Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-b95js Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-02-11T11:51:13.002Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Labor Union Strength and the Equality of Political Representation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 December 2016

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Amid growing evidence of ‘unequal democracy’ in the United States, labor unions can play a potentially important role by ensuring that low-income citizens’ opinions receive more equal consideration when elected officials make policy decisions. To investigate this possibility, this article evaluates the relationship between labor union strength and representational equality across states and finds evidence that states with higher levels of union membership weigh citizens’ opinions more equally in the policy-making process. In contrast, there is no relationship between the volume of labor union contributions to political campaigns in a state and the equality of its political representation. These findings suggest that labor unions promote greater political equality primarily by mobilizing their working-class members to political action and, more broadly, underscore the important role that organized labor continues to play in shaping the distribution of political power across American society.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2016 

There is growing empirical evidence that the United States is an ‘unequal democracy’ in which affluent citizens are more likely to have their preferences reflected in government policy decisions compared to disadvantaged citizens.Footnote 1 This representational inequality has arisen for a variety of possible reasons: compared to citizens with low incomes, wealthier citizens are more likely to vote in elections,Footnote 2 contribute to political campaigns,Footnote 3 have their opinions represented by organized interests and professional lobbyists,Footnote 4 and serve as elected officials in government.Footnote 5 In response, scholars and concerned citizens have begun to search for possible remedies for political inequality.

For most of the twentieth century, labor unions’ attempts to organize their workers for political action were viewed as an important counterweight to the political power amassed by business interests and the affluent.Footnote 6 It is no surprise, then, that among the growing number of studies that document the recent rise in both political and economic inequality in the United States, nearly all point to the steady decline of labor union membership and influence as a major cause.Footnote 7 However, this conclusion is premised on the assumption that stronger labor unions actually help promote greater political equality. Despite a deluge of conventional wisdom that this assumption is true, to date there has been no empirical investigation of the precise relationship between labor union strength and the equality of political representation.

To advance our understanding of the impact of organized labor in American politics, this article uses the variation in labor union membership and campaign contributions across US states to examine the relationship between labor union strength and the equality of political representation between rich and poor citizens. Using public opinion measures from the National Annenberg Election Surveys (NAES) and data on state policy outcomes, I uncover evidence that states with higher levels of union membership weigh citizens’ opinions more equally in the policy-making process. In contrast, there is no relationship between the volume of labor union contributions to political campaigns in a state and the equality of political representation. These findings suggest that labor unions promote greater political equality primarily by mobilizing their working-class members to political action, as opposed to influencing elected officials directly through contributions to political campaigns.

BACKGROUND AND THEORETICAL EXPECTATIONS

Political scientists and political observers more generally have long warned that political representation in the United States is tainted by an upper-class bias, such that wealthier citizens have more influence over government policy decisions than the poor.Footnote 8 But, as the American Political Science Association Taskforce on Inequality and American Democracy lamented, ‘Unfortunately, political scientists have done surprisingly little to investigate the extent of actual inequalities of government responsiveness to public opinion – that is, whether distinct segments of the country exert more influence than others.’Footnote 9 A series of recent studies has sought to correct this problem and more fully understand unequal political influence in the United States. Most notably, Bartels demonstrates that the opinions of affluent constituents strongly predict the voting behavior of their senators, while the opinions of those with low incomes display little or no relationship.Footnote 10 In addition, Gilens collects data from thousands of individual public opinion poll questions and finds that subsequent federal government policy decisions disproportionately reflect the views of the affluent, and that this is especially true when the preferences of the rich and poor diverge.Footnote 11 Investigations of unequal political representation at the state level have tended to come to similar conclusions.Footnote 12 In short, there is a growing body of empirical evidence that shows the stated opinions of citizens with low incomes tend to receive little attention in government policy decisions compared to their more affluent counterparts.

Labor unions, as an organizing instrument for working-class citizens, have the potential to act as a counterweight to the political power amassed by business interests and the affluent.Footnote 13 This potential arises, I argue, through two primary theoretical mechanisms. First, labor unions can help offset the pronounced socio-economic bias in voter turnout and political activity more generallyFootnote 14 if they are successful in mobilizing workers with lower socio-economic status to political action.Footnote 15 In one illustrative example of labor union mobilization efforts, the AFL-CIO (through its Committee on Political Education) routinely devotes considerable resources to voter information, registration and turnout drives.Footnote 16 Moreover, in many states, mandatory collective bargaining laws provide public sector unions with subsidized benefits that can help lower the costs of mobilizing their union members to political action.Footnote 17 It is not surprising, then, that previous research emphatically suggests that unions are successful at mobilizing their members to higher levels of political activity and engagement.Footnote 18 When combined with evidence that voters’ opinions tend to be better represented by the policy decisions of elected officials than non-voters’ opinions,Footnote 19 and proof that the views of low-income citizens tend to be better reflected in government policies when they turn out to vote at higher rates,Footnote 20 jurisdictions with higher levels of union membership (and, by extension, higher levels of union political mobilization) are likely to display more egalitarian patterns of political representation.

Secondly, labor union organizations routinely insert themselves into political campaigns by contributing money directly to candidates running for officeFootnote 21 who support union-friendly policies (such as a higher minimum wage, more generous government health care and retirement support, and a more progressive taxation system) that low-income and working-class citizens, in general, also tend to support.Footnote 22 Although political scientists have uncovered little evidence that campaign contributions directly influence legislators’ roll-call votes, there is ample evidence suggesting that contributions can exert sway behind the scenes by influencing who legislators agree to meet with, what issues they focus on and how they allocate their scarce time while in office.Footnote 23 As a result of these efforts, there is likely to be a more equal weighting of citizens’ political opinions in government policy decisions in jurisdictions where union organizations are more actively involved in contributing to candidates for elected office who support labor-endorsed policy positions.Footnote 24

Despite the potentially important role that labor unions can play in promoting more equal consideration of citizens’ political opinions in government policy decisions, to date this question has received scarce empirical attention. Although related studies suggest that states with higher levels of union membership are more likely to implement liberal public policies,Footnote 25 less likely to implement business-friendly policies,Footnote 26 and tend to have lower levels of poverty and income inequality,Footnote 27 our understanding of the specific effect of labor unions on the opinion–policy linkage between citizens and their government remains limited. Therefore, in what follows, I take advantage of the variation in labor union membership and campaign contributions across the American states to empirically evaluate the relationship between labor union strength and the degree to which the political opinions of the wealthy and poor are equally reflected in the policy decisions made by elected officials.

