Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-kw2vx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-04T18:23:51.937Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Surviving Elections: Election Violence, Incumbent Victory and Post-Election Repercussions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 December 2016

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

It is often assumed that government-sponsored election violence increases the probability that incumbent leaders remain in power. Using cross-national data, this article shows that election violence increases the probability of incumbent victory, but can generate risky post-election dynamics. These differences in the consequences of election violence reflect changes in the strategic setting over the course of the election cycle. In the pre-election period, anti-incumbent collective action tends to be focused on the election itself, either through voter mobilization or opposition-organized election boycotts. In the post-election period, by contrast, when a favorable electoral outcome is no longer a possibility, anti-government collective action more often takes the form of mass political protest, which in turn can lead to costly repercussions for incumbent leaders.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2016 

In some countries, political participation is a dangerous business. In Hun Sen’s Cambodia, where he has been in power for most of the past three decades, government-sponsored election violence and intimidation are among the tools the incumbent Cambodian People’s Party has used to remain in power.Footnote 1 As Sen himself threatened: ‘I not only weaken the opposition, I’m going to make them dead […] and if anyone is strong enough to try to hold a demonstration, I will beat all those dogs and put them in a cage’.Footnote 2 In Belarus, facing protests after the corrupt 2006 elections, President Alexander Lukashenko openly vowed to ‘break the neck immediately–like a duckling’ of any demonstrators.Footnote 3 He has been in power since 1994. Sen and Lukashenko are just two of dozens of incumbent leaders who have used election violence–including physical harassment of the opposition and significant violence involving civilian deaths–before, during or after elections.Footnote 4

Election violence is often discussed in the context of other methods to manipulate elections, such as fraud, or as a subtype of political repression more generally.Footnote 5 Although governments seeking to rig elections often mix methods of manipulation, we focus in this article on government-sponsored election violence because it is a form of election manipulation that is distinct from–and has generally received less attention than–election fraud, corruption and vote buying.Footnote 6 As our data show, not all governments that use election violence also use fraud, and vice versa. Among methods of election manipulation, violence poses the greatest threat to the personal safety of the opposition and voters, and it may have distinct causes and consequences from political repression more generally. Moreover, government-sponsored election violence and intimidation are widespread and occur across nearly all regime types.Footnote 7

It is often assumed that election violence is used precisely because it works in favor of those who use it.Footnote 8 Although research on election violence is growing rapidly, it is not known whether election violence–like election fraud–actually helps incumbent governments to stay in power, either in terms of their ability to win elections or to withstand post-election challenges.Footnote 9 We explore whether election violence actually ‘works’ for incumbents by focusing on the effects of pre-election violence during two points of the election cycle when an incumbent’s hold on power is most likely to be threatened: (1) the election itself, which they could lose outright and (2) the post-election period, when protest movements can lead incumbents to resign, hold new elections or otherwise make significant concessions.

The historical record reveals that election violence is not a guaranteed strategy for maintaining power. Panel A of Figure 1 plots all instances of government-sponsored pre-election violence between 1950 and 2010 and shows that government-sponsored election violence is not always followed by incumbent victory. Leaders can also face challenges to their rule in the immediate post-election period, in part because elections (especially manipulated or violent elections) can facilitate post-election protests against the government. Panel B shows that when post-election protests occur, they have often been followed by significant costs to the incumbent (which we label ‘government concessions’), including the annulment of election results, incumbent resignation or, in a few cases, a military coup. In short, leaders may use election violence because they believe it will work in the short term, but violence does not guarantee that incumbents will win elections––and even when incumbents win, the use of violence as a tactic of manipulation can increase post-election challenges to their rule.

Fig. 1 Trends in election violence and its consequences over time Note: based on data from the National Elections Across Democracy and Autocracy dataset (Hyde and Marinov Reference Hyde and Marinov2012). Elections with pre-election violence (Panel A) are those in which the government harassed the opposition or used violence against civilians. Elections with post-election concessions (Panel B) are those which are followed by election annulment, incumbent resignation or a coup. We explain these data in more detail in the empirical section of the article.

We evaluate the relationship between an incumbent government’s decision to use election violence and its ability to withstand challenges to its rule using a unique election-event dataset that measures pre-election violence, post-election protest and post-election concessions of incumbent power. The full dataset illustrated in Figure 1 contains 1,322 potentially competitive elections in 122 countries, including 339 elections in which the incumbent government used pre-election violence.Footnote 10

Drawing on these data, we show that a government’s decision to use election violence in the pre-election period–much like the decision to use fraud–increases the probability that the incumbent wins the election. We also show that incumbents who use pre-election violence are more likely to face post-election protests. These protests, in turn, increase the risk of costly power concessions. In fact, incumbents who face post-election protests are more than three times as likely to be forced to resign or hold new elections. Moreover, government-sponsored violence against protestors does not improve an incumbent’s chances of surviving these post-election challenges. In short, even though election violence has historically increased an incumbent’s chances of winning an election, the longer-term consequences of using violence include an increased risk of post-election protests, which can result in serious post-election repercussions.

These differences in the short- and medium-term effects of election violence reflect the changing options available to citizens and opposition parties over the course of an election cycle. Within electoral regimes, at least in theory, elections represent a legitimate and institutionalized mechanism through which individuals and parties can compete for power. Opposition parties and individual voters who are dissatisfied with the regime have numerous options in the pre-electoral period, most obviously supporting an opposition party or candidate and trying to gain elected office through legitimate means. Incumbent-sponsored election violence can be used to coerce would-be opposition supporters into staying home or intimidate them into voting for the regime. Additionally, election violence (like fraud) may increase the probability of incumbent victory through another mechanism: by provoking opposition parties to boycott. Although winning a boycotted election may carry significant reputational consequences for the government, a well-executed election boycott also makes an incumbent victory a near certainty.Footnote 11

Thus violence makes incumbent victory more likely by provoking election boycotts and biasing voter turnout in favor of the incumbent.Footnote 12 If the incumbent wins the election, individuals wishing to challenge the incumbent’s hold on power must either accept defeat or take to the streets in protest. But using pre-election violence can make post-election protest more likely, and post-election protest, in turn, increases the likelihood that the incumbent will be forced to make power concessions.Footnote 13

This seemingly inconsistent behavior of the opposition–manipulated into conceding the election yet willing to engage in risky post-election anti-regime protest–makes sense when one considers that the pre- and post-election periods have different focal points for collective action.Footnote 14 Even when the government blatantly employs pre-election violence, pre-election protest aimed at ousting the government is rare for many of the same reasons that collective action against repressive governments is rare in general. In the absence of a clear focal point or knowledge about how many other citizens are willing to challenge a repressive government, any individual effort to challenge the regime is likely to come with ‘high costs coupled with very low chances of success’.Footnote 15 Additionally, before elections, opponents of the government still have the ability to challenge the incumbent using formal and proximate institutional means, either by winning votes or by attempting to undermine the election’s legitimacy with a boycott. Citizens may prefer to wait and see whether other people vote, how many others participate in a boycott, whether the incumbent wins (and by how much), or how much violence (and fraud) is ultimately used.

Pre-election protest is rare, and when it does occur, it is usually in an effort to pressure the government to improve the quality of the electoral process rather than to fundamentally challenge the regime. In the post-election period, however, citizens and parties have gained information about the incumbent’s behavior and popularity. The range of potential options has also narrowed considerably, and protest is often the only remaining option when elections have failed to unseat a corrupt, fraudulent or violent incumbent government.

This article builds on recent work on election manipulation and authoritarianism as well as ‘democratization by elections’ in authoritarian regimes.Footnote 16 These literatures debate the role that elections play in political transitions, including whether election manipulation is a sign of democratization or a tool that electoral autocrats use to stay in power. By examining the consequences of election violence for the governments that use it, our study contributes to related research agendas that focus on the relationship between violent strategies and regime type or the role of violence in explaining political transitions. Our central contribution is to show that, although government-sponsored election violence increases the chances that incumbents win the election, violence can undermine the longer-term benefits of election victory by generating risky post-election dynamics such as mass protest.

The article presents the argument in greater detail, focusing on the different dynamics in pre- and post-election periods. We evaluate the empirical implications of our argument in both periods of the election cycle using global data on all potentially competitive elections from 1981 to 2004. We conclude with a discussion of the study’s broader implications and potential limitations.

The Argument

Although most incumbents facing re-election would prefer to win outright and avoid paying the costs of manipulating an election, some governments nevertheless resort to illicit tactics like election violence. Recent research shows that government-sponsored election violence is particularly likely when incumbents think they might lose or are uncertain about their own popularity.Footnote 17 However, existing studies of election violence do not make clear whether violence is an effective strategy for manipulating elections. Is violence a surefire tactic for incumbents wishing to avoid a serious electoral challenge? Or is the use of violence akin to gambling for resurrection, with a very low probability of success? The answer to these questions hinges in part on how opposition groups and voters respond to election violence, in both the pre- and post-election periods.

How Pre-Election Violence Can Help Incumbents Win Elections

We argue that election violence makes incumbent victory more likely through at least two mechanisms: by making opposition party boycotts more likely and (relatedly) by manipulating who turns out to vote in a manner that benefits the incumbent. Opposition-organized election boycotts can occur for many reasons.Footnote 18 Some parties boycott to save face when they realize they are unlikely to win. More commonly, boycotts are a costly signal aimed at discrediting the electoral process, drawing international attention to the manipulation of an election, or signaling opposition to a violent or illegitimate regime.Footnote 19

Government use of election violence in the pre-election period also signals that the election is unlikely to be free and fair. Under some conditions, a boycott can allow opposition parties to minimize additional physical harm to their supporters while drawing public attention to the manipulation of the election process. As Emily Beaulieu explains:

Opposition leaders hope to force the incumbent into holding fairer elections in the future by [boycotting]. Furthermore, if the kind of manipulation the incumbent is using contains elements of violent repression–or if the opposition suspects that Election Day manipulation will include violence on the part of the incumbent–a boycott may be an attractive option for reducing harm to opposition supporters.Footnote 20

Several accounts suggest that government persecution of opposition candidates is a significant driver of election boycotts, although this relationship has not been formally tested. As Staffan Lindberg argues, ‘opposition parties tend to stay out of presidential elections where politically motivated violence is systematic and/or widespread’.Footnote 21 Beaulieu shows that opposition-initiated pre-election boycotts have been more likely when civil liberties have been curtailed, election fraud was anticipated and the opposition was harassed.Footnote 22 We expect that violence increases the likelihood that opposition groups boycott elections, and that boycotts, in turn, increase the likelihood that the incumbent government ‘wins’ the election.

