. “The Emergence of a National Capital Market in England.Journal of Economic History 53(1): 124.Google Scholar
Büthe, Tim. 2010. “Global Private Politics: A Research Agenda.” Business and Politics 12(3). DOI: 10.2202/1469-3569.1345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capie, Forrest, Fischer, Stanley, Goodhart, Charles and Schnadt, Norbert. 1994. The Future of Central Banking: The Tercentenary Symposium of the Bank of England. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cassis, Yasmin. 1985. “Bankers in English Society in the Late Nineteenth Century.” The Economic History Review, new series 38(2): 210–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chapman, Stanley D. 1984. The Rise of Merchant Banking. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Chiu, Iris H. Y. 2016. “Regulating Financial Benchmarks by ‘Proprietisation’: A Critical Discussion.” Capital Markets Law Journal 11(2): 191227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cleveland, Harold van B., and Huertas, Thomas F.. 1985. Citibank, 1812–1970. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Benjamin J. 1998. The Geography of Money. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Congleton, Roger D. 2012. “On the political economy and limits of crisis insurance: The case of the 2008–11 bailouts.” Public Choice 150: 399423.Google Scholar
Cukierman, Alex. 2013. “Monetary Policy and Institutions Before, During, and After the Global Financial Crisis.” Journal of Financial Stability 9: 373384.Google Scholar
Culpepper, Pepper D. and Reinke, Raphael. 2014. “Structural Power and Bank Bailouts in the United Kingdom and the United States.” Politics and Society 42(4): 427454.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Joseph. 1951. A Note on the Interpenetration of Anglo-American Finance, 1837–1841. Journal of Economic History 11(2): 140–47.Google Scholar
Dowd, Kevin. 1994. “Competitive Banking, Bankers' Clubs, and Bank Regulation.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 26(2): 289308.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. 1996. Globalizing Capital. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Einzig, Paul. 1935. World Finance Since 1914, London: Kegan Paul, Trench, Trübner, & Co. Google Scholar
Ferguson, Niall. 1999. The House of Rothschild: The World's Banker, 1849–1999. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Fichtner, Jan, Heemskerk, Eelke M., and Garcia-Bernardo, Javier. 2017. “Hidden Power of the Big Three? Passive Index Funds, Re-concentration of Corporate Ownership, and New Financial Risk.” Business and Politics 19(2): 298326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Andre G. 1998. ReORIENT: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Fratianni, Michele and Spinelli, Franco. 2006. “Did Genoa and Venice Kick a Financial Revolution in the Quattrocento?” Oesterreichische National Bank Working Paper 112.Google Scholar
Gallarotti, Giulio P. 1995. The Anatomy of an International Monetary Regime: The Classical Gold Standard 1880–1914. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Goodhart, Charles A. E. 1987. “Why Do Banks Need a Central Bank?” Oxford Economic Papers 39.Google Scholar
Goodhart, Charles A. E. 2010. “How Should We Regulate the Financial Sector?” The Future of Finance: The LSE Report. London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
Greenbaum, Stuart I. and Thakor, Anjan V.. 1995. Contemporary Financial Intermediation. New York: Dryden Press.Google Scholar
Gorton, Gary and Mullineaux, Donald J.. 1987. “The Joint Production of Confidence: Endogenous Regulation and Nineteenth-Century Commercial Bank Clearinghouses.” Journal of Money. Credit, and Banking 19(4): 457–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hakenes, Hendrik and Schnabel, Isabel. 2014. “Bank Bonuses and Bailouts.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 46(1) Supplement: 259288.Google Scholar
Hayes, Samuel L. III and Hubbard, Philip M.. 1990. Investment Banking: A Tale of Three Cities. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business Press.Google Scholar