MEASURING THE EQUALITY OF POLITICAL REPRESENTATION IN US STATES

In this study, political representation is measured using a proximity technique that places public opinion and policy on the same linear scale and compares the distance between the two.Footnote 28 Using this method, as the ideological distance between a citizen’s opinion and policy grows (that is, policy is ideologically ‘further’ from a citizen’s preferences), that citizen is not well represented.Footnote 29 In practical terms, this proximity technique allows a researcher to evaluate whether a conservative (liberal) citizen lives in a state that, compared to other states, implements conservative (liberal) policies and is ‘well’ represented, implements liberal (conservative) policies and is ‘poorly’ represented, or gradations in between.

Measuring ideological proximity requires two pieces of data: (1) a measure of citizens’ opinions and (2) a measure of state policy. To measure public opinion, I combine data from the 2000, 2004 and 2008 NAES, three random-digit-dialing rolling cross-sectional surveys conducted in the months leading up to that year’s presidential election. The major advantage of pooling these three NAES surveys is their sheer sample size, which allows a large enough sample without having to aggregate across a long time period or simulate state opinion.Footnote 30 This large sample size is especially important because this article later evaluates the relationship between income and ideological proximity within individual states.Footnote 31

Citizens’ general political ideology is measured using the following item from the NAES: ‘Generally speaking, would you describe your political views as very conservative, conservative, moderate, liberal, or very liberal?’ The measure is coded from −2 (very conservative) to +2 (very liberal). Data on citizens’ self-reported political ideology have been commonly used to measure public opinion in previous studies of political representation,Footnote 32 and there is reason to be confident that self-reported ideology is an accurate measure of citizens’ aggregated policy-specific opinions.Footnote 33

To measure public policy, I require a general measure of the ‘liberalism’Footnote 34 of state policy outputs that comports with the survey item that asks citizens their general political ideology. In their seminal book on state opinion and policy, Erikson, Wright and McIver developed a composite index of state policy liberalism using eight policy areas on which liberals and conservatives typically disagree.Footnote 35 Gray et al. updated this policy liberalism measure for 2000 using the following five policy items: (1) state regulation of firearms as measured by state gun laws; (2) scorecard of state abortion laws in 2000; (3) an index of welfare stringency that accounts for Temporary Assistance to Needy Families rules of eligibility and work requirements for 1997–99; (4) a dummy measure of state right-to-work laws in 2001 and (5) a measure of tax progressivity calculated as a ratio of the average tax burden of the highest 5 per cent of a state’s earners to that of the lowest 40 per cent of a state’s earners.Footnote 36 These five components are then standardized and summed in an additive index such that more liberal state policies are coded higher. I use this index as my first measure of the general ideological tone of state policy.

Secondly, a recent article by Sorens, Muedini and Ruger provides a rich source of data on state policies in twenty different areas ranging from public assistance spending to gun control to health insurance regulations.Footnote 37 In addition to specific statutes and spending data, the authors provide a summary index of policy liberalism for each state that they derive by factor analyzing their entire range of policies. I use this composite score as a second measure of general policy liberalism.Footnote 38 Together, the two policy liberalism measures represent the unidimensional liberal/conservative ideology of state policy decisions that correspond well to the measure of citizens’ general political ideologies described above.

Measuring ideological proximity requires a method of placing citizens’ opinions and state policy on a common scale for comparison. Drawing on previous studies that have also used a proximity technique to measure political representation,Footnote 39 this article approaches this task in three different ways. If all three measurement techniques point to the same conclusion, then we can be more confident in the robustness of the results.Footnote 40

First, all ideological opinions are standardized to a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of one, and the two recent measures of general state policy liberalism described aboveFootnote 41 are then standardized as well. After standardizing both opinion and policy, they are now on a common (standardized) metric, similar to the strategy originally used by Wright and more recently by Ellis.Footnote 42 Proximity is measured as the absolute value of the difference between a respondent’s ideology score and the policy liberalism score for his/her state using both measures of policy. This creates the first measure of ideological distance for each respondent in the NAES sample, which is labeled the Standardized measure.

Secondly, the two measures of state policy are rescaled to the same scale (−2 to +2) as citizens’ self-reported ideology. This technique is similar to that used in early studies of congressional representation,Footnote 43 and is still advocated by representation scholars today.Footnote 44 The absolute value of the distance between a respondent’s ideology score and the policy liberalism score for his/her state is again computed and labeled the Same Scale measure.

Thirdly, policy is rescaled to a tighter range (−1 to +1) than citizens’ ideologies, as suggested and implemented by Powell in her studies of congressional representation.Footnote 45 This procedure is used because we can expect citizens’ ideological opinions to have a wider range and take on more extreme values compared to actual state policy outputs. Again, the absolute value of the distance between a respondent’s ideology score and the state policy liberalism score for his/her state is computed and labeled the Restricted Scale measure.

Together, there are three different measurement techniques and two different measurements of state policy liberalism, for a total of six different measures of ideological proximity between citizens’ opinions and state policy. I am then interested in whether there are systematic differences in proximity between opinion and policy across citizens; specifically, whether there is a link between a citizen’s income and the ideological distance between opinion and policy. Because I am interested in unequal political representation within each state and state populations can vary widely in terms of their income distribution, it would be unwise to simply compare the incomes of citizens in one state to those in another state. Simply put, we might expect someone making $100,000 per year living in West Virginia to exert comparatively greater political influence than someone making $100,000 per year living in Connecticut. To account for differences in income distribution across states, I generate a measure of state relative income that compares a respondent’s income with the average income for a resident in his or her state.Footnote 46

With this measure of state relative income, I then assess whether there is a systematic relationship between citizens’ incomes and the ideological distance between their opinion and state policy by regressing the measure of ideological distance on income for every respondent in the sample using the six different measures of ideological proximity described above.Footnote 47 The results of these six regression estimations reveal strong evidence of unequal political representation. Specifically, all six coefficients for income are negative and bounded below 0, which indicates that as a respondent’s income increases, the distance between their ideology and state policy decreases and they are better represented. Put another away, the lower a respondent’s income, the greater the distance between opinion and policy and the worse that respondent’s general political ideology is represented in the general liberalism of his or her state’s public policies.