Opposition boycotts may undermine the government’s legitimacy in the long term and even result in higher-quality elections in the next cycle.Footnote 23 This is why boycotts can be a rational strategy for opposition parties. However, in the short term, boycotts increase the probability that the incumbent will win the election. By asking their supporters to stay home, boycotting parties reduce their potential for representation, and in so doing reduce electoral competition.Footnote 24 Boycotts are more likely in the presence of election violence or fraud, though in theory, governments could react to an election boycott (or any other form of opposition-organized collective action) with additional fraud and violence.Footnote 25 Although in practice, boycotts should diminish the need to use illegitimate means to win an election, our argument does not rule out the possibility that violence and the decision to boycott are iterated throughout the election cycle.Footnote 26

A second way in which pre-election violence can increase the probability of incumbent victory is through voter intimidation aimed at influencing who turns out to vote on election day and who they ultimately vote for. While ballot box stuffing and similar forms of election fraud distort official turnout figures, violence can also change voting behavior in a variety of ways that advantage the incumbent. Violence can convince opposition voters to stay home on election day, reducing turnout in favor of the opposition.Footnote 27 It can also coerce would-be opposition voters into voting for the incumbent out of fear of reprisal for supporting the opposition. And it can threaten voters who would otherwise prefer to abstain, and convince them to turn out to vote for the incumbent. These methods of intimidation are not mutually exclusive and may require violations of ballot secrecy, or at least knowledge of who is likely to vote for an opposition candidate.Footnote 28 For example, Lisa Blaydes notes in reference to Egyptian elections, ‘in addition to positive inducements for voting, there are also reports of the use of hired thugs to force voters to choose particular candidates […] [and] they are also used to prevent supporters of other candidates from voting at all’.Footnote 29 An international human rights group reported similar efforts in advance of the 2010 elections in Ethiopia:

In the weeks leading up to the polls […] new methods [were] used by the ruling Ethiopian People’s Revolutionary Democratic Front (EPRDF) to intimidate voters in the capital […] apparently because of government concerns of a low election turnout […] officials and militia […] went house to house telling citizens to register to vote and to vote for the ruling party or face reprisals […] [As one voter said], ‘Intimidation to register and to vote for the ruling party is everywhere […]’.Footnote 30

We expect that pre-election violence has historically biased elections by increasing voter turnout in support of the incumbent through intimidation and/or decreasing turnout in favor of the opposition through voter suppression. Both outcomes, which are not mutually exclusive, increase the likelihood that the incumbent wins the election.Footnote 31

How Pre-Election Violence Increases the Risk of Post-Election Protests

Even if a strategy of election violence helps a threatened government ‘win’ an election, we argue that such a strategy may be myopic and can trigger significant consequences in the post-election period that can undermine some or all of the benefits of winning. Specifically, the use of violence in the pre-election period makes post-election protest more likely, which in turn can bring about significant political costs to the incumbent government.

Citizens sometimes respond to the state’s attempts at election manipulation through fraud and violence by expressing their dissent through non-institutional means, frequently by protesting in the streets.Footnote 32 Although there are some cases in which citizens amass in the streets to challenge a regime prior to an election, anti-government post-election protests are much more common.Footnote 33 Prominent examples of protest include the ‘color revolutions’, and the 2009 Iranian elections.Footnote 34 We anticipate that the opposition’s motivation to engage in election-related mass protest is much stronger in the post-election period in part because several options that are available in the pre-election period are no longer on the table.Footnote 35 Prior to the election, citizens or parties unhappy with the government can work to mobilize voters to support opposition candidates on election day. Or, opposition parties dissatisfied with the election process can engage in an election boycott. Once the election has taken place, however, public protest is one of the few remaining forms of dissent; post-election protest becomes the most likely avenue for anti-government mobilization. Many protesters acknowledge this difference between the pre- and post-election periods explicitly. For instance, several participants in the opposition protests and violence following the 2007 Kenyan elections noted to Human Rights Watch interviewers that they ‘were merely doing by force what they had been denied a chance to do through the ballot box’.Footnote 36

Of course, protest does not automatically follow elections that are corrupted or violent. For protests to emerge as a challenge to the incumbent government’s hold on power in the post-election period, citizens must solve a collective action problem. This is particularly difficult in repressive regimes.Footnote 37 Tucker describes the problem:

Most members of society would likely agree that society as a whole would be better off with a less abusive and appropriately restrained state […]. Achieving this goal in states where such abusive actions regularly take place, however, requires confronting these abuses and attempting to stop them.Footnote 38

Because protesters–and especially those citizens who initiate protest–face significant risk of bodily harm, many cases in which citizens are unhappy with their government do not result in protest because it is individually rational to stay home.Footnote 39 Tucker goes on to argue that elections with major election fraud can help solve collective action problems by ‘lowering the costs of participating in anti-regime actions’ after elections, making protests more likely to be successful in bringing down the incumbent government.Footnote 40 As the number of protestors grows, each individual protester is less likely to be punished, while the probability of successful protest (that is, bringing down the government or forcing political concessions) increases.Footnote 41 This logic is consistent with other work that implicitly or explicitly employs the same model in which elections marred by fraud or violence provide a focal point allowing citizens to solve a collective action problem and protest against the regime.Footnote 42 These arguments are consistent with our prediction that pre-election violence is one factor that will increase the likelihood of post-election protests.

Post-election protests occur in about 15 per cent of the elections in our study and, if we are correct, should increase the probability that the newly re-elected incumbent will eventually make substantial power concessions, including the annulment of election results, the holding of new elections, resignation or removal by force. For example, in South Korea in 1960, President Syngman Rhee ran unopposed following the unexpected death of his challenger. Widespread fraud was documented during the election process, including the discovery of a document announcing that ‘police will use force if necessary to see that the voters vote right’.Footnote 43 People took to the streets to protest Rhee’s election, steadfast in the face of a violent government response. After six weeks of protest and at least 145 deaths, Rhee stepped down.Footnote 44

Protests can lead to significant costs for the incumbent–including resignation, annulment of the election results, military coup or new elections–for several reasons.Footnote 45 Unlike most elections, protests represent a publicly coordinated challenge to the regime. They can signal a government’s vulnerability or weakness while also demonstrating the potential strength or resolve of political opponents. And protests of sufficient size and strength can also provoke other challengers–inside or outside the government–to take advantage of the incumbent’s unpopularity and any public moment of weakness.

In some cases, protests can also send a signal to external pro-democracy advocates, such as powerful states or international organizations. Because post-election protests, especially of the pro-democracy variety, tend to attract global media attention, they can increase the chances that outside actors will pressure the government to change its behavior, support protestors directly or otherwise damage the international reputation of the incumbent government, as happened in Ukraine in 2004 and Ethiopia in 2005.Footnote 46

Because mass public protests can threaten to bring down governments after elections, it is not surprising that governments sometimes decide to respond to election protests with violence in an effort to suppress dissent. In Albania, for example, the 1991 legislative election sparked protests against the government, as thousands of people gathered to protest the government’s monopolization of state resources and the media to disadvantage the opposition.Footnote 47 Violence broke out in President Aila’s hometown of Shkoder when police shot to death Arben Broxi, an opposition activist, killed two other protesters and injured fifty-eight. Meanwhile, in the capital city, protesters occupied the communist party headquarters and the police threatened to blow up the building with the activists inside.Footnote 48 Protesters amassed outside. Army troops and tanks were sent out to disburse the crowd and threatened to open fire if protesters did not leave. Several people were shot; three were killed.Footnote 49

Though governments use violence against post-election demonstrators in an effort to crush public opposition to the regime, we expect violence at this stage in the election cycle to be less incumbent sustaining than pre-election violence. Before elections, government violence seeks to manipulate an election outcome in the incumbent’s favor by reducing election competition, provoking actions that reduce the immediate election competition. The objective of post-election violence, by contrast, is frequently to undermine an already mobilized mass movement protesting the regime. Breaking the opposition’s resolve at this stage is likely to be a more difficult task. Post-election violence against demonstrators is inherently very public, and may be as likely to increase the resolve of anti-regime protesters as to deter them. Once protests are in motion, the opposition has, by definition, already overcome the initial collective action problem that is most likely to limit their success. Moreover, since protests are often a response to pre-election violence, fraud and other forms of election manipulation, protesters may have already factored the threat of violence into their decision to protest.

Anecdotal reports suggest that many protesters acknowledge this risk. For example, Mehdi Karrubi, an opposition leader and participant in the 2009 Iranian post-election protests, explained his decision to continue protesting despite the risk of arrest and likely abuse in prison:

They’ve attacked my house twice and broke all the windows. They’ve shut down my office, my newspaper, and my party. They beat up one of my children. Two of my children are banned from leaving the country. They’ve arrested many people who were close to me. Any member of the Parliament who comes to visit me is chased and attacked. I’m not sure whether they’re going to arrest me or not, but […] we are all ready to pay any price for our struggle for the people of Iran.Footnote 50

If individuals within a country are able to overcome the collective action problems associated with organizing against a repressive government, and are resolved enough to protest despite significant risk of personal harm, dispersing them is not trivial. Given these factors, we expect that once post-election protests occur, violence against demonstrators is not likely to increase (and may decrease) the likelihood that the incumbent stays in power. Table 1 summarizes the argument and its observable implications.

Table 1 The Argument

Empirical Analysis

Data

To evaluate the argument we use the National Elections Across Democracy and Autocracy (NELDA) dataset on the characteristics of national elections all over the world.Footnote 51 The NELDA data cover all election events, including more specific measures of election violence, incumbent victory and the dynamics of election protest than have previously been available for all regions.Footnote 52 These data contain information on competitive elections for national office for all sovereign states with a population greater than 500,000, including information on election protest and the existence of several types of election violence.Footnote 53 Temporal limitations of other data used in our model limit the sample to 1981–2004.

NELDA data sources include news wire reports, newspaper archives, academic research including the data handbooks on elections edited by Dieter Nohlen,Footnote 54 archives for specific countries and from intergovernmental organizations such as the Inter-Parliamentary Union, and other sources that are listed in the dataset’s codebook.Footnote 55 Each round of a multi-round election is coded separately. Because post-election protest could follow any round in an election, we treat each round as a separate observation.Footnote 56 For all estimates (below), we exclude the long-term developed democracies (eleven), which are outside the scope of our theory, and elections in which competition is not permitted.Footnote 57

These data are more fine-grained than studies that rely on nationwide aggregate measures of repression or protest that are unable to disaggregate types or targets of repression, or distinguish whether protests or violence are related to an election (as opposed to simply taking place during the calendar year of an election).Footnote 58 In contrast, we measure election-related violence that is targeted at opposition groups and civilians in the pre-election period, and distinguish it from the use of violence by the government against post-election protesters. We also distinguish empirically between election fraud and violence.