Helleiner, Eric. 2002. The Making of National Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical Perspective. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hidy, Ralph W. 1941. “The Organization and Functions of Anglo-American Merchant Bankers, 1815–1860.” Journal of Economic History 1: 5366.Google Scholar
Hoag, Christopher. 2006. “The Atlantic Telegraph Cable and Capital Market Information Flows.” Journal of Economic History 66(2): 342–53.Google Scholar
Holton, Glyn A. 2004. “Defining Risk.” Financial Analysts Journal 60(6): 1925.Google Scholar
Hou, David and Skeie, David. 2014. “LIBOR: Origins, Economics, Crisis, Scandal, and Reform.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, no. 667.Google Scholar
Houben, Aerdt. 2013. “Aligning Macro- and Microprudential Supervision.” In Financial Supervision in the 21st Century edited by Kellermann, A. J.. Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg: 201–20.Google Scholar
Hu, Xiaolian. 2009. On the Roots of the Current Financial Crisis. Interdepartmental Group of Twenty-four Research Papers. http://173.254.126.101/~gtwofouo/wp-content/uploads/2014/03/Hu-1.pdf (accessed 4 January 2015).Google Scholar
Hughes, Joseph P. and Mester, Loretta J.. 1993. “A Quality and Risk-Adjusted Cost Function for Banks: Evidence on the ‘Too-Big-To-Fail’ Doctrine.” Journal of Productivity Analysis 4: 293315.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. Stanley. 1876. Money and the Mechanism of Exchange. Seventeenth Edition. London: Kegan. Paul, Trench, Trübner, & Co., Ltd., downloaded from the web, The Making Of The Modern World, 7 October 2014. Imprint of 1907.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Paul. 1987. The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Killick, John R. 1974. “Bolton Ogden & Co.: A Case Study in Anglo-American Trade, 1790–1850.” Business History Review 48(4): 501–19.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. Boston, MA: Hart, Schaffner & Marx; Houghton Mifflin. Available online from Library of Economics and Liberty, http://www.econlib.org/library/Knight/knRUP10.html (accessed 19 July 2012).Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. 1924. “Some Fallacies in the Interpretation of Social Cost.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 38: 582602.Google Scholar
May, Robert M., Levin, Simon A., and Sugihara, George. 2008. “Complex systems: Ecology for bankers.” Nature 451: 893895.Google Scholar
McNutt, Paul. 1999. “Public Goods and Club Goods.” Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. http://encyclo.findlaw.com/0750book.pdf (accessed 4 July 2012).Google Scholar
Mishkin, Fredrik S. 2006. “How Big a Problem is Too Big to Fail? A Review of Gary Stern and Ron Feldman's Too Big to Fail: The Hazards of Bank Bailouts.” Journal of Economic Literature XLIV: 9881004.Google Scholar
Moen, Jon Roger and Tallman, Ellis William. 1999. “Why Didn't the United States Establish a Central Bank until after the Panic of 1907?” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 99–16.Google Scholar
Morrison, Alan D. and Wilhelm, William J. Jr. 2004. “Partnership Firms, Reputation, and Human Capital.” American Economic Review 94(5): 1682–92.Google Scholar
Morrison, Alan D. and Wilhelm, William J. Jr. 2008. “The Demise of Investment-Banking Partnerships: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Finance 63(1): 311–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nair, Malavika. 2016. “Caste as self-regulatory club: evidence from a private banking system in nineteenth century India.” Journal of Institutional Economics 12(3): 677698.Google Scholar
Oatley, Thomas and Nabors, Robert. 1998. “Redistributive Cooperation: Market Failure, Wealth Transfers, and the Basle Accord.” International Organization 52(1): 3554.Google Scholar
Oatley, Thomas, Winecoff, W. Kindred, Pennock, Andrew, and Danzman, Sarah Bauerle. 2013. “The Political Economy of Global Finance: A Network Model.” Perspectives on Politics 11(1): 133153.Google Scholar