Substantively, the larger opinion–policy distance for a respondent at the 10th percentile for income compared to a respondent at the 90th percentile is about the same as the difference between a respondent at the 10th percentile for (state relative) level of education compared to the 90th percentileFootnote 48 and larger than the difference between an African-American respondent and a white respondent.Footnote 49 These findings comport with the small (but growing) set of studies that has found that citizens with low incomes are systematically under-represented in the policy-making process in US states.Footnote 50

The primary rationale for examining unequal political representation at the state level is to understand and explain variation in political equality across states. To assess in which states political influence is strongly tied to income compared to those that weight opinions more equally, I run a separate regression for each state and compare the coefficient for (state relative) income. Similar to the nationwide regression discussed above, a more steeply negative slope coefficient indicates a stronger relationship between income and ideological distance and, accordingly, less political equality. For example, consider the two hypothetical states presented in Figure 1. For each state, the line represents the slope of the relationship between income and ideological distance. As the figure illustrates, the relationship between income and distance is rather weak in State A, indicating that citizens’ opinions are weighted roughly equally regardless of their income. In contrast, the slope of the relationship between income and ideological distance is quite steeply negative for State B, indicating that there is a strong degree of political inequality in state policy making.

Fig. 1 Computing the relationship for income and ideological distance, by state Note: State A has more equal political representation than State B because the relationship (regression slope coefficient) between income and opinion–policy distance is weaker in State A compared to State B.

A separate regression is run for each state using each of the six different measures of ideological proximity described above (three measurement techniques × two measures of state policy liberalism).Footnote 51 When the six regression coefficients (for state relative income) are compared across the states, they have a Cronbach’s alpha of 0.96, indicating that all six measures appear to be measuring the same concept. To create a single summary score of political equality that is directly comparable across states, I conduct a principal components analysis on the six slope coefficients and generate a single factor score for each state.Footnote 52 Because a more steeply negative slope coefficient indicates more unequal representation (that is, a stronger relationship between income and ideological distance), a more positive factor score indicates greater political equality (that is, a more equal weighting of citizens’ opinions). I label this new measure the Equality of Political Representation Index.

The factor scores generated using this procedure are reported in Table 1, where the states are ranked from the most to least equal in terms of political representation. It is important to note that the index is not simply an alternative measure of the general liberalism of state policy (with the expectation that lower-income citizens support more liberal policies). The Equality of Political Representation Index correlates with the Gray et al. policy liberalism measure at 0.46 and with the Sorens, Muedini and Ruger policy liberalism measure at only 0.36.Footnote 53 Most importantly, however, is the fact that there is significant variation in political equality across states. In the following section, I use this variation to evaluate whether states with stronger labor unions tend to display more egalitarian patterns of political representation.Footnote 54

Table 1 Ranking the States by the Equality of Political Representation

Note: cell entries are factor scores from combining six coefficients for state specific regressions. Larger positive values indicate greater political equality (a weaker relationship between income and ideological proximity).

STATE LABOR UNION STRENGTH AND THE EQUALITY OF POLITICAL REPRESENTATION

Above, I theorized that labor unions can promote greater political equality through two primary theoretical mechanisms: (1) mobilizing union members to political action and (2) contributing to candidates for elected office. To evaluate the individual effect of each mechanism, I measure the strength of labor unions in a state in two different ways. First, to measure the potency of labor mobilization in a state, I take the average percentage of nonagricultural wage and salary employees (including employees in the public sector) who are union members for 2000–06 using data from the Current Population Survey.Footnote 55 Secondly, to measure labor union involvement in political campaigns in a state, I take the amount of campaign contributions to candidates for state office (governor, state senate and state house) for 2000–06 that come from labor unionsFootnote 56 and divide by the total contributions from all sectors including agriculture, communications and electronics, construction, defense, energy and natural resources, finance, insurance, real estate, general business, health care, lawyers and lobbyists, and transportation.Footnote 57 This calculation produces the percentage of all campaign contributions (that are catalogued by industry) that come from labor unions. Across states, these two measures of labor union strength correlate at 0.65.

In the analysis presented below, the Equality of Political Representation Index is regressed on a state’s labor union membership and labor union campaign contributions to evaluate whether states with stronger labor unions have more egalitarian patterns of political representation.Footnote 58 Along with the two measures of labor union strength, I also include in the model a measure of the partisan composition of state government, the composition of a state’s interest group community, and a state’s median income and level of income inequality. The partisan composition of state government is measured as the average percentage of Democrats in the state legislature for 2000–06, and is included to account for the potential alternative explanation that states with a higher percentage of Democratic legislators are both more likely to implement union-friendly policies (that help strengthen labor unions) and more likely to equally represent the political opinions of citizens with low incomes in state policy decisions. The composition of a state’s interest group environment is measured as the percentage of organized groups in 1997 that represented for-profit interests (measure devised by Gray and Lowery and updated by Gray et al.Footnote 59 ) and is included because previous research indicates that a greater proportion of for-profit interest groups attenuates the link between public opinion and state government policy decisions.Footnote 60 Finally, a state’s median income and level of income inequality (using the Gini coefficient) for 2000 from the US Census Bureau are included because previous research on unequal political influence at the state level suggests that political representation is the least egalitarian in poorer states and in states with higher levels of income inequality.Footnote 61

The analysis proceeds by including each of the two union strength variables in a regression model separately before including both in the same model and allowing them to compete for statistical influence. Column 1 of Table 2 reports the estimates with labor union membership as the measure of union strength and reveals that the coefficient for membership is positive and statistically different from 0. This finding indicates that states with a greater percentage of workers who are labor union members tend to weigh citizens’ opinions more equally in the policy-making process. By contrast, Column 2 reports the estimates with labor union campaign contributions as the measure of union strength and reveals that the coefficient for contributions is not statistically different from 0, indicating that there is no relationship between the proportion of campaign contributions that comes from labor unions in a state and the equality of political representation. Finally, Column 3 reports estimates with both measures of union strength included in the model and, again, the coefficient for labor union membership is statistically different from 0 while the coefficient for labor union campaign contributions is not. In addition, the other covariates in the model reveal that (as previous studies have found) states with higher levels of income inequality tend to be less politically equal. Somewhat surprisingly, the coefficient for the percentage of Democrats in the state legislature is not statistically different from 0, indicating that there is little evidence that the partisan composition of state government is associated with the equality of a state’s political representation.Footnote 62