The Effect of Pre-Election Violence on Election Victory

This section shows that pre-election violence against opposition supporters, candidates and the citizenry is strongly associated with an increased probability that the incumbent wins the election. For each election round, we use the NELDA data to code a binary measure of whether the Incumbent Wins,Footnote 59 limiting the sample to elections in which the incumbent runs. This rule includes elections in which the incumbent prime minister or president runs for re-election. In order to measure whether an incumbent used violence prior to an election we use Pre-Election Violence,Footnote 60 from Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski,Footnote 61 which equals 1 if an incumbent harassed or used violence against opposition members or civilians prior to or during the election, and 0 otherwise.Footnote 62 Although opposition harassment (which often includes acts of violence) and civilian violence may sometimes be used separately, our hypotheses make predictions about both violence against voters and opposition groups, so we combine the two in our analysis. In practice, incumbents often target both opposition groups and voters with violence in an effort to suppress competition.Footnote 63 The combination of these two categories of violence is consistent with other published work.Footnote 64 In the Appendix, we also show separate estimates for opposition harassment and civilian violence.Footnote 65

In order to account for the possibility that governments may use violence in response to expected political competition, we include Victory Uncertain if the incumbent made statements prior to the election that suggested she was not confident of victory, or if pre-election polls were unfavorable for the incumbent.Footnote 66

Even after accounting for election competition, it is plausible that more democratic leaders will face a more mobilized opposition and stronger constraints on the use of repression.Footnote 67 To address this source of bias, we include a control for a country’s political institutions.Footnote 68 An additional concern is that election violence is more likely in repressive regimes, and our models estimate the effect of overall repression, rather than election-specific violence. To address this issue, we control for a government’s pre-existing propensity to engage in political repression.

To measure political institutions, we include the Polity2 variable from the Polity IV project.Footnote 69 Polity2 is a twenty-one-point index that ranges from the most autocratic (−10) to the most democratic (10) political institutions. Pre-existing levels of government repression are measured with Physical Integrity, from the CIRI dataset,Footnote 70 which is an additive index of government-sponsored repressive activity, including murder, torture, political imprisonment and forced disappearance. It ranges from 0 (no government respect for these four rights) to 8 (full government respect for these four rights). For both of these variables, we use the average value from the three years prior to the election in order to ensure that these measures are not themselves determined by election violence.Footnote 71 Summary statistics for all variables are shown in the Appendix.

We first estimate a logit model in which the dependent variable is a binary measure of whether or not the incumbent wins the election (Incumbent Wins):

(1) $$ P(Incumbent\,Wins_{{ij}} )=f(\alpha {\plus}\beta \,Election\,Violence_{{ij}} {\plus}\varphi X_{{ij}} ),$$

where Incumbent Wins indicates whether the incumbent wins in country i in election j, and φX ij is a vector of control variables. In the Appendix we also re-estimate all models with country fixed and random effects.

Except where noted, standard errors are clustered by country to account for within-country correlation of errors. Additional control variables include GDP (log) and Population (log) from the World Development Indicators as additional controls, because a country’s population and wealth may influence an incumbent’s election strategies.Footnote 72 Leader-specific factors like time in office and experience may also influence an incumbent’s strategy. All models include Leader Tenure, which is the incumbent leader’s number of days in office, and Leader Age, from the Archigos dataset.Footnote 73 Civil War is included from the Major Episodes of Political Violence datasetFootnote 74 because internal conflict is correlated with human rights violations.Footnote 75

Where appropriate, models include measures of pre-election expectations of Fraud and an aggregate annual measure of Demonstrations. We include controls for these variables to ensure that we are capturing election violence, and not inadvertently using election violence as a proxy for other related events. Fraud measures whether there were concerns, before the election, that it would not be free and fair, and allows us to evaluate the relative effects of fraud compared to, and in conjunction with, violence.Footnote 76 As a proxy for the overall likelihood of any kind of Demonstrations in a given country, we include the total number of any type of anti-government demonstrations, anti-government strikes and riots during the year based on Banks CNTS coding.Footnote 77 Unless otherwise noted, these country- and election-specific control variables are used in models across several dependent variables, in part for simplicity, and in part because they are intended to capture background characteristics that may influence the dynamics of election behavior.

One potential alternative to our argument (that violence provokes boycotts that reduce competition) is that governments are more likely to use election violence against a weak opposition. If this is the case, then a positive relationship between pre-election violence and incumbent victory could be spurious. In our model Demonstrations is a proxy for the propensity of citizens to protest. However, to measure pre-election mobilization more precisely, Table 2, Model 2 includes Pre-Election Protest, which takes a value of 1 if there were any election-related anti-government protests in the period before an election took place.Footnote 78 This allows us to account for the extent to which the opposition is mobilized against the government prior to the election.Footnote 79

Table 2 The Effect of Pre-Election Violence on Incumbent Victory

Note: robust clustered standard errors in parentheses. **p<0.01, *p<0.05.

The results presented in Model 1, Table 2 indicate that pre-election violence, on average, increases an incumbent’s likelihood of winning the election. When she uses election violence, the incumbent has a 50.9 per cent greater predicted probability of winning the election (from 0.37 to 0.55). This is similar to the predicted effect of fraud, which results in a 51.3 per cent increase in the probability of victory. Our results remain nearly identical in Model 2, suggesting that the effect of fraud and violence on the election outcome is not explained by levels of opposition strength. Because fraud and violence are at times used together (correlation=0.36), we exclude fraud in Model 3 and find consistent effects of violence. Figure 2 shows the simulated increase in the probability of Incumbent Wins given a change in each independent variable from its minimum to its maximum level, holding all other variables at the mean (based on Model 1). It illustrates graphically that pre-election violence is associated with election victory for the incumbent at about the same rate as fraud.

Fig. 2 Estimated effects of explanatory variables on incumbent victory Note: points indicate the simulated increase in the probability of Incumbent Wins given a change in each independent variable from its minimum to its maximum level, holding all other variables at their mean. Lines indicate the 95 per cent confidence intervals for predictions. Estimated using a logit model with robust clustered standard errors.

Next, we evaluate whether the data are consistent with our argument that the success of Pre-Election Violence results in part because violence increases the probability of boycotts. We create Boycott, which equals 1 if some opposition leaders boycotted the election and 0 otherwise,Footnote 80 and estimate a logit model:

(2) $$P(Boycott_{{ij}} )=f(\alpha {\plus}\beta \,Election\,Violence_{{ij}} {\plus}\varphi X_{{ij}} ),$$

where Boycott indicates if there was a boycott in country i and election j, and φX ij is a vector of control variables. Since boycotts usually occur before instances of fraud, we exclude fraud as a control from this model to avoid post-treatment bias. To confirm that boycotts favor the incumbent at the polls, we also estimate a logit model of Incumbent Wins, with the addition of Boycott as an explanatory variable to the model shown in Equation 1.

Table 3 presents estimates consistent with the hypothesis that boycotts are part of the reason election violence works in the short term. In Column 1, we estimate that Pre-Election Violence increases the probability of Boycotts by about 80 per cent (from 0.05 to 0.09). In Column 2, we confirm that boycotts in turn increase the likelihood of incumbent victory by about 45 per cent (from 0.38 to 0.55). By comparing these predictions with those from Table 2, we conclude that the effect of Pre-Election Violence on Boycotts explains about 18 per cent of the effect of Pre-Election Violence on Incumbent Wins.Footnote 81

Table 3 The Effect of Pre-Election Violence on Boycott and Victory

Note: robust clustered standard errors in parentheses. **p<0.01, *p<0.05, +p<0.1.

One might be concerned that these estimates are driven by the effect of boycotts in non-violent elections. Boycott strategies might be different in violent versus non-violent elections. In non-violent elections, candidates may boycott in order to avoid an obvious election defeat, particularly when there are expectations of widespread fraud.Footnote 82 However in violent elections, opposition candidates often boycott despite facing an electorally threatened incumbent.Footnote 83 To assess whether boycotts are effective in both violent and non-violent elections, in Column 3 of Table 3 we include an interaction between Boycott and Pre-Election Violence. The results confirm that boycotts increase Incumbent Victory in both violent and non-violent elections. We plot these predictions in Figure 3.

Fig. 3 Probability of incumbent victory in violent and boycotted elections Note: predicted probability of incumbent victory for all values of Boycott and Pre-Election Violence with 95 per cent confidence intervals. Predicted from Column 3 in Table 3. All control variables set at mean.

We next evaluate the relationship between pre-election violence and turnout to determine whether violence is changing voter behavior to the advantage of the incumbent. We argue that government-sponsored violence in the pre-election period should alter voter turnout in a manner that benefits the incumbent, decreasing votes by the opposition and/or increasing votes by regime supporters. It is easy to find anecdotal reports of electoral violence and intimidation influencing turnout, though the effect of violence on turnout can be positive or negative. For example, as one opposition member in Ethiopia was quoted during the 2010 elections amid predictions of high turnout, ‘A lot of soldiers are around. It’s a sign of intimidation of the local population to vote for the government.’Footnote 84 In contrast, during the 2015 Sri Lankan presidential elections, the Centre for Monitoring Electoral Violence predicted low turnout in some regions due to ‘the government instilling fear among the electorate by deploying the army in the guise of providing security’.Footnote 85

Evaluating whether the effect of violence on turnout benefits the incumbent is challenging for several reasons, including the fact that cross-national data cannot document turnout by individual vote choice, which is really what our ideal test would include. Moreover, there are weaknesses in existing data since violent regimes may also be more likely to falsify official turnout results.Footnote 86

Recognizing these limitations, we use two approaches to evaluate this hypothesis. First, we evaluate the effect of Pre-Election Violence on turnout using cross-national data to see if we can observe aggregate effects of violence on turnout. In order to evaluate the effects of Pre-Election Violence on turnout levels, we create Voter Turnout, which equals the percentage of registered voters that casts a ballot.Footnote 87 We estimate a linear model of Turnout and a logit model of Incumbent Wins which are identical to Equation 1 but add Turnout:

(3) $$Turnout_{{ij}} =f(\alpha {\plus}\beta \,Election\,Violence_{{ij}} {\plus}\varphi X_{{ij}} ),$$

where Turnout ij indicates the rate of voter turnout in country i and election j, and φX ij is a vector of control variables. In addition, we control for institutional variables that are likely to affect voter turnout. We include Compulsory Voting, which equals 1 if there was a law requiring citizens to vote and 0 otherwise.Footnote 88 We also control for Multiple Rounds, which equals 1 if there were multiple rounds of voting.Footnote 89 To account for additional institutional confounds, we also include fixed effects estimates in the Appendix, which are consistent.