Odlyzko, Andrew. 2000. “The History of Communications and Its Implications for the Internet.” http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=235284 (accessed 16 June 2013).Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 2010. “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems.” American Economic Review 100(3): 641–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor and Ostrom, Vincent. 1977. “Public Goods and Public Choices.” In Alternatives for Delivering Public Services: Toward Improved Performance, edited by Savas, E. S.. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Penikas, Henry. 2012. “An Optimal Incentive Contract Preventing Excessive Risk-Taking by a Bank Manager.” Higher School of Economics Research Paper No. WP BRP 03/FE/2012.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl. 1944. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. 2001 ed. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Quaglia, Lucia. 2017. “Regulatory Power, Post-crisis Transatlantic Disputes and the Network Structure of the Financial Industry.” Business and Politics 19(2): 241266.Google Scholar
Rajan, Raghuram. G. 2006. Has Financial Development Made the World Riskier? European Financial Management 12(4): 499533.Google Scholar
Rasler, Karen and Thompson, William R. 2000. “Global Wars and the Political Economy of Structural Change.” In Handbook of War Studies II., edited by Midlarsky, M.. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Rogoff, Ken. 2009. This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rothschild, Emma. 1976. “Banks: The Coming Crisis.” The New York Review of Books, 27 May 1976: 1625.Google Scholar
Salter, Alexander. W. and Tarko, Vlad. 2017. “Polycentric Banking and Macroeconomic Stability.” Business and Politics 19(2): 365395.Google Scholar
Sandler, Todd and Tschirhart, John. 1997. “Club Theory: Thirty Years Later.” Public Choice 93: 335–55.Google Scholar
Schwartz, Herman Mark. 2017. “Club Goods, Intellectual Property Rights, and Profitability in the Information Economy.” Business and Politics 19(2): 191214.Google Scholar
Selmier, W. Travis II. 2013. “Members Only: The Decline of Partnerships and the Rise of Club Goods Structures in Investment Banking.” Working Paper W13–12. The Vincent and Elinor Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis. Available at https://www.researchgate.net/publication/257637034 (accessed 8 March 2017).Google Scholar
Selmier, W. Travis II. 2014. “Why Club Goods Proliferated in Investment Finance.” In Handbook of the International Political Economy of Monetary Relations, edited by Oatley, Thomas and Winecoff, W. Kindred. Cheltenham, U.K.; Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
Selmier, W. Travis II, Penikas, Henry, and Vasilyeva, Kseniya. 2014. “Financial Risk as a Good.” Procedia Computer Science 31: 115123.Google Scholar
Tilly, Richard H. 1989. “Banking Institutions in Historical and Comparative Perspective: Germany, Great Britain and the United States in the Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Century.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 145: 189209.Google Scholar
Tsingou, Eleni. 2015. “Club governance and the making of global financial rules.” Review of International Political Economy 22(2): 225256.Google Scholar
van Horne, J.C. 1985. “Of Financial Innovations and Excesses.” Journal of Finance 40(3): 620631.Google Scholar
Watkins, G. P. 1922. “Knight's Risk, Uncertainty and Profit.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 36(4): 682–90.Google Scholar
Weimer, David L. and Vining, Aidan R. 2005. Policy Analysis: Concepts and Practice. 4th ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Wicker, Elmus. 2000. Banking Panics of the Gilded Age. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Winecoff, W. Kindred. 2015. “Structural power and the global financial crisis: a network analytical approach.” Business and Politics 17(3), 495525.Google Scholar
Young, Kevin, Marple, Tim, and Heilman, James. 2017. “Beyond the Revolving Door: Advocacy Behavior and Social Distance to Financial Regulators.” Business and Politics 19(2): 327364.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1: Generic Goods typology and the Assumption of Risk

Figure 1

Table 2: 2 × 2 × 2 Cube of financial products and structures employed in managing risk

Figure 2

Chart 1: 100 year trends for Silver Price and Gold/Silver ratio [CPI-adjusted]

Sources: http://www.macrotrends.net/1470/historical-silver-prices-100-year-chart; http://www.macrotrends.net/1441/gold-to-silver-ratio (Accessed June 15, 2016).