Table 2 Labor Union Strength and the Equality of Political Representation

Note: dependent variable is the Equality of Political Representation Index (higher value indicates a more equal weighting of citizens’ political opinions). Cell entries are ordinary least squares regression coefficients with standard errors reported beneath in brackets. Column 4 reports the standardized coefficients for the model in Column 3 (the predicted change in terms of standard deviations of the Equality of Political Representation Index when the independent variable in question is increased one standard deviation). *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01 (two-tailed test)

From a substantive standpoint, the magnitude of the relationship between labor union membership and the equality of political representation is quite large. Column 4 of Table 2 reports the standardized coefficients (the predicted change in terms of standard deviations of the Equality of Political Representation Index when the independent variable in question is increased one standard deviation) from the regression estimated in Column 3. As illustrated in the table, labor union membership has the largest substantive relationship with the equality of political representation of any predictor in the model. Specifically, a one-standard-deviation increase in the percentage of a state’s workers who are union members corresponds to more than half (0.53) a standard deviation increase in the Equality of Political Representation Index. In summary, the data indicate that labor union membership is an important predictor of representational equality in US states.

One potential concern about the findings reported in Table 2 is that the ability of labor unions to mobilize their members to political action or influence policy making through contributions to political campaigns are not optimally operationalized. To investigate this concern, I estimate a set of additional regression models with different measures of both union membership/mobilization and union campaign contribution activity. To measure how successful labor unions are at mobilizing their members to political action, I use validated voter turnout data from the 2008 Cooperative Congressional Election Study to calculate the share of the electorate in each state that is from a union member household. To measure how active labor unions are in contributing to political candidates compared to other organized interests, I calculate the ratio of labor union contributions to business contributions in each state for 2000–06.Footnote 63 Using these two alternative measures of labor union strength and the same empirical strategy and model specification as above, the results of the additional estimations are reported in Table 3. The coefficients for these estimations are consistent with those reported in Table 2. Namely, labor union mobilization is a significant predictor of greater representational equality in a state, while labor union campaign contributions are not. Again, the analysis points to the conclusion that labor unions’ ability to promote more egalitarian patterns of political representation lies in their effectiveness in organizing and then mobilizing union members to political action as opposed to contributing directly to state political campaigns.Footnote 64

Table 3 Robustness Check Using Alternative Measures of Labor Union Strength

Note: dependent variable is the Equality of Political Representation Index (higher value indicates a more equal weighting of citizens’ political opinions). Cell entries are ordinary least squares regression coefficients with standard errors reported beneath in brackets. Column 4 reports the standardized coefficients for the model in Column 3 (the predicted change in terms of standard deviations of the Equality of Political Representation Index when the independent variable in question is increased one standard deviation). *p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01 (two-tailed test)

CONCLUSION

Political equality is a cornerstone of democracy. As Sidney Verba declares, ‘One of the bedrock principles in a democracy is the equal consideration of the preferences and interests of all citizens.’Footnote 65 However, recent studies at both the nationalFootnote 66 and state levelsFootnote 67 report that, across a wide array of issue areas, affluent citizens are more likely to have their preferences reflected in government policy decisions compared to disadvantaged citizens. In response to these revelations, scholars and concerned citizens alike have begun to turn their attention to searching for possible remedies for political inequality. For example, Flavin finds that patterns of political representation are more egalitarian in states with stricter lobbying regulations and suggests tighter restrictions on the registration and conduct of professional lobbyists as one viable avenue of promoting more equal consideration of citizens’ political opinions.Footnote 68 Carnes also shows that citizens from working-class and low-income backgrounds are strikingly under-represented in state legislatures across the nation and, in response, recommends specific programs to recruit more blue-collar workers to run for elected office and advocate the opinions of disadvantaged citizens within government.Footnote 69

This article uses variation in labor union membership and campaign contributions across US states to examine the relationship between labor union strength and the equality of political representation between rich and poor citizens, and uncovers evidence that states with higher levels of union membership (and where union households make up a greater share of the electorate) weigh citizens’ opinions more equally in the policy-making process. In contrast, there is no statistical relationship between the volume of labor union contributions to political campaigns in a state and the equality of political representation. Taken together, these findings suggest that labor unions promote greater political equality primarily by mobilizing their working-class members to political action as opposed to influencing elected officials directly through contributions to political campaigns.

As illustrated by recent high-profile battles over ‘right-to-work’ legislation in several states that have traditionally supported labor-friendly policies such as Indiana, Michigan and Wisconsin, the ability to organize and join a labor union has increasingly become a politically contentious issue. Even in states without right-to-work laws, local governments (such as cities and counties in Illinois and Kentucky) are attempting to bypass state labor policies by creating right-to-work enclaves within their jurisdictions. The ultimate aim (and effect) of these efforts is to lower union membership rates and substantially reduce the influence of labor unions in both the workplace and the political arena. Given the empirical findings reported in this article, this increasingly adversarial climate for organized labor will likely only exacerbate existing inequalities in political influence between the rich and the poor. Therefore, citizens who are concerned about rising levels of economic and political inequality should focus greater attention on the important role that organized labor can still play in shaping the distribution of power in American politics.

More broadly, this article suggests a fruitful avenue for future study of the relationship between organized labor and the equality of political representation. Recent research examines the correspondence between public opinion and party positions/government policies in twenty-one parliamentary democracies and reports evidence that, similar to the United States, affluent citizens are more likely than disadvantaged citizens to have their opinions represented.Footnote 70 Power Resources Theory posits that one of the most effective ways for lower- and working-class citizens to exert greater political influence and secure public policies favorable to them is by organizing and affiliating with a labor union.Footnote 71 However, to date, there has been no empirical evaluation of whether countries with stronger and more politically active labor unions display more egalitarian opinion–policy linkages. Therefore future research should take advantage of the sizable cross-national variation in union strength and activity to explicitly examine whether the important role that labor unions play in promoting political equality in the United States applies internationally as well.

Footnotes

*

Department of Political Science, Baylor University (email: patrick_j_flavin@baylor.edu). A previous version of this article was presented at the 2016 meeting of the Southern Political Science Association in San Juan, Puerto Rico. I thank Nicholas Carnes, Michael Hartney and Christopher Witko for helpful comments. Data replication sets are available at https//dataverse.harvard.edu/dataverse/BJPolS, and online appendices are available at http://dx.doi.org/doi:10.1017/S0007123416000302.