Column 1 of Table 4 shows the relationship between Pre-Election Violence and Turnout. The estimates provide some limited support for our argument about violence being used to coerce support. Column 1 shows that when incumbents use violence, there is a positive effect on voter turnout, though this effect is only significant at the 10 per cent level. These results provide suggestive evidence that violence can increase turnout in favor of the incumbent. We recognize, however, that interpreting this result is challenging given the fact that the effect of violence may also be to lower turnout among opposition supporters.Footnote 90

Table 4 The Effect of Pre-Election Violence on Turnout

Note: robust clustered standard errors in parentheses. Excludes cases where the incumbent lost the election and exited office. **p<0.01, *p<0.05, +p<0.1.

Column 2 indicates that higher turnout is associated with a higher probability that the incumbent government wins the election. Column 3 includes the interaction between Voter Turnout and Pre-Election Violence. The probability that the Incumbent Wins when Voter Turnout and Pre-Election Violence are set at their maximums is over 0.75 compared to the probability (0.32) that the incumbent wins without the use of pre-election violence (but maximum turnout).Footnote 91 This result is consistent with the argument that pre-election violence results in changes in voter turnout that benefit the incumbent.Footnote 92 Figure 4 shows the effect of turnout on the probability that Incumbent Wins by whether or not there was Pre-Election Violence, with all other variables held constant at mean values.

Fig. 4 The effect of Turnout on Incumbent Wins Note: estimated effect of Pre-Election Violence on the probability of Incumbent Wins at various levels of turnout. Vertical lines indicate the 95 per cent confidence interval.

These results imply that when pre-election violence occurs, higher turnout is associated with an increased probability of incumbent victory. Combined with the survey-level data in the Appendix, this suggests that incumbents are often successful at using violence and intimidation to ‘persuade’ voters to turn out and vote in their favor. The results also suggest that this strategy works for incumbents: when the government does not use pre-election violence, increasing turnout has no effect on incumbent victory. However, when the government employs pre-election violence, higher turnout is associated with a higher probability of incumbent victory. This is consistent with our hypothesis that violence shifts turnout among opposition and incumbent supporters in ways that increase vote totals for the incumbent.

As a complementary approach, we include a separate set of regressions using individual survey data. Using Afrobarometer and Latin America Barometer survey results, we estimate whether reported turnout differs between respondents who claim to support opposition parties and those who claim to support incumbent parties. The results show that respondents in violent elections who support opposition parties are less likely to report having voted than citizens who support incumbent parties. We discuss these results in more detail alongside the estimates in the Appendix.

The Effect of Post-Election Protests on Power Concessions

This section explores whether pre-election violence drives mass protests, and whether such protests increase the likelihood that the incumbent will make power concessions. Election Protests equals 1 if there were election-related riots and protests after the election, and 0 otherwise.Footnote 93 We estimate the effect of Pre-Election Violence on Election Protests in country i and election j using a logit model with clustered standard errors and the same set of control variables described above:

(4) $$P(Election\,Protests_{{ij}} )=f(\alpha {\plus}\beta \,Election\,Violence_{{ij}} {\plus}\varphi X_{{ij}} ),$$

where φX ij is a vector of control variables. Since our primary interest is in how violence affects incumbent behavior, we exclude cases where the incumbent lost the election and exited office.Footnote 94

The estimates in Column 1 of Table 5 confirm that pre-election violence–like fraud–significantly predicts the outbreak of post-election protests. Violence increases the estimated probability of protests by 0.21.Footnote 95 For comparison, the use of fraud increases the probability of protests by 0.10.

Table 5 The Effect of Protests on Power Concessions

Note: robust clustered standard errors in parentheses. Excludes cases where the incumbent lost the election and exited office. **p<0.01, *p<0.05, +p<0.1.

In Columns 2 through 5 we evaluate the relationship between protest and the probability that the newly re-elected incumbent makes concessions after the election. Power Concessions equals 1 if the incumbent is removed from power by means other than the loss of the election–including through resignation, coup or other non-electoral means–or if the initial election results were annulled and new elections held.Footnote 96

(5) $$P(Power\,Concessions_{{ij}} )=f(\alpha {\plus}\beta \,Election\,Protest_{{ij}} {\plus}\varphi X_{{ij}} ),$$

where φX ij is a vector of control variables. Again we exclude cases where the incumbent lost the election and exited office. We again account for the possibility that governments are more likely to use violence against a strong opposition by including Pre-Election Protest as a proxy for how mobilized the opposition was against the government prior to the election.

Column 2 of Table 5 reveals an interesting story. Protests increase the probability that an incumbent will make power concessions in the post-election period by more than 500 per cent.Footnote 97 Moreover, Column 3 suggests that using violence against protesters does not change the likelihood of concessions. Violence Against Protesters equals 1 if an incumbent used violence against demonstrators protesting the election, and 0 otherwise. The coefficient is statistically insignificant from 0. Although we cannot rule out the possibility that the more virulent protests are being repressed, this lack of a relationship suggests that post-election violence may not be an especially successful way for the incumbent to crack down on threats to her hold on power once post-election protests have begun. In Column 4, we include an interaction between Pre-Election Violence and Violence Against Protestors to investigate whether violence against post-election protestors counteracts concession demands against governments that have engaged in pre-election violence. The interaction coefficient is not significantly different from 0, suggesting that violence against protestors may not be a successful way to thwart concessions.Footnote 98

Together, these findings lend support to our argument that pre-election violence can help incumbents win elections but may also increase the risk that leaders will eventually face mass protests, which may oust them from power after the election, or annul election results that were favorable to the incumbent and call new elections.

Caveats

Why do ‘Rational’ Leaders Choose a Risky Strategy?

We have shown that pre-election violence–like fraud–increases the chances that leaders win elections as well as the chances they will face post-election protests, which are costly in their own right and can lead to power concessions. Rational leaders who aim to stay in power should seek to avoid these potentially negative consequences of using violence. Why, then, do the repercussions of violence in the post-election period not deter all violence in the pre-election period? If voters and opposition leaders are acting rationally given their available options, are leaders irrational?

While a definitive answer is beyond the scope of this article, we offer some tentative speculations. Our argument is not that leaders are irrational. To the contrary, much like the opposition they face, leaders running for re-election may be operating with short-term discount rates focused on the immediate goal of winning at the expense of longer-term strategy. They may be aware of the eventual possibility of protest and its consequences, but weigh the probability or longer-run costs associated with this strategy as lower than the immediate benefits of election victory. Some may also underestimate the strength or resolve of the general public once mobilized. And it is likely that many repressive incumbents have difficulty perfectly accessing or evaluating information about their own popularity–indeed, it is precisely in these circumstances of uncertainty that incumbents are most likely to engage in election violence, and thus may be prone to miscalculating the public’s reaction.Footnote 99

Endogeneity

The decision to use election violence is itself a strategic decision driven by factors such as election uncertainty, executive constraints and capacity. This raises the question of whether we are identifying an effect of election violence, or whether our results are biased by some unobserved characteristic of violent elections. One important concern is that both the use of violence and incumbent victory might be determined by the election threat faced by the incumbent. Other empirical work has shown that violence is most likely when incumbents are uncertain about the election outcome.Footnote 100 To the extent this is a problem, it should result in an underestimation of the effect of election violence on winning, since this logic suggests that the incumbents most likely to lose elections are also the most likely to use violence. We thus included several control variables that measure pre-election expectations of victory, including opposition mobilization, level of democracy and expectations of victory (Victory Uncertain). We also include fixed-effect estimates in the Appendix. Since many of these potential confounds vary little between elections (such as the level of executive constraints or democracy), they are unlikely to confound estimates from a fixed-effects model.

Reverse Causation

Relatedly, one might worry about reverse causation. If more electorally successful leaders are more likely to rely on election violence, then this relationship between violence and incumbent victory might be spurious. This seems unlikely. First, as we note above, leaders who are confident of victory rarely use election violence. Secondly, we include several control variables to account for expectations of victory and the incumbent’s tenure in office. Such an explanation does not align with our findings on the post-election consequences of election violence: if more successful leaders are using violence, we would not expect to see violence trigger protest and undermine leader tenure in the post-election period and over the longer term.

Other Manipulation Tactics

It is also possible that the choice to use violence is not independent of the choice to engage in other forms of election manipulation, such as distorting vote counts, manipulating election timing, vote buying or rigging registration processes. If these strategies complement or substitute for one another in ways that are related to incumbents’ election prospects, we run the risk of obtaining biased estimates of the effect of election violence.Footnote 101 A full exploration of these alternative strategies is an important area for future research and well beyond the scope of this article; however, we take several steps to address this inferential challenge.Footnote 102 First, we include controls for expectations of fraud in our models where feasible. This ensures that we are not substantially overestimating the effects of violence due to complementarities between fraud and violence. Controlling for other strategies–such as vote buying or abuse of public spending–is more difficult, yet we take steps to account for factors that others have suggested might make violence cheaper than other strategies, such as the presence of election monitors, the size of the government budget and media transparency. We describe and show these alternative estimates in the Appendix. Our results remain consistent.

Implications

Writing in the early 1990s, Samuel Huntington observed that ‘[w]e all know that military coups, censorship, rigged elections, coercion and harassment of the opposition, jailing of political opponents, and prohibition of political meetings are incompatible with democracy’.Footnote 103 Does this also imply that election violence is incompatible with democratization and greater political liberalization? Scholars have long recognized that most governments around the world hold elections, but the majority of election-holding countries are not full democracies.Footnote 104 Yet debate continues about the role political violence plays in political transitions, and what violent elections might mean for a country’s prospects for democratization. Despite the widespread recognition that many countries experience election violence, and the generally accepted tension between state-sponsored political violence and democracy, there has been little research investigating how the timing of election violence relates to its consequences. Much more attention has been given to fraud.

This article contributes to the debate about whether election violence is a ‘harbinger of democracy’Footnote 105 by examining the consequences of government-sponsored election violence across regime types, while also avoiding the assumption that annual measures of repression are accurate proxies for election violence. Our results point anecdotally to when and why violent elections should lead to democratic transitions and regime turnover. On the one hand, election violence helps unpopular incumbents win competitive elections in part because it mobilizes political parties to protest the regime–and the election process–by boycotting elections, and may also intimidate voters into increasing the incumbent’s vote share. On the other hand, violence can embolden opposition movements in the post-election period, which at times turn to non-election means such as protests that increase the risk that the incumbent will make concessions of power. This makes election violence risky as a long-term strategy for incumbents. The United Democratic Action Organization in the Philippines was able to mobilize support for overthrowing the Marcos regime in part by organizing rallies against the government’s purported assassination of opposition leader Benigo Aquino.Footnote 106 Similar links between election violence and opposition mobilization can be seen in the rise of opposition to Syngman Rhee in South Korea and Zulfikar Ali Bhutto in Pakistan.Footnote 107

One possible implication is that election violence may actually–and inadvertently–promote political liberalization in some cases over the long term. This is not to say that repression cannot quell these movements. The people power movement in 1988 Burma, the so-called 8888 movement, obtained significant concessions from the governing junta, only to be violently repressed following the movement’s victory in the 1990 parliamentary elections.Footnote 108 Even so, incumbents who use election violence are more likely to face protests that eventually force them out of power and are more likely to face some form of democratization event during their tenure.Footnote 109 Exploring all conditions under which election violence leads to political liberalization is beyond the scope of this article; however our results suggest that, while election violence may provide short-term gains for the incumbent, in the long run it can motivate powerful opposition movements to take to the streets and demand reform.