2 Verba, Schlozman, and Brady Reference Verba, Schlozman and Brady1995.

3 Schlozman, Verba, and Brady Reference Schlozman, Verba and Brady2012.

4 Schlozman and Tierney Reference Schlozman and Tierney1986.

7 Bartels Reference Bartels2008; Gilens Reference Gilens2012; Gilens and Page Reference Gilens and Page2014; Hacker and Pierson Reference Hacker and Pierson2010; Kelly Reference Kelly2009; Schlozman, Verba, and Brady Reference Schlozman, Verba and Brady2012; Volscho and Kelly Reference Volscho and Kelly2012. According to the US Bureau of Labor Statistics, in 2014 only 11.1 per cent of all wage and salary workers were members of a labor union, compared to 20.1 per cent in 1983.

9 Jacobs and Skocpol Reference Jacobs and Skocpol2005, 124.

10 Bartels Reference Bartels2008. Ellis (Reference Ellis2012) finds a similar income bias in political representation for members of the US House of Representatives.

14 Leighley and Nagler Reference Leighley and Nagler1992; Rosenstone and Hansen Reference Rosenstone and Hansen1993; Verba, Schlozman, and Brady Reference Verba, Schlozman and Brady1995.

15 Leighley and Nagler Reference Leighley and Nagler2007.

17 For example, public school teachers’ unions are almost always contractually entitled to receive a comprehensive list of all district employees at the outset of each school year with detailed contact information that can be utilized for political mobilization purposes (Flavin and Hartney Reference Flavin and Hartney2015).

19 Griffin and Newman Reference Griffin and Newman2005.

21 Ansolabehere, de Figueiredo, and Snyder Reference Ansolabehere, de Figueiredo and Snyder2003.

22 Franko, Tolbert, and Witko Reference Franko, Tolbert and Witko2013; Gilens Reference Gilens2009.

24 Importantly, a third way in which labor unions can potentially promote greater political equality is by employing an ‘insider approach’ of lobbying elected officials and urging them to implement public policies that are supported by organized labor (Facchini, Mayda, and Mishra Reference Facchini, Mayda and Mishra2011; Masters and Delaney Reference Masters and Delaney2005). Unfortunately, there currently exists no comprehensive database of lobbying activity or expenditures by sector in every state that would allow for empirical testing of this potential mechanism. However, the National Institute on Money in State Politics is engaged in an ongoing effort to collect and catalog data on lobbying expenditures, and currently reports preliminary data for sixteen states. When I construct a measure of labor union lobbying spending as a share of total lobbying spending in a state and run a regression for those sixteen states using the model specification in Table 2, the coefficient for labor union lobbying is not statistically different from 0 (complete results are reported in Appendix Table A5). Across the sixteen states for which data are available, the labor union lobbying expenditures measure correlates at 0.56 with the labor union membership measure and at 0.16 with the labor union campaign contributions measure. Because data collection efforts in this area are ongoing, this is a fruitful avenue for future investigation.

25 Radcliff and Saiz Reference Radcliff and Saiz1998.

26 Witko and Newmark Reference Witko and Newmark2005.

27 Brady, Baker, and Finnigan Reference Brady, Baker and Finnigan2013; Kelly and Witko Reference Kelly and Witko2012.

29 The identical measurement technique has been used in several recent studies to evaluate the ideological distance between citizens and members of Congress (Ellis Reference Ellis2012; Griffin and Flavin Reference Griffin and Flavin2007; Griffin and Newman Reference Griffin and Newman2008), senators (Gershtenson and Plane Reference Gershtenson and Plane2007) and presidential candidates (Burden Reference Burden2004; Jessee Reference Jessee2009) in the United States, as well as the ideological distance between citizens and political parties in Europe (Blais and Bodet Reference Blais and Bodet2006; Giger, Rosset, and Bernauer Reference Giger, Rosset and Bernauer2012; Golder and Stramski Reference Golder and Stramski2010; Powell Reference Powell2009).

30 Carsey and Harden Reference Carsey and Harden2010.

31 A total of 177,043 NAES respondents across the three survey waves answered the ideological self-placement and income items. All states except North Dakota (N=475) and Wyoming (N=414) have a sample size of over 500 respondents. Alaska and Hawaii were not surveyed.

33 For example, only 38 per cent of respondents who place themselves in the ‘very conservative’ category believe that ‘Government should reduce income differences between the rich and poor’, while 77 per cent of respondents who place themselves in the ‘very liberal’ category support that policy proposal. Similarly, 81 per cent of respondents who place themselves in the ‘very liberal’ category oppose ‘Laws making it more difficult for a woman to get an abortion’, while only 28 per cent of respondents who place themselves in the ‘very conservative’ category oppose that policy proposal. For additional examples, see Appendix Table A1.

34 Klingman and Lammers Reference Klingman and Lammers1984.

35 Erikson, Wright, and McIver Reference Erikson, Wright and McIver1993.

36 Gray et al. Reference Gray, Lowery, Fellowes and McAtee2004. They argue that using these policy items, as opposed to a measure of per capita expenditures for different policy areas, precludes the possibility that policy liberalism is simply a proxy for a state’s wealth. The five measures produce a Cronbach’s alpha of 0.63.

37 Sorens, Muedini, and Ruger Reference Sorens, Muedini and Ruger2008. The state policy data is available at http://www.statepolicyindex.com.

38 The Gray et al. (Reference Gray, Lowery, Fellowes and McAtee2004) and Sorens, Muedini, and Ruger (Reference Sorens, Muedini and Ruger2008) policy liberalism measures correlate across the states at 0.79.

40 One common critique of using the proximity method to evaluate political representation is that, regardless of the statistical technique used to match up the two, opinion and policy are not on the same scale. However, whatever the flaws of each of the three different measures of ideological proximity in matching up opinion and policy, they are likely equally flawed for all citizens regardless of their income. Therefore, the proximity measures are appropriate for evaluating how ideologically proximate opinion and policy are for a poor person in comparison to a rich person (also see Ellis Reference Ellis2012).

44 Burden Reference Burden2004; Giger, Rosset, and Bernauer Reference Giger, Rosset and Bernauer2012; Griffin and Newman Reference Griffin and Newman2008.

46 The NAES codes respondents into one of nine categories based on their self-reported household income. To create a state relative measure of income for each respondent, I take the respondent’s income category and subtract the average income category value for all respondents in the state. The resulting calculation is positive if a respondent’s income is above the state average and negative it is below the state average.

47 The results of these regressions are reported in Appendix Table A2. Because respondents are clustered within states and experience the same state policy, I use standard errors clustered by state for all regressions. The choice of a single time period (2000–08) for the analysis is primarily a function of data availability on public opinion. As discussed above, while the NAES collects a large sample size in each wave, it is a national sample that is not designed to sample equal numbers of respondents in each state. As a result, many small population states have a sample size of less than 150 respondents in any single survey wave. Because the measure of the equality of political representation developed below requires running a separate regression for each state, a sample size of less than 150 survey respondents is problematic for the precision of the regression estimates. By comparison, when pooling the 2000, 2004 and 2008 NAES waves together for the analysis, all states except North Dakota (N=475) and Wyoming (N=414) have a sample size of over 500 respondents. Therefore, a pooling strategy is necessary to have enough respondents to run state-specific regressions and evaluate the relationship between income and opinion–policy proximity within each state. Nevertheless, as a robustness check and to make sure pooling the data is not masking differences across survey waves, I also run a separate analysis for each wave on the national sample and report the results in Appendix Table A3. As the regression coefficients indicate, the relationship between income and ideological distance is negative (that is, state policy is more proximate to citizens’ opinions as income increases) and of roughly the same magnitude for all three survey waves.

49 Griffin and Newman Reference Griffin and Newman2008.

51 One potential concern with running a regression separately for each state with opinion–policy distance as the dependent variable is that every respondent has the same value for state policy, effectively making the policy term a constant. However, consider a state where income and ideological conservatism correlate perfectly (that is, as income increases, so does ideological conservatism). If the state’s policy position is more conservative than all citizens’ ideology positions, the regression coefficient for income would be negative (indicating that as income increases, the ideological distance between opinion and policy decreases). But if the state’s policy position is more liberal than all citizens’ ideology positions, the coefficient for income would be positive (indicating that as income increases, the ideological distance between opinion and policy also increases). Even though the distribution of citizens’ opinions is identical under both scenarios, the regression coefficients are very different depending on where state policy is located in the ideological space (relative to citizens’ opinions). Therefore, the coefficient for respondents’ income for single-state regressions does not simply indicate the relationship between income and ideology within a state but instead indicates (as intended) the sign and strength of the relationship between income and opinion–policy distance.

52 The eigenvalue for the lone retained factor is 5.15 and explains 86 per cent of the total variance.

54 Although inequality in political influence among different racial/ethnic groups is not the focus of this article, it is nonetheless possible that the Equality of Political Representation Index may correlate with state racial/ethnic composition such that states with higher proportions of residents who are racial minorities are also those in which citizens with low incomes are most unequally represented. To investigate this possibility, I ran a set of regression models using the same specification as reported in Table 2 and added a measure of the percentage of state residents that identifies as a race/ethnicity other than white (Caucasian). In all models, the coefficient for the percent of a state’s residents that is non-white is not statistically different from 0, which indicates that more racially diverse states are no more or less likely to exhibit unequal political representation along income lines. Moreover, the coefficients for the other variables included in the regression models are substantive identical to the main findings reported in Table 2 below (complete results are reported in Appendix Table A6).

55 Hirsch, Macpherson, and Vroman Reference Hirsch, Macpherson and Vroman2001; Volscho and Kelly Reference Volscho and Kelly2012. Union density data are available at http://unionstats.gsu.edu/MonthlyLaborReviewArticle.htm. For 2000, private and public union membership rates (density) correlated across the states at 0.73.

56 Included in this measure are contributions from general trade unions (construction, mining, etc.), public sector unions (civil servants, teachers, etc.) and transportation unions (air, automotive, etc.).

57 State campaign contribution data by industry are collected by the National Institute on Money in State Politics and are available at http://www.followthemoney.org/.

58 Because the income–ideological proximity slope coefficients are estimated rather than observed for the states and have different levels of uncertainty (Achen Reference Achen2005; Lewis and Linzer Reference Lewis and Linzer2005), I also run Feasible Generalized Least Squares regressions in the second stage using the six individual sets of state regression coefficients from the first stage (instead of the combined Equality of Political Representation Index) as the dependent variables and weight observations by the inverse of a coefficient’s standard error. These six estimations yield substantially similar results to those reported in Table 2 (see Appendix Table A7). The results are also similar when Huber–White robust standard errors are employed.

61 Rigby and Wright Reference Rigby and Wright2011, Reference Rigby and Wright2013. Nebraska has a non-partisan state legislature, and Alaska and Hawaii were not surveyed in the NAES, so N=47 for the regression estimations. Descriptive statistics for all variables included in the analysis are reported in Appendix Table A4.

62 This finding is consistent with Bartels (Reference Bartels2008) and Rigby and Wright (Reference Rigby and Wright2013), who demonstrate that both Republican and Democratic candidates/elected officials are unresponsive to the political opinions of citizens with low incomes.

63 Across the states, union membership and union household share of the electorate correlate at 0.87, and union campaign contributions as a percent of the total and the union/business contributions ratio correlate at 0.85. Data on campaign contributions from business are from the National Institute on Money in State Politics and include general business advocacy associations (e.g., Chambers of Commerce) and individuals and groups engaged in business services, manufacturing, gambling and casinos, food and beverage hospitality, lodging and tourism, liquor and tobacco companies and sales, and retail sales.

64 Another potential concern with the findings presented in Table 2 is that equality of political representation is driving labor union membership (i.e., more egalitarian political representation in a state leads to higher levels of union membership). To investigate this concern, I estimated a model with state union membership as the dependent variable as a function of the Equality of Political Representation Index and three variables measured in 2000 that are common in the literature on the determinants of state union density: a dummy variable for whether a state has a mandatory collective bargaining law for state public employees (as originally specified by Valletta and Freeman Reference Valletta and Freeman1988) and the percentage of private sector employees in a state that is in the construction and manufacturing sectors (Hirsch, Macpherson, and Vroman Reference Hirsch, Macpherson and Vroman2001). The results of this estimation are reported in Appendix Table A8; they reveal that the coefficient for the Equality of Political Representation Index is not statistically different from 0.