Footnotes

*

School of Global Policy and Strategy, University of California, San Diego (email: ehafner@ucsd.edu); Department of Political Science, University of California, Berkeley (email: susanhyde@berkeley.edu); Department of Government, London School of Economics and Political Science (email: r.s.jablonski@lse.ac.uk). Replication data is available at https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataverse/BJPolS and online appendices are available at http://dx.doi.org/doi:10.1017/S000712341600020X.

1 Human Rights Watch 2003; McCargo Reference McCargo2005.

3 Agence France Presse 2006; The Guardian 2008.

4 We define government-sponsored election violence as ‘events in which incumbent leaders and ruling party agents employ or threaten violence against the political opposition or potential voters before, during or after elections’ (Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014, 150). We focus on government-sponsored election violence because the government has a disproportionate ability to employ the forms of election violence that we measure, and because we are interested in whether an incumbent’s use of violence influences their ability to stay in power. Our work complements existing research on general election violence, violence perpetrated by opposition groups or elections as a substitute for civil war. See, for example Brancati and Snyder Reference Brancati and Snyder2011, Reference Brancati and Snyder2012; Collier and Vicente Reference Collier and Vicente2012; Dunning Reference Dunning2011; Flores and Nooruddin 2012; Gandhi and Przeworski Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2009; Höglund Reference Höglund2009; Höglund, Jarstad, and Kovacs Reference Höglund, Jarstad and Kovacs2009; Straus and Taylor Reference Straus and Taylor2012. Bhasin and Gandhi focus on government-sponsored election repression, but restrict their analysis to authoritarian regimes (2013).

5 For more historic work on election fraud and violence, see Bensel (Reference Bensel2004), Barnes (Reference Barnes1998), Hermet, Rouquie, and Rose (Reference Hermet, Rouquie and Rose1978), Posada-Carbó (Reference Posada-Carbó2000), Little and Posada-Carbo (Reference Little and Posada-Carbo1996), Hoppen (Reference Hoppen1984), and Zeldin (Reference Zeldin1958). For examples of work that discusses election violence as a subtype of election manipulation, see Birch (Reference Birch2011), Hermet, Rouquie, and Rose (Reference Hermet, Rouquie and Rose1978), Huntington (Reference Huntington1991), Lehoucq (Reference Lehoucq2003), Schedler (Reference Schedler2002a, Reference Schedler2002b, Reference Schedler2009). There are excellent relevant new and working papers. See, for example, Arriola and Johnson Reference Arriola and Johnson2011; Bekoe Reference Bekoe2013; Bhasin and Gandhi Reference Bhasin and Gandhi2013; Borzyskowski Reference von Borzyskowski2013; Daxecker Reference Daxecker2014; Kuhn Reference Kuhn2010, Reference Kuhn2013; Norris Reference Norris2012; Pevehouse, Straus, and Taylor Reference Pevehouse, Straus and Taylor2012; Straus and Taylor Reference Straus and Taylor2012.

6 A full analysis of whether fraud and violence are compliments or substitutes is beyond the scope of this article.

7 Excepting autocratic regimes that do not hold elections and the most democratic regimes.

8 Kristine Höglund states that the ‘overall objective of election violence is to influence the election process’ (2009, 416). Andreas Schedler lists election violence and political repression as one instrument that ‘ruling parties may deploy to contain the democratic uncertainty of political elections’ (Schedler Reference Schedler2002b, 104). The assumption that election violence is used because it works is also referenced in a number of other pieces on election violence and election manipulation more generally (Collier Reference Collier2009, 33; Collier and Vicente Reference Collier and Vicente2012; Robinson and Torvik Reference Robinson and Torvik2009). Steven Wilkinson’s work illustrates how ethnic riots are allowed strategically when violence benefits politicians at the ballot box (2006). Other examples of election violence ‘working’ for incumbents are discussed in Boone (Reference Boone2011), Bratton (Reference Bratton2008), LeBas (Reference LeBas2006), and Teshome-Bahiru (Reference Teshome-Bahiru2009).

9 See Simpser for a comprehensive treatment of the benefits of election fraud (2012). For other examinations of the relationship between fraud and protest, see Little, Tucker, and LaGatta (Reference Little, Tucker and LaGatta2015).

10 Data availability for control variables limits the sample to 458 elections, 1981–2004. We exclude twenty-one long-term consolidated democracies where the probability of election violence is extremely low (Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Britain and the United States).

11 Note that other research has shown that opposition party election boycotts can result in longer-term movement toward political liberalization (Beaulieu Reference Beaulieu2014; Smith Reference Smith2014), but at least in the short term, pre-election collective action against the government can make it more likely that the government wins.

12 Collier (Reference Collier2009, Reference Fearon34) also mentions this possibility.

13 While post-election protests increase the risk that the incumbent incurs costly consequences, pre-election violence is but one potential motivator for these protests. On the causes of post-election protest more generally, see Beaulieu (Reference Beaulieu2014), Svolik and Chernykh (Reference Svolik and Chernykh2012), Daxecker (Reference Daxecker2012), and Hyde and Marinov (Reference Hyde and Marinov2014).

14 For more sophisticated theoretical treatments of the strategic dynamics of collective action surrounding elections, see Fearon (Reference Fearon2011), Little, Tucker, and LaGatta (Reference Little, Tucker and LaGatta2015), Little (Reference Little2012), Gandhi and Przeworski (Reference Gandhi and Przeworski2009), and Svolik and Chernykh (Reference Svolik and Chernykh2012).

15 Tucker Reference Tucker2007, 536. See also Beaulieu (Reference Beaulieu2014), Kuran (Reference Kuran1995).

17 Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014.

18 For a more comprehensive treatment of election boycotts see Beaulieu (Reference Beaulieu2006, Reference Beaulieu2014), Lindberg (Reference Lindberg2006b), and Smith (Reference Smith2014).

19 Boycotts may be associated with other reputational costs or lead to longer-term institutional reform. See Beaulieu Reference Beaulieu2014; Smith Reference Smith2014.

20 Beaulieu Reference Beaulieu2014, 37.

21 Lindberg Reference Lindberg2006b, 160.

22 Beaulieu Reference Beaulieu2014.

24 This research has led several scholars to conclude that opposition party election boycotts should be avoided. See Huntington Reference Huntington1991; Schedler Reference Schedler2009.

25 Beaulieu (Reference Beaulieu2014) argues that boycotts should reduce election violence because they reduce competition, but finds no consistent support for this hypothesis. This could be because violence causes boycotts, as we suggest.

26 Even if a boycott were called first and the government-initiated violence against the opposition afterwards (which we think is rare), government-sponsored violence could still reinforce the decision to boycott. Because boycotts are not carried out automatically and require significant effort to implement successfully (Beaulieu Reference Beaulieu2014), and because pre-election violence can be used throughout the pre-election period, we do not argue that violence causes boycotts in a one-shot iteration. Even so, we argue that a government’s decision to use election violence increases the probability that a boycott will be carried out. For recent work on the iterative nature of political repression and dissent, see Ritter (Reference Ritter2014). Other work explores the sequencing of strategic decisions related to protest. See Frank Reference Frank2014.

27 This line of reasoning is similar to Simpser’s argument that election fraud can decrease voter engagement and result in lower voter turnout (Simpser Reference Simpser2012). Patrick Kuhn (Reference Kuhn2013) shows that voters who fear election violence are less likely to turn out to vote.

28 On voter perceptions of ballot secrecy, see IFES’ surveys (available at www.ifes.org). See also Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011; Chandra Reference Chandra2007; Gerber et al. Reference Gerber, Huber, Doherty and Dowling2013; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2006; Nichter Reference Nichter2008; Stokes Reference Stokes2005.

29 Blaydes Reference Blaydes2011, 105.

30 Human Rights Watch 2010.

31 Some formal models also suggest that violence may suppress turnout: Robinson and Torvik (Reference Robinson and Torvik2009) argue that violent incumbents may attempt to suppress voting among swing groups in an attempt to retain resources. Collier and Vicente’s (Reference Collier and Vicente2012) argument suggest that violence is used to suppress voting among the ‘soft’ opposition.

33 Hyde and Marinov Reference Hyde and Marinov2012. Additionally, many pre-election protests are aimed at improving the election process rather than challenging the incumbent’s hold on power. In our sample, pre-election protests are half as likely to occur as election boycotts. Post-election protests are twice as likely to occur as pre-election protests.

34 Bunce and Wolchik Reference Bunce and Wolchik2011.

35 Additionally, our data suggest that pre-election protests are not only rarer, but also significantly more likely to be met with government-sponsored violence.

36 Human Rights Watch 2008.

38 Tucker Reference Tucker2007, 540.

39 Weingast Reference Weingast1997.

40 Tucker Reference Tucker2007, 540–1.

44 Los Angeles Times 1960a, 1960b.

45 Non-violent civil resistance may also be more effective. See Chenoweth and Stephan Reference Chenoweth and Stephan2011; Stephan and Chenoweth Reference Stephan and Chenoweth2008.

47 National Republic Institute for International Affairs 1991.

48 Williams Reference Williams1991.

49 Binder Reference Binder1991. Similarly, in El Salvador, the day after the 1977 presidential election, an estimated 75,000 to 100,000 opposition supporters joined non-violent protests against election fraud and intimidation. The government responded with violence, killing as many as twenty protesters, arresting hundreds and declaring a state of siege. The opposition party vice-presidential candidate fled into exile (Organization of American States 1978; United States Congress House Committee on International Relations, Subcommittee on International Relations 1977).

50 Bahari and Alinejad Reference Bahari and Alinejad2010.

51 Hyde and Marinov Reference Hyde and Marinov2012.

52 The NELDA data and codebook are available at http://hyde.research.yale.edu/nelda. Appendix A includes a full list of countries included in the sample.

53 A complete list of the countries in our sample is available in the Appendix.

54 Nohlen Reference Nohlen2005; Nohlen, Grotz, and Hartmann Reference Nohlen, Grotz and Hartmann2001; Nohlen, Krennerich, and Thibaut Reference Nohlen, Krennerich and Thibaut1999.

55 Hyde and Marinov Reference Hyde and Marinov2011.

56 We also re-estimate our results using only the final round of all elections. The results are consistent.

57 This rule excludes elections in which any of the following are not ‘yes’: Nelda3: Was opposition allowed?; Nelda4: Was more than one party legal?; Nelda5: Was there a choice of candidates on the ballot? See Hyde and Marinov Reference Hyde and Marinov2012.

58 Exceptions include: Bhasin and Gandhi Reference Bhasin and Gandhi2013; Straus and Taylor Reference Straus and Taylor2012.

59 Incumbent Wins is from Nelda40: ‘Did the leader step down because the vote count gave victory to some other actor?’ It equals 1 if no and 0 otherwise.

60 Pre-Election Violence is coded from Nelda15: ‘Is there evidence that the government harassed the opposition?’ and Nelda33: ‘Was there significant violence involving civilian deaths immediately before, during, or after the election?’ If either Nelda15 or Nelda33 is ‘yes’, then Pre-Election Violence is coded as ‘yes’. Although Nelda15 and Nelda33 could technically involve some post-election violence, research assistants were instructed to focus primarily on harassment and deaths in the period leading up to and including election day (personal correspondence with authors). As an additional check, we asked our own researchers to recode a random subset of Nelda33 with reference to when violence occurred in the electoral cycle. Less than 3 per cent of cases (4/141 coded so far) reference only post-election violence involving civilian deaths. Post-Election Violence is focused explicitly on violence against demonstrators, and is coded from Nelda31. Nelda31 is only coded if there were riots and protests after the election, and indicates whether ‘the government used violence against demonstrators’.

61 Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014.

62 Hyde and Marinov Reference Hyde and Marinov2011. Consistent with our argument, incumbents win 66 per cent of the cases of violence in our sample, compared with 49 per cent of elections without violence. Detailed summary information is available in the Appendix.

63 Makumbe Reference Makumbe2002; Throup and Hornsby Reference Throup and Hornsby1998; Tripp Reference Tripp2010. In our data, civilian violence and opposition harassment are correlated at 0.25.

64 Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014.

65 Frank (Reference Frank2014) distinguishes between threats of violence and actual violence. This is a potentially fruitful distinction, but is not central to our focus on whether violence helps incumbents stay in power.

66 Again following Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski (Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014), Victory Uncertain is coded from Nelda12 and Nelda26. Nelda12equals ‘yes’ in cases in which the incumbent made ‘public statements expressing confidence’ of victory, the opposition indicated that they were ‘not likely to win’, or there were cases in which the ‘incumbent or ruling party has been dominant for a number of years and is projected to win in a landslide’. Nelda26 equals ‘yes’ if there were ‘reliable polls that indicated popularity of ruling political party or of the candidates before elections’ and ‘they were favorable for the incumbent’. Victory Uncertain equals 1 when either variable equals ‘no’, 0 when both equal 0, and is coded as missing when both are ‘unclear’ or ‘N/A’.

67 Poe and Tate Reference Poe and Tate1994.

68 Note that a negative correlation between democracy and violence should bias us against seeing a positive effect of violence on election outcomes.

69 Marshall and Jaggers Reference Marshall and Jaggers2008.

70 Cingranelli and Richards Reference Cingranelli and Richards2010.

71 Both Polity and Physical Integrity are likely to change based on election events.

72 World Bank 2013.

73 Goemans, Gleditsch, and Chiozza Reference Goemans, Gleditsch and Chiozza2009.

74 Marshall Reference Marshall2007.

75 Poe, Tate, and Keith Reference Poe, Tate and Keith1999.

76 Coded from Nelda11. This measure relates to ‘domestic or international concern’ about the quality of the election, including whether ‘elections were widely perceived to lack basic criteria for competitive elections, such as more than one political party’. We use pre-election expectations of fraud rather than post-election accusations of fraud.

78 Variable coded by merging the Banks protest data and NELDA (Banks Reference Banks2005; Hyde and Marinov Reference Hyde and Marinov2012). For all election years in which anti-government demonstrations occurred, researchers coded whether anti-government demonstration(s) were election related. Pre-election rallies in favor of one party or candidate were not considered protest. Coders also indicated whether the government responded to pre-election protests with violence.

79 Alternatively, we have examined this relationship within ‘competitive authoritarian’ regimes only. We use a measure of whether the opposition has formed a pre-election coalition, introduced by Howard and Roessler (Reference Howard and Roessler2006). Opposition coalitions are present ‘when multiple opposition groupings, parties, or candidates joined together to create a broad movement in opposition to the incumbent leader or party in power’, with a slightly larger sample of elections obtained from Hyde and Marinov (Reference Hyde and Marinov2012), who use Howard and Roessler’s definition to code a larger sample (N=109) of elections in competitive authoritarian regimes. The results hold within this subsample.

80 Coded from Nelda14.

81 For a discussion of the assumptions required for accurate estimates of mediation effects, see Imai et al. (Reference Imai, Keele, Tingley and Yamamoto2011).

83 Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014.

84 Malone and Clarke Reference Malone and Clarke2010.

85 The Island–Sri Lanka 2015.

86 This would likely mean that errors would not be independent or normally distributed. Although a majority of turnout data is likely to accurately reflect actual voter turnout, it is likely that some turnout data is falsified, and not reflective of actual voter turnout. Such falsification is often covert. We do not know when the measure is most likely to be inaccurate, and suspect that measurement error and election violence may be correlated.

87 International IDEA Voter Turnout website, http://www.idea.int/vt/, accessed July 2015.

88 International IDEA Voter Turnout website, http://www.idea.int/vt/, accessed July 2015.

89 Hyde and Marinov Reference Hyde and Marinov2011. We only have turnout data for the final round of voting, which is often lower than earlier rounds of voting in multi-round elections.

90 Note that if turnout differs between opposition and incumbent supporters, this will bias us against seeing a significant effect.

91 For reference, under conditions of minimum Voter Turnout and the use of Pre-Election Violence, the probability the incumbent wins is 0.3.

92 This could also be consistent with an alternative explanation in which governments that resort to pre-election violence are also more likely to falsify high voter turnout.

93 Coded from Nelda29, which indicates whether there were ‘riots or protests after the election’ that were ‘at least somewhat related to the outcome or handling of the election’.

94 In Appendix A we re-estimate these models including elections where the incumbent lost. The results are consistent.

95 Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014.

96 This variable was coded from Nelda34: Were results that were favorable to the incumbent canceled?, Nelda39: Was the incumbent replaced? and Nelda40: If yes (Nelda39), did the leader step down because the vote count gave victory to some other political actor? Power Concessions equals 1 if Nelda34=‘yes’ or Nelda39=yes’. Cases in which Nelda40=‘yes’ are coded as 0 to exclude cases in which the incumbent lost the election and stepped down.

97 This relationship holds when we exclude cases in which the incumbent lost the election and exited power.

98 Since some coups are initiated within regimes, rather than by opposition groups, we re-estimate the model after excluding the only case in which concessions resulted from a coup (after the 1982 election in Guatemala). The results remain consistent.

99 Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014.

100 Hafner-Burton, Hyde, and Jablonski Reference Hafner-Burton, Hyde and Jablonski2014.

101 The data suggest that violence may be both a complement to and substitute for fraud. For instance, both fraud and violence are often used alone; however incumbents are about 30 per cent more likely to use fraud in violent elections than in non-violent elections.

102 Several scholars have proposed theories about when incumbents might choose one strategy over another. See Birch Reference Birch2011; Collier and Vicente Reference Collier and Vicente2012; Daxecker Reference Daxecker2014; Hyde and O’Mahony Reference Hyde and O’Mahony2010; Kelley Reference Kelley2012; Simpser Reference Simpser2012.

103 Huntington Reference Huntington1991, 8.

104 Hermet, Rouquie, and Rose Reference Hermet, Rouquie and Rose1978, vii.

105 Brownlee Reference Brownlee2009.

106 Thompson Reference Thompson1995.

107 AAP Reuter 1977; Los Angeles Times 1960a, 1960b; Trumbull Reference Trumbull1960.

108 Schock Reference Schock1999.

109 Violent leaders have a 25 per cent chance of an increase in their regime’s democracy score during their tenure, compared to 8 per cent for non-violent leaders. Authors’ calculation.