65 Verba Reference Verba2003, 663.

70 Giger, Rosset, and Bernauer Reference Giger, Rosset and Bernauer2012.

71 Hicks Reference Hicks1999; Huber and Stephens Reference Huber and Stephens2001; Stephens Reference Stephens1979. Indeed, one commonly cited reason that the United States has one of the highest levels of income inequality and one of the stingiest social welfare systems among the advanced industrialized democracies is the relative weakness of its labor movement (Hacker and Pierson Reference Hacker and Pierson2010; Volscho and Kelly Reference Volscho and Kelly2012).

References

Achen, Christopher. 1978. Measuring Representation. American Journal of Political Science 22:475510.Google Scholar
Achen, Christopher. 2005. Two-Step Hierarchical Estimation: Beyond Regression Analysis. Political Analysis 13:447456.Google Scholar
Ahlquist, John S., and Levi, Margaret. 2013. In the Interest of Others: Organizations and Social Activism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, de Figueiredo, John M., and Snyder, James M.,. 2003. Why is There so Little Money in U.S. Politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives 17:105130.Google Scholar
Asher, Herbert B., Heberlig, Eric, Ripley, Randall, and Snyder, Karen. 2001. American Labor Unions in the Electoral Arena. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.Google Scholar
Bartels, Larry M. 2008. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, R. Frank, Berry, Jeffrey M., Hojnacki, Marie, Kimball, David C., and Leech, Beth L.. 2009. Lobbying and Policy Change: Who Wins, Who Loses, and Why. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Blais, Andre, and Bodet, Marc Andre. 2006. Does Proportional Representation Foster Closer Congruence Between Citizens and Policymakers? Comparative Political Studies 39:12431262.Google Scholar
Brady, David, Baker, Regina S., and Finnigan, Ryan. 2013. When Unionization Disappears State-Level Unionization and Working Poverty in the United States. American Sociological Review 78:872896.Google Scholar
Burden, Barry C. 2004. A Technique for Estimating Candidate and Voter Locations. Electoral Studies 23:623639.Google Scholar
Carnes, Nicholas. 2013. White-Collar Government: The Hidden Role of Class in Economic Policy Making. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Carsey, Thomas M., and Harden, Jeffrey J.. 2010. New Measures of Partisanship, Ideology, and Policy Mood in the American States. State Politics & Policy Quarterly 10:136156.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1961. Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Ellis, Christopher. 2012. Understanding Economic Biases in Representation: Income, Resources, and Policy Representation in the 110th House. Political Research Quarterly 65:938951.Google Scholar
Erikson, Robert S., Wright, Gerald C., and McIver, John P.. 1993. Statehouse Democracy: Public Opinion and Policy in the American States. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Facchini, Giovanni, Mayda, Anna Maria, and Mishra, Prachi. 2011. Do Interest Groups Affect U.S. Immigration Policy? Journal of International Economics 85:114128.Google Scholar
Fellowes, Matthew C., and Rowe, Gretchen. 2004. Politics and the New American Welfare States. American Journal of Political Science 48:362373.Google Scholar
Flavin, Patrick. 2012. Income Inequality and Policy Representation in the American States. American Politics Research 40:2959.Google Scholar
Flavin, Patrick. 2015. Lobbying Regulations and Political Equality in the American States. American Politics Research 43:304326.Google Scholar
Flavin, Patrick, and Hartney, Michael T.. 2015. When Government Subsidizes Its Own: Collective Bargaining Laws as Agents of Political Mobilization. American Journal of Political Science 59:896911.Google Scholar
Flavin, Patrick, and Radcliff, Benjamin. 2011. Labor Union Membership and Voting Across Nations. Electoral Studies 30:633641.Google Scholar
Fowler, Anthony. 2013. Electoral and Policy Consequences of Voter Turnout: Evidence from Compulsory Voting in Australia. Quarterly Journal of Political Science 8:159182.Google Scholar
Francia, Peter L. 2006. The Future of Organized Labor in American Politics. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Franko, William W., Tolbert, Caroline, and Witko, Christopher. 2013. Inequality, Self-Interest and Public Support for ‘Robin Hood’ Tax Policies. Political Research Quarterly 66:923937.Google Scholar
Gershtenson, Joseph, and Plane, Dennis L.. 2007. Ideology and Representation in the US Senate: Roll Calls v. Constituent Assessments. Journal of Legislative Studies 13:558576.Google Scholar
Giger, Nathalie, Rosset, Jan, and Bernauer, Julian. 2012. The Poor Political Representation of the Poor in a Comparative Perspective. Representation 48:4761.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin. 2005. Inequality and Democratic Responsiveness. Public Opinion Quarterly 69:778796.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin. 2009. Preference Gaps and Inequality in Representation. PS: Political Science & Politics 42:335341.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin, and Page, Benjamin I.. 2014. Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens. Perspectives on Politics 12:564581.Google Scholar
Golder, Matt, and Stramski, Jacek. 2010. Ideological Congruence and Electoral Institutions. American Journal of Political Science 54:90106.Google Scholar
Goldfield, Michael. 1987. The Decline of Organized Labor in the United States. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gray, Virginia, and Lowery, David. 1996. The Population Ecology of Interest Representation: Lobbying Communities in the American States. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Gray, Virginia, Lowery, David, Fellowes, Matthew, and McAtee, Andrea. 2004. Public Opinion, Public Policy, and Organized Interests in the American States. Political Research Quarterly 57:411420.Google Scholar
Griffin, John D., and Flavin, Patrick. 2007. Racial Differences in Information, Expectations, and Accountability. Journal of Politics 69:220236.Google Scholar
Griffin, John D., and Newman, Brian. 2005. Are Voters Better Represented? Journal of Politics 67:12061227.Google Scholar
Griffin, John D., and Newman, Brian. 2008. Minority Report: Evaluating Political Equality in America. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S., and Pierson, Paul. 2010. Winner Take All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich Richer – and Turned Its Back on the Middle Class. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hall, Richard L., and Wayman, Frank W.. 1990. Buying Time: Moneyed Interests and the Mobilization of Bias in Congressional Committees. American Political Science Review 84:797820.Google Scholar
Hicks, Alexander M. 1999. Social Democracy and Welfare Capitalism. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Hill, Kim Quaile, and Leighley, Jan E.. 1992. The Policy Consequences of Class Bias in State Electorates. American Journal of Political Science 36:351365.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Barry T., Macpherson, David A., and Vroman, Wayne G.. 2001. Estimates of Union Density by State. Monthly Labor Review 124:5155.Google Scholar