References

AAP Reuter . 1977. Detention Sparks Pakistan Battles. AAP-Reuter, 18 May, p. 7.Google Scholar
Adams, Brad. 2012. 10,000 Days of Hun Sen. The International Herald Tribune, 1 June, p. 6.Google Scholar
Agence France Presse. 2006. ‘Belarus Leader to ‘Break Neck’ of Election Demonstration’. Minsk: Agence France Presse.Google Scholar
Arriola, Leonardo, and Johnson, Chelsea. 2011. Election Violence in Democratizing States. Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Seattle, WA, 1–4 September.Google Scholar
Bahari, Maziar, and Alinejad, Masih. 2010. Mehdi Karrubi: ‘We Are Ready to Pay Any Price’; The Former Presidential Candidate on Reforming Iran. Newsweek, 14 June, p. 38.Google Scholar
Banks, Arthur S. 1975. Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive: User’s Manual. Binghamton, NY: Center for Comparative Political Research, State University of New York.Google Scholar
Banks, Arthur S. 2005. Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive. Binghamton: Databanks International.Google Scholar
Barnes, Kenneth C. 1998. Who Killed John Clayton?: Political Violence and the Emergence of the New South, 1861–1893 . Durham, NC: Duke University Press Books.Google Scholar
Beaulieu, Emily. 2006. Protesting the Contest: Election Boycotts Around the World, 1990–2002. PhD Dissertation. San Diego: University of California.Google Scholar
Beaulieu, Emily. 2014. Electoral Protest and Democratization in the Developing World. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beech, Keyes. 1960. Foes Charge Rhee Charts Vote Theft: Korean Police Break Up Student Protest Parade. The Washington Post, 9 March, p. A4.Google Scholar
Bekoe, Dorina, ed. 2013. Voting in Fear: Electoral Violence in Sub-Saharan Africa. Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press.Google Scholar
Bensel, Richard Franklin. 2004. The American Ballot Box in the Mid-Nineteenth Century. New York and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhasin, Tavishi, and Gandhi, Jennifer. 2013. Timing and Targeting of State Repression in Authoritarian Elections. Electoral Studies 32 (4):620631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binder, David. 1991. Albanian Troops Kill 3 Protesters and Wound 30. The New York Times, 2 April, p. 3.Google Scholar
Birch, Sarah. 2011. Electoral Malpractice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaydes, Lisa. 2011. Elections and Distributive Politics in Mubarak’s Egypt. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Boone, Catherine. 2011. Politically Allocated Land Rights and the Geography of Electoral Violence. The Case of Kenya in the 1990s. Comparative Political Studies 44 (10):13111342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brancati, Dawn, and Snyder, Jack L.. 2011. Rushing to the Polls: The Causes of Premature Post-Conflict Elections. Journal of Conflict Resolution 55:469492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brancati, Dawn, and Snyder, Jack L.. 2012. Time to Kill: The Impact of Election Timing on Post-Conflict Stability. Journal of Conflict Resolution 57:822853.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratton, Michael. 2008. Vote Buying and Violence in Nigerian Election Campaigns. Electoral Studies 27 (4):621632.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brownlee, Jason. 2009. Portents of Pluralism: How Hybrid Regimes Affect Democratic Transitions. American Journal of Political Science 53 (3):515532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunce, Valerie J., and Wolchik, Sharon L.. 2010. Defeating Dictators: Electoral Change and Stability in Competitive Authoritarian Regimes. World Politics 62 (1):4386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunce, Valerie J., and Wolchik, Sharon L.. 2011. Defeating Authoritarian Leaders in Postcommunist Countries. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, Sabine C. 2006. The Dynamic Relationship Between Protest and Repression. Political Research Quarterly 59 (1):111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chandra, Kanchan. 2007. Why Ethnic Parties Succeed: Patronage and Ethnic Head Counts in India. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Chenoweth, Erica, and Stephan, Maria J.. 2011. Why Civil Resistance Works: The Strategic Logic of Nonviolent Conflict. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Cingranelli, David L., and Richards, David L.. 2010. The Cingranelli-Richards (CIRI) Human Rights Dataset. Available from http://www.humanrightsdata.org, accessed 23 July 2015.Google Scholar
Collier, Paul. 2009. Wars, Guns, and Votes. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Collier, Paul, and Vicente, Pedro C.. 2012. Violence, Bribery, and Fraud: The Political Economy of Elections in Sub-Saharan Africa. Public Choice 153:117147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daxecker, Ursula E. 2012. The Cost of Exposing Cheating International Election Monitoring, Fraud, and Post-Election Violence in Africa. Journal of Peace Research 49 (4):503516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Daxecker, Ursula E. 2014. All Quiet on Election Day? International Election Observation and Incentives for Pre-Election Violence in African Elections. Electoral Studies 34:232243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunning, Thad. 2011. Fighting and Voting: Violent Conflict and Electoral Politics. Journal of Conflict Resolution 55 (3):327339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. 2011. Self-Enforcing Democracy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (4):16611708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flores, Thomas E., and Nooruddin, Irfan. 2012. The Effect of Elections on Post-Conflict Peace and Reconstruction. Journal of Politics 74 (2):558570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Richard W. 2014. The Strategic Use of Election Violence. Annual Meeting of the International Studies Association, Toronto, 28 March.Google Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer. 2010. Political Institutions Under Dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer, and Przeworski, Adam. 2009. Holding Onto Power By Any Means? The Origins of Competitive Elections. Unpublished Manuscript. Atlanta, GA: Emory University. Available at http://cowles.yale.edu/sites/default/files/files/conf/2009/rat_przeworski.pdf, accessed 14 December 2009.Google Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer, and Lust-Okar, Ellen. 2009. Elections Under Authoritarianism. Annual Review of Political Science 12:403422.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerber, Alan S., Huber, Gregory A., Doherty, David, and Dowling, Conor M.. 2013. Is There a Secret Ballot? Ballot Secrecy Perceptions and Their Implications for Voting Behaviour. British Journal of Political Science 43 (1):77102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goemans, Hein E., Gleditsch, Kristian S., and Chiozza, Giacomo. 2009. Introducing Archigos: A Dataset of Political Leaders. Journal of Peace Research 46 (2):269283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greene, Kenneth F. 2007. Why Dominant Parties Lose: Mexico’s Democratization in Comparative Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greene, Kenneth F. 2008. Dominant Party Strategy and Democratization. American Journal of Political Science 52 (1):1631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The Guardian . 2008. Belarus Elections Labelled Corrupt as Lukashenko Backers Win all Seats, 29 September. Available from http://www.theguardian.com/world/2008/sep/29/belarus, accessed 6 August 2013.Google Scholar
Gupta, Dipak K., Singh, Harinder, and Sprague, Tom. 1993. Government Coercion of Dissidents. Journal of Conflict Resolution 37 (2):301339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hafner-Burton, Emilie M., Hyde, Susan D., and Jablonski, Ryan S.. 2014. When Do Governments Resort to Election Violence? British Journal of Political Science 44 (1):149179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hermet, Guy, Rouquie, Alain, and Rose, Richard, eds. 1978. Elections Without Choice. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Höglund, Kristine. 2009. Electoral Violence in Conflict-Ridden Societies: Concepts, Causes, and Consequences. Terrorism and Political Violence 21 (3):412427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Höglund, Kristine, Jarstad, Anna K., and Kovacs, Mimmi Söderberg. 2009. The Predicament of Elections in War-Torn Societies. Democratization 16 (3):530557.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoppen, K. Theodore. 1984. Elections, Politics, and Society in Ireland, 1832–1885. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Howard, Marc M., and Roessler, Philip G.. 2006. Liberalizing Electoral Outcomes in Competitive Authoritarian Regimes. American Journal of Political Science 50 (2):365381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Human Rights Watch. 2003. Don’t Bite the Hand that Feeds You: Coercion, Threats, and Vote-Buying in Cambodia’s National Elections. Available from http://www.hrw.org/legacy/backgrounder/asia/cambodia/elections.htm, accessed 6 August 2013.Google Scholar
Human Rights Watch. 2008. Ballots to Bullets: Organized Political Violence and Kenya’s Crisis of Governance. Available from http://www.hrw.org/reports/2008/03/16/ballots-bullets-0, accessed 8 January 2015.Google Scholar
Human Rights Watch. 2010. Ethiopia: Government Repression Undermines Poll: International Election Observers Should Condemn Voter Intimidation. Available from http://www.hrw.org/news/2010/05/24/ethiopia-government-repression-undermines-poll, accessed 6 January 2012.Google Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. 1991. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press.Google Scholar
Hyde, Susan D., and O’Mahony, Angela. 2010. International Scrutiny and Pre-Electoral Fiscal Manipulation in Developing Countries. Journal of Politics 72 (2):690704.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyde, Susan D., and Marinov, Nikolay. 2011. Codebook for National Elections Across Democracy and Autocracy (NELDA), available at http://hyde.research.yale.edu/nelda/NELDA_Codebook_version3.pdf, accessed 30 May 2012.Google Scholar
Hyde, Susan D., and Marinov, Nikolay. 2012. Which Elections Can Be Lost? Political Analysis 20 (2):191210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyde, Susan D., and Marinov, Nikolay. 2014. Information and Self-Enforcing Democracy: The Role of International Election Observation. International Organization 68 (2):329359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imai, Kosuke, Keele, Luke, Tingley, Dustin, and Yamamoto, Teppei. 2011. Unpacking the Black Box of Causality: Learning About Causal Mechanisms from Experimental and Observational Studies. American Political Science Review 105 (4):765789.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The Island – Sri Lanka. 2015. Poll Monitoring Body in Sri Lanka Says Army Presence May Lower Turnout in North. BBC Monitoring South Asia – Political Supplied by BBC Worldwide Monitoring, 7 January. Available from http://www.lexisnexis.com/lnacui2api/api/version1/getDocCui?lni=5F15-J7W1-DYRV-32B8&csi=237924&hl=t&hv=t&hnsd=f&hns=t&hgn=t&oc=00240&perma=true, accessed 3 August 2015.Google Scholar
Kelley, Judith G. 2012. Monitoring Democracy: When International Election Observation Works, and Why It Often Fails. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Patrick M. 2010. Fraud, Coordination Problems, and Successful Post-Electoral Protests in Competitive Electoral Autocracies. Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL, 23 April.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Patrick. 2013. Ethnic Voting, Partisanship, and Pre-Electoral Violence: Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. Presented at the Pre-APSA Workshop on Electoral Integrity, Chicago, IL, 28 August.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1995. Private Truths, Public Lies: The Social Consequences of Preference Falsification. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
LeBas, Adrienne. 2006. Polarization as Craft: Party Formation and State Violence in Zimbabwe. Comparative Politics 38 (4):419438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lehoucq, Fabrice. 2003. Electoral Fraud: Causes, Types, and Consequences. Annual Review of Political Science 6:233256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitsky, Steven, and Way, Lucan. 2002. The Rise of Competitive Authoritarianism. Journal of Democracy 13 (2):5165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitsky, Steven, and Way, Lucan. 2010. Competitive Authoritarianism: The Origins and Evolution of Hybrid Regimes in the Post-Cold War Era. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindberg, Staffan I. 2006a. Democracy and Elections in Africa. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindberg, Staffan I. 2006b. Tragic Protest: Why Do Opposition Parties Boycott Elections? In Electoral Authoritarianism: The Dynamics of Unfree Competition, edited by Andreas Schedler, 149163. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, Andrew T. 2012. Elections, Fraud, and Election Monitoring in the Shadow of Revolution. Quarterly Journal of Political Science 7 (3):249283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, Andrew T., Tucker, Joshua A., and LaGatta, Tom. 2015. Elections, Protest, and Alternation of Power. Journal of Politics 77 (4):11421156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, Walter, and Posada-Carbo, Eduardo, eds. 1996. Political Corruption in Europe and Latin America. New York: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1994. The Dynamics of Informational Cascades: The Monday Demonstrations in Leipzig, East Germany, 1989–91. World Politics 47 (1):42101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Los Angeles Times . 1960a. Rhee Steps Down: Foreign Minister to Head Caretaker Regime in Korea. Los Angeles Times (1923-Current File), 27 April. Available from http://search.proquest.com/docview/167690452/abstract/13BD93180B549904B10/2?accountid=15172, accessed 6 August 2013.Google Scholar
Los Angeles Times . 1960b. South Korea Torn by New Rioting: Violence Flares in 7 Cities. Los Angeles Times (1923-Current File), 20 April. Available from http://search.proquest.com/docview/167674850/abstract/13FBF06884D19322FC0/1?accountid=15172, accessed 7 August 2013.Google Scholar
Lust, Ellen. 2009. Competitive Clientelism in the Middle East. Journal of Democracy 20 (3):122135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lust-Okar, Ellen. 2004. Divided They Rule: The Management and Manipulation of Political Opposition. Comparative Politics 36 (2):159179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lust-Okar, Ellen. 2006. Elections Under Authoritarianism: Preliminary Lessons from Jordan. Democratization 13 (3):456471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2006. Voting for Autocracy: Hegemonic Party Survival and Its Demise in Mexico. Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2010. The Game of Electoral Fraud and the Ousting of Authoritarian Rule. American Journal of Political Science 54 (3):751765.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Makumbe, John. 2002. Zimbabwe’s Hijacked Election. Journal of Democracy 13 (4):87101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malone, Barry. 2010. Ethiopian PM Says EU Election Report is Trash. Reuters. Available from http://www.reuters.com/article/2010/11/15/ozatp-ethiopia-election-idAFJOE6AE0LQ20101115, accessed 25 January 2013.Google Scholar
Malone, Barry, and Clarke, David. 2010. Ethiopia’s Meles Expects Win, EU Says High Turnout. Reuters UK, Sec. World, 23 May. Available from http://uk.reuters.com/article/2010/05/23/uk-ethiopia-election-idUKTRE64L2FB20100523, accessed 3 August 2015.Google Scholar
Marshall, Monty G. 2007. Major Episodes of Political Violence, 1946–2006. Center for Systemic Peace. Available from http://www.systemicpeace.org/warlist.htm, accessed 17 August 2009.Google Scholar
Marshall, Monty G., and Jaggers, Keith. 2008. Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800–2008. Dataset Users’ Manual. College Park: Center for International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland.Google Scholar
McCargo, Duncan. 2005. Cambodia: Getting Away with Authoritarianism? Journal of Democracy 16 (4):98112.Google Scholar
McCoy, Jennifer, and Hartlyn, Jonathan. 2009. The Relative Powerlessness of Elections in Latin America. In Democratization by Elections: A New Mode of Transition, edited by Staffan I. Lindberg, 4776. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Moore, Will H. 1998. Repression and Dissent: Substitution, Context, and Timing. American Journal of Political Science 42 (3):851873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morse, Yonatan L. 2012. The Era of Electoral Authoritarianism. World Politics 64 (1):161198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
National Republic Institute for International Affairs. 1991. The 1991 Elections in Albania: Report of the Election Observer Delegation. Washington, DC: National Republic Institute for International Affairs. Available from http://www.iri.org/sites/default/files/Albania%27s%201991%20Parliamentary%20Elections.pdf, accessed 25 January 2013.Google Scholar
Nichter, Simeon. 2008. Vote Buying or Turnout Buying? Machine Politics and the Secret Ballot. American Political Science Review 102 (1):1931.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nohlen, Dieter, ed. 2005. Elections in the Americas: A Data Handbook. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nohlen, Dieter, Grotz, Florian, and Hartmann, Christof, eds. 2001. Elections in Asia and the Pacific: A Data Handbook. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nohlen, Dieter, Krennerich, Michael, and Thibaut, Bernhard, eds. 1999. Elections in Africa: A Data Handbook. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norris, Pippa. 2012. Why Electoral Malpractices Heighten Risks of Electoral Violence. SSRN Scholarly Paper, Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY. Available from http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=2104551, accessed 27 January 2013.Google Scholar
Organization of American States. 1978. El Salvador 1978 – Chapter IX. OAS. Available from http://www.cidh.org/countryrep/ElSalvador78eng/chap.9.htm, accessed 16 January 2013.Google Scholar
Pevehouse, Jon C., Straus, Scott, and Taylor, Charles. 2012. Perils of Pluralism: Electoral Violence and Competitive Authoritarianism in Sub-Saharan Africa. Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, New Orleans, LA, 1 September.Google Scholar
Poe, Steven C., and Tate, C. Neal. 1994. Repression of Human Rights to Personal Integrity in the 1980s: A Global Analysis. The American Political Science Review 88 (4):853872.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poe, Steven C., Tate, C. Neal, and Keith, Linda Camp. 1999. Repression of the Human Right to Personal Integrity Revisited: A Global Cross-National Study Covering the Years 1976–1993. International Studies Quarterly 43 (2):291313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posada-Carbó, Eduardo. 2000. Electoral Juggling: A Comparative History of the Corruption of Suffrage in Latin America, 1830–1930. Journal of Latin American Studies 32 (3):611644.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritter, Emily Hencken. 2014. Policy Disputes, Political Survival, and the Onset and Severity of State Repression. Journal of Conflict Resolution 58 (1):143168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, James A., and Torvik, Ragnar. 2009. The Real Swing Voter’s Curse. American Economic Review 99 (2):310315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roessler, Philip G., and Howard, Marc M.. 2009. Post-Cold War Political Regimes: When Do Elections Matter? In Democratization by Elections, edited by Staffan I. Lindberg, 101127. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Schedler, Andreas. 2002a. The Menu of Manipulation. Journal of Democracy 13 (2):3650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schedler, Andreas. 2002b. The Nested Game of Democratization by Elections. International Political Science Review 23 (1):103122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schedler, Andreas, ed. 2006. Electoral Authoritarianism: The Dynamics of Unfree Competition. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schedler, Andreas. 2009. The Contingent Power of Authoritarian Elections. In Democratization by Elections: A New Mode of Transition, edited by Staffan Lindberg, 291313. Baltimore, MD and London: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Schock, Kurt. 1999. People Power and Political Opportunities: Social Movement Mobilization and Outcomes in the Philippines and Burma. Social Problems 46 (3):355375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simpser, Alberto. 2012. Why Parties and Governments Manipulate Elections: Theory, Practice, and Implications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Ian O. 2014. Election Boycotts and Hybrid Regime Survival. Comparative Political Studies 47 (5):743765.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephan, Maria J., and Chenoweth, Erica. 2008. Why Civil Resistance Works: The Strategic Logic of Nonviolent Conflict. International Security 33 (1):744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokes, Susan C. 2005. Perverse Accountability: A Formal Model of Machine Politics with Evidence from Argentina. American Political Science Review 99 (3):315325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Straus, Scott, and Taylor, Charlie. 2012. Democratization and Electoral Violence in Sub-Saharan Africa, 1990–2008. In Voting in Fear: Electoral Violence in Sub-Saharan Africa, edited by Dorina A. Bekoe, 1538. Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace Press.Google Scholar
Svolik, Milan W., and Chernykh, Svitlana. 2012. Third-Party Actors and the Success of Democracy: How Electoral Commissions, Courts, and Observers Shape Incentives for Election Manipulation and Post-Election Protest. Available from http://publish.illinois.edu/msvolik/files/2012/12/thirdparties.pdf, accessed 12 July 2013.Google Scholar
Teshome-Bahiru, Wondwosen. 2009. Electoral Violence in Africa: Experience from Ethiopia. SSRN eLibrary. Available from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1595585, accessed 6 November 2012.Google Scholar
Thompson, Mark R. 1995. The Anti-Marcos Struggle: Personalistic Rule and Democratic Transition in the Philippines. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Throup, David, and Hornsby, Charles. 1998. Multi-Party Politics in Kenya: The Kenyatta & Moi States & The Triumph of the System in the 1992 Election. Melton: J. Currey.Google Scholar
Tripp, Aili Mari. 2010. Museveni’s Uganda: Paradoxes of Power in a Hybrid Regime. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trumbull, Robert. 1960. Police Open Fire: Some Students Hurt – Lee Told to Give Up Vice-Presidency. New York Times, 26 April, p. 1.Google Scholar
Tucker, Joshua. 2007. Enough! Electoral Fraud, Collective Action Problems, and Post-Communist Colored Revolutions. Perspectives on Politics 5 (3):535551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
United States Congress House Committee on International Relations, Subcommittee on International Relations. 1977. The Recent Presidential Elections in El Salvador, Implications for US Foreign Policy Hearings Before the Subcommittee on International Organizations and on Inter-American Affairs of the Committee on International Relations, House of Representatives, Ninety-fifth Congress, First Session, March 9 and 17, 1977. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office. Available from http://www.lexisnexis.com/congcomp/getdoc?HEARING-ID=HRG-1977-HIR-0055, accessed 16 January 2013.Google Scholar
von Borzyskowski, Inken. 2013. Sore Losers? International Condemnation and Domestic Incentives for Post-Election Violence. Available from http://www.polisci.wisc.edu/Uploads/Documents/IRC/Borzyskowski_Election%20Violence.pdf, accessed 19 November 2014.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1997. The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law. The American Political Science Review 91 (2):245263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilkinson, Steven I. 2006. Votes and Violence. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Williams, Carol J. 1991. Albania Erupts in Violence; 3 Killed, 58 Hurt. Los Angeles Times. Available from http://articles.latimes.com/1991-04-03/news/mn-1645_1_democratic-party, accessed 4 December 2012.Google Scholar
World Bank. 2013. World Development Indicators. Available from http://wdi.worldbank.org, accessed 15 January 2013.Google Scholar
Zeldin, Theodore. 1958. The Political System of Napoleon III. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Fig. 1 Trends in election violence and its consequences over timeNote: based on data from the National Elections Across Democracy and Autocracy dataset (Hyde and Marinov 2012). Elections with pre-election violence (Panel A) are those in which the government harassed the opposition or used violence against civilians. Elections with post-election concessions (Panel B) are those which are followed by election annulment, incumbent resignation or a coup. We explain these data in more detail in the empirical section of the article.