Huber, Evelyne, and Stephens, John D.. 2001. Development and Crisis of the Welfare State. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Jacobs, Lawrence R., and Skocpol, Theda, eds. 2005. Inequality and American Democracy: What We Know and What We Need to Learn. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Jessee, Stephen A. 2009. Spatial Voting in the 2004 Presidential Election. American Political Science Review 103:5981.Google Scholar
Kelly, Nathan J. 2009. The Politics of Income Inequality in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kelly, Nathan J., and Witko, Christopher. 2012. Federalism and American Inequality. Journal of Politics 74:414426.Google Scholar
Klingman, David, and Lammers, William W.. 1984. The ‘General Policy Liberalism’ Factor in American State Politics. American Journal of Political Science 28:598610.Google Scholar
Langbein, Laura I. 1986. Money and Access: Some Empirical Evidence. Journal of Politics 48:10521062.Google Scholar
Leighley, Jan E., and Nagler, Jonathan. 1992. Socioeconomic Class Bias in Turnout, 1964–1988: The Voters Remain the Same. American Political Science Review 86:725736.Google Scholar
Leighley, Jan E., and Nagler, Jonathan. 2007. Unions, Voter Turnout, and Class Bias in the U.S. Electorate, 1964–2004. Journal of Politics 69:430441.Google Scholar
Lewis, Jeffrey B., and Linzer, Drew A.. 2005. Estimating Regression Models in Which the Dependent Variable is Based on Estimates. Political Analysis 13:345364.Google Scholar
Makinson, Larry. 2003. Speaking Freely: Washington Insiders Talk About Money in Politics. Washington, DC: Center for Responsive Politics.Google Scholar
Masters, Marick F., and Delaney, John T.. 2005. Organized Labor’s Political Scorecard. Journal of Labor Research 26:365392.Google Scholar
Miller, Warren E. 1964. Majority Rule and the Representative System of Government. In Cleavages, Ideologies, and Party Systems, edited by Erik Allardt and Yrjo Littunen, 343376. Helsinki: Academic Bookstore.Google Scholar
Powell, G. Bingham. 2009. The Ideological Congruence Controversy: The Impact of Alternative Measures, Data, and Time Periods on the Effects of Election Rules. Comparative Political Studies 42:14751497.Google Scholar
Powell, Lynda W. 1982. Issue Representation in Congress. Journal of Politics 44:658678.Google Scholar
Powell, Lynda W. 1989. Analyzing Misinformation: Perceptions of Congressional Candidates’ Ideologies. American Journal of Political Science 33:272293.Google Scholar
Powell, Lynda W. 2012. The Influence of Campaign Contributions in State Legislatures: The Effects of Institutions and Politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Radcliff, Benjamin. 2001. Organized Labor and Electoral Participation in American National Elections. Journal of Labor Research 22:405414.Google Scholar
Radcliff, Benjamin, and Saiz, Martin. 1998. Labor Organization and Public Policy in the American States. Journal of Politics 60:113125.Google Scholar
Rigby, Elizabeth, and Wright, Gerald C.. 2011. Whose Statehouse Democracy: Policy Responsiveness to Poor Versus Rich Constituents in Poor Versus Rich States. In Who Gets Represented? edited by Peter Enns and Christopher Wlezian, 189222. New York: Russell Sage.Google Scholar
Rigby, Elizabeth, and Wright, Gerald C.. 2013. Political Parties and Representation of the Poor in the American States. American Journal of Political Science 57:552565.Google Scholar
Rosenfeld, Jake. 2014. What Unions No Longer Do. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rosenstone, Steven J., and Hansen, John Mark. 1993. Mobilization, Participation, and Democracy in America. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, Elmer Eric. 1960. The Semisovereign People. New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston.Google Scholar
Schlozman, Kay Lehman, and Tierney, John T.. 1986. Organized Interests and American Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Schlozman, Kay Lehman, Verba, Sidney, and Brady, Henry E.. 2012. The Unheavenly Chorus: Unequal Political Voice and the Broken Promise of American Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schram, Martin. 1995. Speaking Freely: Former Members of Congress Talk About Money in Politics. Washington, DC: Center for Responsive Politics.Google Scholar
Smith, Mark A. 2000. American Business and Political Power: Public Opinion, Elections, and Democracy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sorauf, Frank. 1988. Money in American Elections. Glenview: Scott, Foresman.Google Scholar
Sorens, Jason, Muedini, Fait, and Ruger, William P.. 2008. U.S. State and Local Public Policies in 2006: A New Database. State Politics & Policy Quarterly 8:309326.Google Scholar
Stephens, John D. 1979. The Transition from Capitalism to Socialism. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Valletta, Robert G., and Freeman, Richard B.. 1988. Appendix B: The NBER Public Sector Collective Bargaining Law Data Set. In When Public Sector Workers Unionize, edited by Richard B. Freeman and Casey Ichniowski, 399419. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Verba, Sidney. 2003. Would the Dream of Political Equality Turn Out to Be a Nightmare? Perspectives on Politics 1:663680.Google Scholar
Verba, Sidney, Schlozman, Kay Lehman, and Brady, Henry. 1995. Voice and Equality: Civic Voluntarism in American Politics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Volscho, Thomas W., and Kelly, Nathan J.. 2012. The Rise of the Super-Rich: Power Resources, Taxes, Financial Markets, and the Dynamics of the Top 1 Percent, 1949 to 2008. American Sociological Review 77:679699.Google Scholar
Witko, Christopher. 2006. PACs, Issue Context, and Congressional Decisionmaking. Political Research Quarterly 59:283295.Google Scholar
Witko, Christopher, and Newmark, Adam J.. 2005. Business Mobilization and Public Policy in the U.S. States. Social Science Quarterly 86:356367.Google Scholar
Wright, Gerald C. 1978. Candidates’ Policy Positions and Voting in U.S. Congressional Elections. Legislative Studies Quarterly 3:445464.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Fig. 1 Computing the relationship for income and ideological distance, by stateNote: State A has more equal political representation than State B because the relationship (regression slope coefficient) between income and opinion–policy distance is weaker in State A compared to State B.

Figure 1

Table 1 Ranking the States by the Equality of Political Representation

Figure 2

Table 2 Labor Union Strength and the Equality of Political Representation

Figure 3

Table 3 Robustness Check Using Alternative Measures of Labor Union Strength

Supplementary material: PDF

Flavin supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Flavin supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 94.5 KB
Supplementary material: Link

Flavin Dataset

Link