Figure 1

Table 1 The Argument

Figure 2

Table 2 The Effect of Pre-Election Violence on Incumbent Victory

Figure 3

Fig. 2 Estimated effects of explanatory variables on incumbent victoryNote: points indicate the simulated increase in the probability of Incumbent Wins given a change in each independent variable from its minimum to its maximum level, holding all other variables at their mean. Lines indicate the 95 per cent confidence intervals for predictions. Estimated using a logit model with robust clustered standard errors.

Figure 4

Table 3 The Effect of Pre-Election Violence on Boycott and Victory

Figure 5

Fig. 3 Probability of incumbent victory in violent and boycotted electionsNote: predicted probability of incumbent victory for all values of Boycott and Pre-Election Violence with 95 per cent confidence intervals. Predicted from Column 3 in Table 3. All control variables set at mean.

Figure 6

Table 4 The Effect of Pre-Election Violence on Turnout

Figure 7

Fig. 4 The effect of Turnout on Incumbent Wins Note: estimated effect of Pre-Election Violence on the probability of Incumbent Wins at various levels of turnout. Vertical lines indicate the 95 per cent confidence interval.

Figure 8

Table 5 The Effect of Protests on Power Concessions

Supplementary material: Link

Hafner-Burton et al. Dataset

Link
Supplementary material: File

Hafner-Burton supplementary material

Appendix

Download Hafner-Burton supplementary material(File)
File 417.8 KB